Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Governing smart grids: the case for an independent system operator

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The next years should bring about a rapid transformation of the electricity sector towards high levels of renewable generation and increasing numbers of electric vehicles. Smart grids are seen as the silver bullet responding to the challenge of integrating renewables, managing flexibility, and keeping the costs down in distribution networks. Network unbundling on the other hand is essential for competition in the liberalized electricity industry. It forces independence of the networks and thereby eliminates concern that incumbent integrated (network) firms discriminate against new entrants. With smart grids the unbundling questions become relevant for distribution networks, because active control in smart grids entails discrimination potentials. However, smart grids exhibit coordination needs for efficient system operation and unbundling eliminates firm-internal coordination. Accounting for both aspects, this paper proposes an independent system operator to govern smart distribution grids. It eliminates discrimination incentives and serves coordination needs, thereby striking a balance between both competition and efficiency goals.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. DG can but does not have to be RES. Large parts of DG are combined heat and power (CHP) plants fueled with natural gas.

  2. This article focuses on the European discussion of smart grids in distribution networks where smart grids are seen as a necessary tool to address the challenges of a low carbon electricity supply and integration of renewable energy sources (RES). In the US also the national transmission system plays an important role when talking about smart grids (see e.g. DoE 2009). This is driven by an explicit investment need and reliability concerns that the system is facing (Coll-Mayor et al. 2007, pp. 2456; 2461). Recently the discussion started to involve smart gas grids and the combination of different resources to smart poly grids or smart systems (see e.g. Hinterberger and Kleimaier, 2010).

  3. In the European Union this materializes in the renewable directive, the internal market directive, and the directive on energy end-use efficiency and energy services respectively Directive 2009/28/EC, Directive 2009/72/EC, and Directive 2006/32/EC. All these directives encourage intelligent networks or intelligent metering (EC 2009a, b, 2006). Financial support within the Seventh Framework Programme for research and technological development (FP7) for research and development (R&D) in smart grids, microsystems & ICT, and Green Cars & electromobility amounts to roughly 1.5 billion Euro. FP7 runs from 2007 to 2013 (Cordis 2009).

  4. The third legislative package on the European internal market for energy consists of two Directives, concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity and gas, 2009/72/EC and 2009/73/EC respectively, and three Regulations, one establishing an Agency for the Cooperation of Energy Regulators, 713/2009, and two on conditions for access to the electricity and natural gas transmission networks, 714/2009 and 715/2009 respectively. They are published in EC (2009c).

  5. Joskow (2008) gives an overview of electricity sector reform. Detailed country studies are collected in Sioshansi and Pfaffenberger (2006).

  6. For an overview on the theory of monopolistic bottlenecks and the consideration of competitive versus regulated markets see Knieps (2006).

  7. The existence of cross subsidies in electricity network practice is disputed. The Dutch regulator did not find evidence for cross subsidization in Dutch network companies (NMa 2007).

  8. On the European level, we observe a tendency for long term (central) planning for system development with the 10-year-network-development-plan (TYNDP), published by the European network of transmission system operators (ENTSO-E). At a national level, long term development statements published by network operators (Ofgem 2007a, b) are elements that move in this direction. They can increase transparency and promote coordination of developments.

  9. Theoretically, also simple communication can enhance coordination: the network could ask generators about their plans to adapt its network expansion to the developments at the generation stage. Unfortunately simple information exchange might fail due to strategic behaviour (Brunekreeft and Friedrichsen 2010).

  10. There may also be other motivations to discontinue ripple control: regulatory pressure to save cost can represent a disincentive for load control since cost for installation of the control equipment are one place to save fixed costs (Stevenson 2004, p. 4). Furthermore, experience from New Zealand suggests that commercial suppliers abandoned ripple control which was widely used in monopoly times, to benefit from demand driven price spikes (Bertram 2006, p. 204, footnote 2).

  11. While discrimination can be welcome in some cases such as favouring sustainable energy production over conventional generation, in general discrimination is considered undesirable as it may impede fair competition. Kruimer (2010) gives a detailed analysis of (non-) discrimination in the context of energy system operation.

  12. Baldick and Kahn (1993) illustrate the investment interdependency with a three node network. They show that a lack of coordination may cause inefficiencies because network expansion critically depends on the development of generation.

  13. This is a simplifying assumption. Even within an integrated firm, problems of coordination among the different division and supply stages are frequently present. A whole strand of literature deals with agency problems in firms. For an overview see Miller (2005).

  14. Prosumer refers to a customer who both consumers and produces electricity at its connection point.

  15. In future self-control will be assisted by automation devices. The user programmes the automation device to switch appliances on or off based on electricity prices.

  16. At transmission level, several markets around the world rely on nodal pricing, most prominently PJM in the US.

  17. In a simulation analysis of different tariff schemes for electric vehicles, Sioshansi (2012) finds that even though one would assume real time prices to be best suited to co-optimize vehicle charging with power system operation, they perform worse than other tariffs (even fixed rate) because of the “inability of linear prices to signal non-convex generator costs”.

  18. This parallels the findings of Coase (1960). Assume a good that benefits different parties. Coase (1960) investigates the effect that the allocation of rights on that good has on the final outcome. Under standard economic assumptions including zero transaction costs the rights’ allocation does not affect the final outcome. In a world with costs of market transactions, it does.

  19. see ”http://www.e-energy.de/” and ”http://www.gridwise.org” or ”http://www.gridwiseac.org” for further information.

  20. System balancing is currently a task of the transmission system operator. Whether or not with s mart grids some tasks shift to distribution system operators is still open.

  21. Recent research addresses bottom-up self-organization in infrastructures and decentralized coordination of electricity supply (see e.g. Kiesling 2009; Egyedi et al. 2007). Agent based systems are the technological grounds for decentralized coordination (see for example Kok 2010).

  22. The same could be true for customers: preferential treatment of customers of the affiliated retailer in case of curtailments or control actions. However, stakes are small at the retail stage compared to generation.

  23. Traditionally, in Germany many municipal utilities did not own a lot of generation capacity but examples show that this might change. EWE (after takeover in 2009 including SWB), Stadtwerke München, and MVV, three of the bigger utilities after the ‘big four’, all invest in renewable energy projects, CHP, and smart grids, and position themselves as innovative, forward looking, and environmentally conscious companies (SWM 2008; MVV 2010; EWE 2010).

  24. With this line of argument, unbundling regulation in New Zealand was loosened for distribution network operators (MED 2006).

  25. Furthermore, information handling needs to fulfill requirements on data privacy and security [for more information see e.g. McDaniel and Smith (2009)].

  26. Standards also benefits competition in the markets related to metering and information software and hardware as the product and services become more homogeneous.

  27. Strbac (2002) even argues that DG inevitably leads to unbundling and a changing role of the network operator.

References

  • Ackermann, T. (2004). Distributed resources in a re-regulated market environment. PhD thesis, KTH, Stockholm.

  • Baldick, R., & Kahn, E. (1993). Network costs and the regulation of wholesale competition in electric power. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 5(4), 367–384. http://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/regeco/v5y1993i4p367-84.html.

  • Balmert, D., & Brunekreeft, G. (2010). Deep ISOs and network investment. Competition and Regulation in Network Industries, 1, 27–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • BDEW. (2011). Abschätzung des Ausbaubedarfs in deutschen Verteilungsnetzen aufgrund von Photovoltaik- und Windeinspeisungen bis 2020. march 30, 2011.

  • Beard, T. R., Kaserman, D. L., & Mayo, J. W. (2001). Regulation, vertical integration and sabotage. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 49(3), 319–333, http://www.jstor.org/stable/3569828.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertram, G. (2006). Restructuring the New Zealand Electricity Sector 1984–2005. In F. P. Sioshansi & W. Pfaffenberger (Eds.), Electricity market reform: An international perspective (pp. 203–234). Oxford: Elsevier.

  • Brandstätt, C., Brunekreeft, G., & Friedrichsen, N. (2011). Locational signals to reduce network investments in smart distribution grids: What works and what not? Utilities Policy (in press). doi:10.1016/j.jup.2011.07.001.

  • Brunekreeft, G. (2008). Eigentumsentflechtung, deep-ISO, der dritte Weg—wohin führt die Reise der Europäischen Energiemärkte. Zeitschrift für Energiewirtschaft, 3, 33–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunekreeft, G., & Friedrichsen, N. (2010). Vertical unbundling, the coordination of investment, and network pricing, Bremen Energy Working Paper (BEWP) No. 03. Jacobs University Bremen/ Bremer Energie Institut.

  • Brunekreeft, G., Neuhoff, K., & Newbery, D. (2005). Electricity transmission: An overview of the current debate. Utilities Policy 13(2), 73–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunekreeft, G., Balmert, D., & Gabriel, J. (2007). Independent System Operators—ein Überblick. Bremer Energie Institut.

  • Bundeskartellamt. (2001). Bericht der Arbeitsgruppe Netznutzung Strom der Kartellbehörden des Bundes und der Länder über 1. die Reichweite der kartellrechtlichen Eingriffsnormen für die Überprüfung der Höhe der Entgelte für die Nutzung der Stromnetze 2. die kartellrechtliche Relevanz von den Netzzugang behindernden Verhaltensweisen der Stromnetzbetreiber. Tech. rep., Bundeskartellamt - Federal Cartel Office.

  • Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405. http://www.jstor.org/stable/2626876.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coll-Mayor, D., Paget, M., Lightner, E. (2007). Future intelligent power grids: Analysis of the vision in the European Union and the United States. Energy Policy, 35(4), 2453–2465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook, C. J. (2008). Private enforcement of EU competition law in member state courts: experience to date and the path ahead. Competition Policy International, 4(2).

  • Cordis. (2009). http://cordis.europa.eu/fp7/energy/open-topics_en.htmlopen-topics-table.

  • DoE. (2009). Smart grid system report. Tech. rep., United States Department of Energy Office.

  • EC. (2006). Directive 2006/32/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 5 april 2006 on energy end-use efficiency and energy services and repealing Council Directive 93/76/EC. Tech. rep., European Commission, http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:L:2006:114:0064:0085:EN:PDF.

  • EC. (2007). Report on energy sector inquiry SEC(2006)1724, 10 january 2007. Tech. rep., European Commission, DG Competition.

  • EC. (2008). White paper on damages actions for breach of the EC antitrust rules. Tech. rep., European Commission.

  • EC. (2009a). Directive 2009/28/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 23 april 2009 on the promotion of the use of energy from renewable sources and amending and subsequently repealing Directives 2001/77/EC and 2003/30/EC. Tech. rep., European Commission, http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:L:2009:140:0016:0062:EN:PDF.

  • EC. (2009b). Directive 2009/72/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 july 2009 concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity and repealing Directive 2003/54/EC. Tech. rep., European Commission, http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:L:2009:211:0055:0093:EN:PDF.

  • EC. (2009c). Legislation: Acts adopted under the EC treaty/euratom treaty whose publication is obligatory. Official Journal of the European Union, 52, 1–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • EC. (2011). Smart grids: from innovation to deployment, Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions, SEC(2011) 463 final. Tech. rep., European Commission.

  • Egyedi, T. M., Vrancken, J. L., & Ubacht, J. (2007). Inverse infrastrucutres: Coordination in self-organizing systems. In P. Feng, D. Meeking & R. Hawkins (Eds.), 5th international conference on standardization and innovation in information technology (SIIT 2007), University of Calgary, Canada, pp. 23–35.

  • EWE (2010). Information on the corporate website. http://www.ewe.com/konzern/profil.php; http://www.ewe.com/konzern/energie.php, last access 14.06.2010.

  • Granger Morgan, M., Apt, J., Lave, L. B., Ilic, M. D., Sirbu, M., Peha, J. M. (2009). The Many Meanings of Smart Grid. EPP Policy Brief, August.

  • Hinterberger, R., & Kleimaier, M. (2010). Die intelligenten Gasnetze der Zukunft: Herausforderung und Chance für die Gaswirtschaft. DVGW Energie & Wasser Praxis, 6, 32–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hogan, W. W. (1992). Contract networks for electric power transmission. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 4(3), 211–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joskow, P. (2008). Lessons learned from electricity market liberalization. The Energy Journal, Special Issue The Future of Electricity: Papers in Honor of David Newbery, 9–42.

  • Joskow, P., & Schmalensee, R. (1983). Markets for Power: An Analysis of Electric Utility Deregulation. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaserman, D. L., & Mayo, J. W. (1991). The measurement of vertical economies and the efficient structure of the electric utility industry. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 39(5), 483–502. http://www.jstor.org/stable/2098457.

  • Kiesling, L. L. (2009). Deregulation, innovation and market liberalization—electricity regulation in a continually evolving environment. Routledge Studies in Business Organizations and Networks.

  • Knieps, G. (2006). Sector-specific market power regulation versus general competition law: Criteria for judging competitive versus regulated markets. In F. P. Sioshansi & W. Pfaffenberger (Eds.), Electricity market reform: An international perspective (pp. 49–74). Oxford: Elsevier.

  • Kok, K. (2010). Multi-agent coordination in the electricity grid—from concept towards market introduction. In van der Hoek, Kaminka, Lespérance, Luck, & Sen (Eds.), 9th international conference on autonomous agents and multiagent systems (AAMAS 2010), 10–14 May 2010, Toronto, Canada.

  • Kruimer, H. (2010). Non-discriminatory energy system operation: What does it mean? Competition and Regulation in Network Industries, 12(3), 260–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Künneke, R. W., & Fens, T. (2009). Towards an information architecture in unbundled energy distribution networks. In: Unecom Workshop Brussels.

  • Künneke, R. W., Groenewegen, J., & Ménard, C. (2010). Aligning modes of organization with technology: Critical transactions in the reform of infrastructures. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 75, 494–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kwoka, J. E. (2002). Vertical economies in electric power: Evidence on integration and its alternatives. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 20, 653–671.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, F. (2007). The benefit of a long-run incremental pricing methodology to future network development. In IEEE power engineering society general meeting, 24–28 June 2007, Tampa, Florida USA.

  • McDaniel, P., & Smith, S. W. (2009) Security and privacy challenges in the smart grid. IEEE of Security & Privacy, 3, 75–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MED. (2006). Investment in electricity generation by lines companies. Ministry of Economic Development New Zealand.

  • Meyer, R. (2011). Vertical economies of scope in electricity supply—analysing the costs of ownership unbundling. PhD thesis, Jacobs University, School of Humanities and Social Sciences.

  • Miller, G. (2005). Solutions to principal-agent problems in firms. In C. Ménard & M. Shirley (Eds.), Handbook of new institutional economics (pp. 349–370). US: Springer. doi:10.1007/0-387-25092-1_15.

  • MVV. (2010). Strategy. http://www.mvv-investor.de/de/wir-ueber-uns/konzern/strategie.php, information in the investor relations section of the website. last access: 17.06.2010.

  • Nemoto J., & Goto, M. (2004). Technological externalities and economies of vertical integration in the electric utility industry. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 22(1), 67–81. http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/B6V8P-498TYG0-1/1/1dd985cf7bf85a9ab9f5b0c1c0101e83.

  • Niesten, E. (2010). Network investments and the integration of distributed generation: Regulatory recommendations for the dutch electricity industry. Energy Policy, 38, 4355–4362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • NMa. (2007). Onderzoeksrapport inzake de interne verrekeningsprijzen van energiebedrijven. Tech. rep., Nma, Den Haag.

  • Ofgem. (2007a). Decision on the long term development statements (LTDS) for electricity distribution networks—decision letter. Tech. rep., Office of Gas and Electricity Markets, http://www.ofgem.gov.uk/NETWORKS/TECHN/NETWRKSUPP/LONGTERMDS/Documents1/Decision.

  • Ofgem. (2007b). Form of long term development statement. Tech. rep., Office of Gas and Electricity Markets, http://www.ofgem.gov.uk/NETWORKS/TECHN/NETWRKSUPP/LONGTERMDS/Documents1/Form.

  • Ofgem. (2010). Press release 26 July 2010: Ofgem reengineers network price controls to meet £32 billion low carbon investment challenge.

  • Perry, M. K. (1989). Vertical integration: Determinants and effects. In R. Schmalensee & R. Willig (Eds.), Handbook of industrial organization (Vol. 1, Chap. 4, pp. 183–255). Elsevier, http://ideas.repec.org/h/eee/indchp/1-04.htm.

  • Piccolo, A., & Siano, P. (2009). Evaluating the impact of network investment deferral on distributed generation expansion. IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, 24(3), 1559–1567.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pielow, J. C., Brunekreeft, G., & Ehlers, E. (2009). Legal and economic aspects of ownership unbundling in the EU. Journal of World Energy Law & Business, 2(2), 96–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prica, M., & Ilic, M. (2007). Optimal distribution service pricing for investment planning. In IEEE power engineering society general meeting, 2007, Citeseer, pp. 1–7.

  • Pudjianto, D., Ramsay, C., & Strbac, G. (2007). Virtual power plant and system integration of distributed energy resources. IET Renewable Power Generation, 1(1), 10–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt-Preuss, M. (2009). OU-ISO-ITO: Die Unbundling-Optionen des 3. EU-Liberalisierungspakets. Energiewirtschafltiche Tagesfragen, 59(9), 82–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schweppe, F. C., Tabors, R. D., Caramanis, M. C., & Bohn, R. E. (1988). Spot pricing of electricity. Norwell, MA: Kluwer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sioshansi, F. P., & Pfaffenberger, W. (2006) Electricity market reform: An international perspective. Elsevier, Oxford, chap Why restructure Electricity Markets? (pp. 35–48).

  • Sioshansi, R. (2012). Modeling the impacts of electricity tariffs on plug-in hybrid electric vehicle charging, costs, and emissions. Operations Research, 60.

  • Stevenson, T. (2004). Mass market load control—its use and its potential use. Report prepared for the energy efficiency and conservation authority new zealand. http://www.happyhome.co.nz/anytime/pdf_files/anytime48069484d5411f400.pdf.

  • Strbac, G. (2002). Impact of dispersed generation on distribution systems: A European perspective. In IEEE power engineering society winter meeting (Vol 1).

  • Strbac, G. (2008). Demand side management: Benefits and challenges. Energy Policy, 36(12), 4419–4426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • SWM. (2008). Energiekonzept 2030 der Stadtwerke München GmbH.

  • Talus, K., & Johnston, A. (2009). Comment on Pielow, Brunekreeft and Ehlers on ‘ownership unbundling’. Journal of World Energy Law & Business, 2(2), 149–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veldman, E., Geldtmeijer, D. A., Knigge, J. D., & Slootweg, J. (2010). Smart grids put into practice: Technological and regulatory aspects. Competition and Regulation in Network Industries, 3, 287–306.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wachovius, M. (2008). Ownership unbundling. Frankfurt: VWEW Energieverlag GmbH.

    Google Scholar 

  • WIK, Fraunhofer ISI, Fraunhofer ISE. (2006). Potenziale der Informations- und Kommunikations-Technologien zur Optimierung der Energieversorgung und des Energieverbrauchs (eEnergy). Tech. rep., Studie für das Bundesministerium für Wirtschaft und Technologie (BMWi).

  • Williamson, O. E. (2000). The new institutional economics: Taking stock, looking ahead. Journal of Economic Literature, 38(3), 595–613. http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0515.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Financial assistance from Next Generation Infrastructures within the project UNECOM and from the German Federal Ministry of Economics within the research project IRIN - Innovative Regulation for Intelligent Networks (grant number: FKZ 0328007A) is gratefully acknowledged. The author would also like to thank Gert Brunekreeft, Rolf Künneke, Roland Meyer, Christine Brandstätt, and Jana Friedrichsen for valuable suggestions. Furthermore, the author acknowledges useful comments by participants of the 9th Conference on Applied Infrastructure Research, October 8–9, 2010 in Berlin, the 3rd Annual Conference on Competition and Regulation in Network Industries, November 19, 2010 in Brussels, the SIB Business Week Workshop on Research in Air Transport and other Network Industries, May 19-21, 2011 in Bremen, and the 13th Economics of Infrastructures Conference, May 26-27, 2011 in Delft. All remaining errors are the responsibility of the author.

Conflict of interest

The author declares that she has no conflict of interest.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Nele Friedrichsen.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Friedrichsen, N. Governing smart grids: the case for an independent system operator. Eur J Law Econ 39, 553–572 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-012-9345-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-012-9345-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation