Skip to main content
Log in

Recurrent default or policy-optimal taxation

  • Published:
Economic Change and Restructuring Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the syndrome of “this time is different” with respect to Reinhart and Rogoff’s (This time is different: eight centuries of financial folly Princeton University Press, Princeton, 2011) interpretation of their extensive, historical data on financial default, and with particular regard to public debt in a closed-economy. Recurrent and over-generous promises to credulous investors of an ex ante, policy-optimal return amounts to an extra policy instrument in boosting the demand for public debt. In a numerical simulation of a version of the Diamond (Am Econ Rev 55:1126–1150, 1965) model, we find that the incentive for the policy-maker to pursue this strategy is trivial if taxes can be set at a policy-optimal level, but possibly over-riding if they cannot. Thus, the main result lines up with the empirical conclusion of Reinhart et al. (Debt intolerance. Debt intolerance, 2003) that “debt intolerant countries have weak fiscal structures”. The subsidiary result of the model is that defaulting countries will also have higher shares of public expenditure. Thus the model also predicts Wagner’s Law to the extent that fiscal structure is correlated with economic development.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Convergence to rational expectations in learning models may only arise asymptotically, so that if lives are finite, approximate convergence may require that the revision of beliefs is at a high frequency.

  2. Reinhart and Rogoff (2011) use the term “this time is different” to describe hubristic beliefs, which because of some structural change, the normal “rules” may no longer apply. We use it in a subtly different and even more hubristic sense that each generation believes that default only belongs to the past. This is a more operational use of the concept for modelling a, typically, constant economic structure.

  3. This approach allows portfolio balance for two assets. The weightings may also be interpreted as probabilities in a two state case.

  4. See (Ang et al. 2006).

  5. Specifying logarithmic preferences and omitting a second period earned income ensures that the saving and portfolio decisions are separable.

  6. This term could be replaced by the total income of old households, but this would merely dampen the results, while making them stochastic.

  7. Symmetrically, unwarranted pessimism would lead to pleasant surprises.

  8. If households believe they will receive the ex post outcome,\(S_{t} (R_{t + 1}^{B} ) = R_{t + 1}^{B}\), they must also believe there is a rational expectations steady state. Leading Eq. (8) one period shows that for current expectations to be strictly rational, there must be a foreknowledge of the following generation’s beliefs,\(S_{t + 1} (R_{t + 2}^{B} )\), while at best there can only be beliefs about future beliefs. A steady state requires that each generation believes their successors will form the same beliefs as themselves. Designating current beliefs on future beliefs as \(F_{t} \left( {F_{t + 1} (R_{t + 2}^{B} )} \right)\), a stationary REE requires that \(S_{t} \left( {S_{t + 1} (R_{t + 2}^{B} )} \right) = S_{t} (R_{t + 1}^{B} ) = R_{t + 1}^{B}\), \(\forall t\). This is the benchmark for measuring the effects of persuading households to believe otherwise, \(S_{t} (R_{t + 1}^{B} ) > R_{t + 1}^{B}\).

  9. Ferguson (2002) claims that the holders of the public debt in nineteenth century Britain, a politically well-connected minority, gained from an extended period of deflation at the expense of an unenfranchised, tax-paying majority.

  10. One reason why a real redistribution of this kind may no longer apply may be that many of the owners of the public debt may gain instead from the ex post redistribution furnished by a pay-as-you-go social security scheme.

  11. As we assume only labour income is taxed and as we assign a labour income share of 50%, the calculations are based on a labour income tax of 25%.

  12. Of the 173 countries on Macroeconomic Data and Index of Economic Freedom (2015) list, 22 have tax rates between 0 and 10%, 63 between 10 and 20%, 47 between 20 and 30%, 30 between 30 and 40%, 10 between 40 and 50% and 1 with a tax rate over 50% of GDP. These figures are not exactly comparable to our present exercise, because there may be other actual sources of revenue, for example, from oil and commodity exports, and, more generally, because cross-country differences will also reflect varying preferences over the size of government.

  13. Naïve expectations, leading to an unduly high demand for public debt, thus imply a negative generational externality through an excessive crowding-out of the capital stock.

  14. It would be also interesting if there where implications for the composition of public expenditure between productive and non-productive uses, but here these remain in fixed proportion to each other, because of the assumption of a combination of a Cobb–Douglas production technology with a logarithmic policy objective function.

  15. An exception is the more historical case of fiefdom where one jurisdiction may be contracted to pay tribute to another one on a permanent basis.

  16. Or, as Abraham Lincoln said more succinctly, “You can fool some of people some of the time, but you can’t fool all of the people all of the time”.

References

  • Ang A, Chen J, Xing Y (2006) Downside risk. Rev Financ Stud 19:1191–1239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ (1990) Government spending in a simple model of endogenous growth. J Polit Econ 98(S5):103–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Gordon DB (1983) A positive theory of monetary policy in a natural rate model. J Polit Econ 91:589–610

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo G (1988) Servicing the public debt: the role of expectations. Am Econ Rev 78:647–661

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond PA (1965) National debt in a neoclassical growth model. Am Econ Rev 55:1126–1150

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferguson Niall (2002) The Cash Nexus: Economics and Politics from the Age of Warfare to the Age of Welfare. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohlscheen E (2007) Why are there serial defaulters? Evidence from constitutions. J Law Econ 50(4):713–730

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohlscheen E (2010) Sovereign risk: constitutions rule. Oxf Econ Papers 62(1):62–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydland FE, Prescott EC (1977) Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans. J Polit Econ 85(3):473–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macroeconomic Data and Index of Economic Freedom (2015) Heritage Foundation, Washington DC

  • Norberg J (2009) Financial Fiasco. Cato Institute, Washington DC

    Google Scholar 

  • North DC, Weingast BR (1989) Constitutions and commitment: the evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth century England. J Econ Lit 49(4):803–832

    Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart CM, Rogoff KS, Savastano MA (2003) Debt intolerance. Brook Pap Econ Activity 1:1–74

    Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart CM, Rogoff KS (2011) This time is different: eight centuries of financial folly. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Tanzi V, Zee HH (2000) Tax policy for emerging markets: developing countries. Natl Tax J 53(2):299–322

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Mike Bleaney and an anonymous referee for helpful comments without implicating them.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mark A. Roberts.

Appendix: Solution

Appendix: Solution

1.1 Factor prices, public expenditure and economic growth

For analytical convenience, we calculate the solutions sequentially, although this is not significant for the results. Returning to Eq. (9), \(\begin{aligned} \ln Z_{t} = \ln \left( {(1 - \tau_{t} )w_{t} } \right) + \eta \ln \left( {\tau_{t} w_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )w_{t} - g_{{_{t} }}^{P} - g_{t}^{N} } \right) \hfill \\ + \varpi \ln \left( {(1 - \beta_{t} )\sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )w_{t} } \right) + \gamma \ln g_{t}^{N} \hfill \\ \end{aligned}\), the policy-optimal level of non-productive public expenditure is

$$g_{{_{t} }}^{N} = \frac{\gamma }{\gamma + \eta }\left( {\tau_{t} w_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )w_{t} - g_{t}^{P} } \right) .$$
(12)

Substituting this back into (9) gives

$$\begin{aligned} \ln Z^{\prime}_{t} = \ln \left( {(1 - \tau_{t} )w_{t} } \right) + (\eta + \gamma )\ln \left( {\tau_{t} w_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )w_{t} - g_{{_{t} }}^{P} } \right),\;{\text{or}} \hfill \\ \quad+ \varpi \ln \left( {(1 - \beta_{t} )\sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )w_{t} } \right) + \cdots \hfill \\ \quad\ln Z^{\prime}_{t} = \ln (1 - \tau_{t} ) + (\eta + \gamma )\ln \left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} ) - {{g_{{_{t} }}^{P} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{g_{{_{t} }}^{P} } {w_{t} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {w_{t} }}} \right) \hfill \\ \quad+ \varpi \ln \left( {(1 - \beta_{t} )\sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right) + (1 + \eta + \gamma + \varpi )\ln w_{t} \hfill \\ \end{aligned}$$
(13)

Substituting (5) for the wage into (13) gives

$$\begin{aligned} \ln Z^{\prime\prime}_{t} = \ln (1 - \tau_{t} ) + (\eta + \gamma )\ln \left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} ) - \frac{{g_{t}^{P\mu } }}{{(1 - \mu )Ak_{t}^{\mu } }}} \right) \hfill \\ + \varpi \ln \left( {(1 - \beta_{t} )\sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right) + (1 + \eta + \gamma + \varpi )(1 - \mu )\ln g_{t}^{P} + \cdots \hfill \\ \end{aligned}$$
(14)

The policy-optimal level of productive public expenditure is

$$g_{t}^{P} = \left( {\frac{{(1 - \mu )^{2} (1 + \eta + \gamma + \varpi )\left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right)A}}{\mu (\eta + \gamma ) + (1 - \mu )(1 + \eta + \gamma + \varpi )}} \right)^{{\frac{1}{\mu }}} k_{t} ,$$
(15)

which, according to (5) implies a wage and an expected value return on capital of

$$w_{t} = (1 - \mu )A\left( {\frac{{(1 - \mu )^{2} (1 + \eta + \gamma + \varpi )\left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right)A}}{\eta + \gamma + (1 - \mu )(1 + \varpi )}} \right)^{{\frac{1}{\mu } - 1}} k_{t} ,$$
(16)
$$E_{t - 1} \left(R_{{_{t} }}^{K} \right) = \mu \left( {\frac{{(1 - \mu )^{2} (1 + \eta + \gamma + \varpi )\left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right)}}{\eta + \gamma + (1 - \mu )(1 + \varpi )}} \right)^{{\frac{1}{\mu } - 1}} A^{{{1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \mu }} \right. \kern-0pt} \mu }}}$$
(17)

The ratio of the productive public expenditure to the wage is

$$\frac{{g_{t}^{P} }}{{w_{t} }} = \left( {\frac{(1 - \mu )(1 + \eta + \gamma + \varpi )}{\eta + \gamma + (1 - \mu )(1 + \varpi )}} \right)\left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right)$$
(18)

Equations (12) and (18) imply the equivalent ratio for total public expenditure,

$$\frac{{g_{t} }}{{w_{t} }} = \frac{{g_{t}^{P} + g_{t}^{N} }}{{w_{t} }} = \left( {\frac{\eta (1 - \mu ) + \gamma + (1 - \mu )(1 + \varpi )}{\eta + \gamma + (1 - \mu )(1 + \omega )}} \right)\left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right)$$
(19)

Equations (14) and (15) give

$$\ln Z^{\prime\prime\prime}_{t} = \ln (1 - \tau_{t} ) + \varPsi \ln \left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right) + \varpi \ln \left( {(1 - \beta_{t} )\sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right) + ..$$
$$\varPsi \equiv \left( {(\eta + \gamma ) + \frac{1 - \mu }{\mu }\left( {1 + \eta + \gamma + \varpi } \right)} \right)$$
(20)

Equations (2) and(16) give the growth factor for the capital stock as

$$\frac{{k_{t} }}{{k_{t - 1} }} = (1 - \mu )(1 - \beta_{t - 1} )\sigma (1 - \tau_{t - 1} )A^{{^{{{1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \mu }} \right. \kern-0pt} \mu }}} }} \left( {\frac{{(1 - \mu )^{2} \left( {\tau_{t - 1} + \beta_{t - 1} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t - 1} )} \right)}}{{\frac{\mu (\eta + \gamma )}{1 + \eta + \gamma + \varpi } + 1 - \mu }}} \right)^{{{1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \mu }} \right. \kern-0pt} \mu } - 1}}$$
(21)

1.2 Actual ex post returns on public debt

Equations (8) and (19) give

$$R_{t}^{B} = \left( {\frac{\eta \mu }{\eta + \gamma + (1 - \mu )(1 + \omega )}} \right)\left( {\frac{{\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )}}{{\beta_{t - 1} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t - 1} )}}} \right)\frac{{w_{t} }}{{w_{t - 1} }}$$
(22)

Equation (16) implies a factor of wage growth of

$$\frac{{w_{t} }}{{w_{t - 1} }} = \left( {\frac{{\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )}}{{\tau_{t - 1} + \beta_{t - 1} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t - 1} )}}} \right)^{{{1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \mu }} \right. \kern-0pt} \mu } - 1}} \frac{{k_{t} }}{{k_{t - 1} }}$$
(23)

The last three equations imply

$$R_{t}^{B} = \frac{{\eta \mu (1 - \mu )\left( {(1 + \eta + \gamma + \varpi )(1 - \mu )^{2} } \right)^{{{1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 {\mu - 1}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\mu - 1}}}} }}{{\left( {\eta + \gamma + (1 - \mu )(1 + \varpi )} \right)^{{{1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \mu }} \right. \kern-0pt} \mu }}} }}\left( {\frac{{1 - \beta_{t - 1} }}{{\beta_{t - 1} }}} \right)\left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right)^{{{1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \mu }} \right. \kern-0pt} \mu }}} A^{{{1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \mu }} \right. \kern-0pt} \mu }}}$$
(24)

This can be expressed in relation to \(E_{t - 1} (R_{{_{t} }}^{K} )\) in Eq. (17) as

$$R_{t}^{B} = \frac{{\eta \mu (1 - \mu )\left( {(1 + \eta + \gamma + \varpi )(1 - \mu )^{2} } \right)^{{{1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 {\mu - 1}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\mu - 1}}}} }}{{\left( {\eta + \gamma + (1 - \mu )(1 + \varpi )} \right)^{{{1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \mu }} \right. \kern-0pt} \mu }}} }}\left( {\frac{{1 - \beta_{t - 1} }}{{\beta_{t - 1} }}} \right)\left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right)^{{{1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \mu }} \right. \kern-0pt} \mu }}} A^{{{1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \mu }} \right. \kern-0pt} \mu }}}$$
$$E_{t - 1} (R_{{_{t} }}^{K} ) = \mu \left( {\frac{{(1 - \mu )^{2} (1 + \eta + \gamma + \varpi )\left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right)}}{\eta + \gamma + (1 - \mu )(1 + \varpi )}} \right)^{{\frac{1}{\mu } - 1}} A^{{{1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \mu }} \right. \kern-0pt} \mu }}}$$
$$\frac{{R_{t}^{B} }}{{E_{t - 1} (R_{t}^{K} )}} = \varGamma \left( {\frac{{1 - \beta_{t - 1} }}{{\beta_{t - 1} }}} \right)\left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right),\;\varGamma \equiv \frac{\eta (1 - \mu )}{\eta + \gamma + (1 - \mu )(1 + \varpi )} ,$$
(25)

1.3 Public debt under rational expectations

King expectations of the future value of the ration (25), while assuming E t (τ t+1) = τ t and E t (β t+1) = β t gives

$$\frac{{E_{t} (R_{t + 1}^{B} )}}{{E_{t} (R_{t + 1}^{K} )}} = \varGamma \left( {\frac{{1 - \beta_{t} }}{{\beta_{t} }}} \right)\left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right),\;\quad\varGamma \equiv \frac{\eta (1 - \mu )}{\eta + \gamma + (1 - \mu )(1 + \varpi )}$$

This is solved simultaneously with (3) gives a quadratic equation for the portfolio share of public debt, β t ,

$$\varGamma \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )\beta_{t}^{2} + \left( {1 + \varGamma \left( {\tau_{t} - \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right)} \right)\beta_{t} - \frac{\alpha }{1 + \alpha } - \varGamma \tau_{t} = 0$$
(26)

1.4 Public debt under manipulation of beliefs

As \(\tilde{\beta }_{t}\) is a positive monotonic function of \(_{t} \tilde{R}_{t + 1}^{B}\), we consider its value that maximizes (20),

$$\tilde{\beta }_{t} = \frac{{\varPsi + {{(\varpi } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{(\varpi } \sigma }} \right. \kern-0pt} \sigma })\left( {1 - (1 - \tau_{t} )^{ - 1} } \right)}}{\varPsi + \varpi },\quad\varPsi \equiv \left( {(\eta + \gamma ) + \frac{1 - \mu }{\mu }\left( {1 + \eta + \gamma + \varpi } \right)} \right),$$
(27)

which according to (3) requires a promised return factor of

$$_{t} \tilde{R}_{{_{t + 1} }}^{B} = \left( {1 - \left( {\frac{\alpha }{1 + \alpha }} \right)\left( {\frac{\varPsi + \omega }{{\varPsi - ({\varpi \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {\varpi \sigma }} \right. \kern-0pt} \sigma }){{\tau_{t} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\tau_{t} } {(1 - \tau_{t} )}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {(1 - \tau_{t} )}}}}} \right)} \right)E_{t} (R_{t + 1}^{K} )$$
(28)

This is lagged one period then divided by the actual return in (25) to give the default ratio

$$\frac{{_{t - 1} \tilde{R}_{{_{t} }}^{B} }}{{R_{t}^{B} }} = \frac{{\varPsi - \alpha \omega - \left( {\varPsi + \varpi \left( {(1 + \alpha )\sigma^{ - 1} - \alpha } \right)} \right)\tau_{t - 1} }}{{\varpi \varGamma (1 + \alpha )\left( {1 + (\sigma^{ - 1} - 1)\tau_{t - 1} } \right)\left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right)}}$$
(29)

1.5 Policy-optimal taxes

Returning to Eq. (20), the policy-maker’s preference for taxation is the rate

$$1 - \tau_{t} = \frac{\varPi }{{1 - \sigma \beta_{t} }},{\text{ where}}\;\;\varPi \equiv \frac{\mu (1 + \varpi )}{1 + \eta + \gamma + \varpi } .$$
(30)

Under policy-optimal taxes, Eq. (27) for rational beliefs becomes,

$$\beta = \frac{{{\alpha \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {\alpha {(1 + \alpha )}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {(1 + \alpha )}} + (1 - \varPi )\varGamma }}{1 + (1 - \varPi )\varGamma },\;\varGamma \equiv \frac{\eta (1 - \mu )}{\eta + \gamma + (1 - \mu )(1 + \varpi )}$$
(31)

implying optimal taxes in this case of

$$\tilde{\tau }_{t} = 1 - \frac{\mu }{(1 + \varpi + \eta + \gamma )(1 - \sigma )} .$$
(32)

1.6 Public welfare with the optimal levels of the expenditures

Returning to Eqs. (18) and (19), where \(g_{t}^{P} = \kappa^{P} \left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma \left( {1 - \tau_{t} } \right)} \right)\,w_{t}\), where \(\kappa^{P} \equiv \frac{(1 - \mu )(1 + \eta + \gamma + \varpi )}{\eta + \gamma + (1 - \mu )(1 + \varpi )}\), and \(g_{t}^{N} = \kappa^{N} \left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma \left( {1 - \tau_{t} } \right)} \right)w_{t}\), where \(\kappa^{N} \equiv \frac{\mu \gamma }{\eta + \gamma + (1 - \mu )(1 + \varpi )}\),means Eq. (7) becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \ln Z_{t} = \ln (1 - \tau_{t} ) + \eta \ln (1 - \kappa^{P} - \kappa^{N} )\left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right) \hfill \\ + \omega \ln \left( {(1 - \beta_{t} )\sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right) + \gamma \ln \left( {\kappa^{N} \left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right)} \right) + (1 + \eta + \varpi + \gamma )\ln w_{t} \hfill \\ \end{aligned}$$
(33)

Since Eq. (5) and \(g_{t}^{P} = \kappa^{P} \left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma \left( {1 - \tau_{t} } \right)} \right)w_{t}\) imply

$$w_{t} = \frac{1}{\mu }\ln \left( {(1 - \mu )A} \right) + \left( {\frac{1 - \mu }{\mu }} \right)\ln \left( {\kappa^{P} \left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right)} \right) + \ln k_{t} ,$$
(34)

Eq. (33) is finally presented as

$$\begin{aligned} \ln Z_{t} = (1 + \varpi )\ln (1 - \tau_{t} ) + \varpi \ln (1 - \beta_{t} ) \hfill \\ + \left( {\eta + \gamma + \left( {\frac{1 - \mu }{\mu }} \right)(1 + \eta + \varpi + \gamma )} \right)\ln \left( {\tau_{t} + \beta_{t} \sigma (1 - \tau_{t} )} \right) + .. \hfill \\ \end{aligned} ,$$
(35)

which is the basis for calculating the gains.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Roberts, M.A. Recurrent default or policy-optimal taxation. Econ Change Restruct 50, 279–297 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-017-9211-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-017-9211-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation