Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

A Biodiversity Hotspots Treaty: The Road not Taken

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

After brief introductory comments on the Dasgupta Review, I turn to a subject little discussed in this report, the Convention on Biological Diversity. I explain the many weaknesses of this agreement, and its greatest missed opportunity: a protocol to conserve biodiversity as a global public good. This value of biodiversity represents only a fraction of the total value of conservation, but it’s the fraction that can only be supplied by a global treaty. I explain the flaws in the current approach by parties to the Convention of target setting, the advantages of a focus on biodiversity hotspots, and the reasons another treaty, the World Heritage Convention, has failed to conserve hotspots representing humankind’s biodiversity heritage. I then sketch a model showing that collective action in conserving global biodiversity hotspots can be supported by a self-enforcing treaty. The road not taken looks far more promising than the one we’ve been on since 1992.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A new high seas treaty is now being negotiated, to include rules for establishing marine protected areas in the high seas (rules that, among other purposes, must clarify whether states must consent to having their freedom in these areas restricted or whether such restrictions can be decided by a subset of states).

  2. As of February 2022, of the Convention’s 196 parties, only 133 have joined Nagoya; non-participants include Australia, Canada, and Russia. The United States is a non-party to the Convention and both of its protocols.

  3. Radiative forcing depends on atmospheric concentrations, but also other sources of forcing, including the concentration of non-CO2 greenhouse gases, aerosols, surface albedo, clouds, changes in solar irradiance, volcanoes, etc. Atmospheric temperature depends on radiative forcing, and dynamically on exchanges between the oceans and the atmosphere.

  4. For an early application of this concept in an economics model, see Barrett (1993).

  5. An exception is when a group of sufficient size is able to act so as to change the behavior of the other states, an approach studied by Nordhaus (2015) and Barrett and Dannenberg (2022). Of course, for this approach to work, the set of likeminded countries needs to be at least as large as the set needed to stimulate “tipping.”

  6. According to the IUCN, a little less than 16% of terrestrial area and 8% of marine area is protected as of February 2022; see https://www.protectedplanet.net/en.

  7. https://www.cbd.int/doc/c/efb0/1f84/a892b98d2982a829962b6371/wg2020-02-03-en.pdf.

  8. See https://www.conservation.org/priorities/biodiversity-hotspots.

  9. See Weitzman (1998).

  10. Wilson (2016) notes the potential of the World Heritage Convention for protecting biodiversity in an appendix.

  11. For “natural sites,” the Committee is advised by the International Union for the Conservation of Nature and Natural Resources (IUCN).

  12. https://whc.unesco.org/en/criteria/.

  13. https://whc.unesco.org/en/list/stat/.

  14. https://whc.unesco.org/en/world-heritage-fund/.

  15. See Frey and Steiner (2011). Lynn Meskell, an anthropologist witness of the process observed, “Over the past eight years of my research, I sat through many World Heritage Committee meetings, and I noticed that when it’s time to discuss matters of conservation, most countries’ delegates don’t bother to participate. All they care about is whether their sites end up on the World Heritage List, so that they could use them in tourism strategies.” See https://news.stanford.edu/2018/11/19/stanford-scholar-examines-unescos-world-heritage-program/.

  16. Theoretically, it is even possible that supply of the private good of eco-tourism suffices to conserve the globally optimal amount of biodiversity; see Heal (2003).

  17. The United Kingdom followed the US’s lead, withdrawing in 1985, and rejoining in 1997. The UK’s International Development Secretary wanted the UK to withdraw again in 2018, in response to Trump’s announced withdrawal, but did not win support of the Cabinet.

  18. https://whc.unesco.org/en/world-heritage-fund/.

  19. Another problem is that the Committee favors the listing of sites under the jurisdiction of its own 21 members. A proposal was made to prohibit the Committee from nominating sites under the jurisdiction of its members, but this would have to be approved by the Committee itself, and the Committee rejected the proposal (Meskell 2013).

  20. In the model above, this outcome would only emerge if the parameter values happened to be of the right magnitudes: \({k}_{N}^{*}={n}^{N}\iff {n}^{N}>\left({c}^{S}-{b}^{S}\right)/{b}_{N}^{S}>{n}^{N}-1.\)

References

  • Alvarado-Quesada I and Hans-Peter Weikard (2017) International Environmental Agreements for Biodiversity Conservation: A Game-Theoretic Analysis. Int Environ Agreements 17:731–754

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S (1993) “Optimal Economic Growth and the Conservation of Biological Diversity. In: Barbier EB (ed) Economics and Ecology: New Frontiers in Sustainable Development. Chapman & Hall, London, pp 130–145

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S (1994) The Biodiversity Supergame. Environ Resource Econ 4:111–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S (2001) “International Cooperation for Sale,” European Economic Review, 45(10): 1835–1850, 2001

  • Barrett S (2003) Environment & Statecraft: The Strategy of Environmental Treaty-Making, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2003

  • Barrett S (2007) Why Cooperate? The Incentive to Supply Global Public Goods. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S (2013) Climate Treaties and Approaching Catastrophes,“. J Environ Econ Manag 66(2):235–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S (2016) “Coordination vs. Voluntarism and Enforcement in Sustaining International Environmental Cooperation,“ Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 113(51): 14515–14522

  • Barrett S (2012) and Astrid Dannenberg “Climate Negotiations Under Scientific Uncertainty,“ Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 109(43): 17372–17376

  • Barrett S and Astrid Dannenberg (2014) Sensitivity of Collective Action to Uncertainty about Climate Tipping Points,“. Nat Clim Change 4:36–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S and Astrid Dannenberg (2016) An Experimental Investigation into ‘Pledge and Review’ in Climate Negotiations. Clim Change 138(1):339–352

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S and Astrid Dannenberg (2017) Tipping versus Cooperating to Supply a Public Good. J Eur Econ Association 15(4):910–941

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S and Astrid Dannenberg (2022) The Decision to Link Trade Agreements to the Supply of Global Public Goods. J Association Environ Resource Economists 9(2):273–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta P (2021) The Economics of Biodiversity: The Dasgupta Review. HM Treasury, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Desmet P and Richard Cowling (2004) Using the Species-Area Relationship to Set Baseline Targets for Conservation. Ecol Soc 9(2):11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond JM (1975) The Island Dilemma: Lessons of Modern Biogeographic Studies for the Design of Nature Reserves. Biol Conserv 7:129–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichner T, Rüdiger P (2018) Self-Enforcing Biodiversity Agreements with Financial Support from North to South. Ecol Econ 153:43–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Simon G (2002) Altruistic Punishment in Humans. Nature 415:137–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finus M, Game Theoretic Research on the Design of International Environmental Agreements (2008) Insights, Critical Remarks, and Future Challenges. Int Rev Environ Resource Econ 2:29–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Folke, Carl S, Carpenter B, Walker M, Scheffer T, Elmqvist L, Gunderson, Holling CS (2004) Regime Shifts, Resilience, and Biodiversity in Ecosystem Management. Annu Rev Ecol Evol Syst 35:557–581

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey BS, and Lasse Steiner (2011) World Heritage List: Does it Make Sense? Int J Cult Policy 17(5):555–573

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey BS, Pamini P, and Lasse Steiner (2013) Explaining the World Heritage List: An Empirical Study. Int Rev Econ 60:1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heal G (2003) Bundling Biodiversity. J Association Environ Resource Economists 1(2–3):553–560

    Google Scholar 

  • High Level Panel (2012) Report of the High-Level Panel on Global Assessment of Resources for Implementing the Strategic Plan for Biodiversity 2011–2020, Conference of the Parties to the Convention on Biological Diversity, Eleventh meeting

  • Keesing F et al (2010) The Impacts of Biodiversity on the Emergence and Transmission of Infectious Diseases. Nature 468:647–652

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leopold A (1949) A Sand County Almanac. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • MacArthur RH, Edward OW (1967) The Theory of Island Biogeography. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Mace GM et al (2014) Approaches to Defining a Planetary Boundary for Biodiversity. Glob Environ Change 28:289–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maxwell SL et al (2020) Area-Based Conservation in the Twenty-First Century. Nature 586:217–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meskell L (2013) UNESCO’s World Heritage Convention at 40: Challenging the Economic and Political Order of International Heritage Conservation. Curr Anthropol 54(4):483–494

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mills L, Scott ME, Soulé, Daniel FD (1993) The Keystone-Species Concept in Ecology and Conservation. Bioscience 43(4):219–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myers N, Mittermeier RA, Mittermeier CG, Gustavo AB, da Fonseca, Kent J (2000) Biodiversity Hotspots for Conservation Priorities. Nature 403:853–858

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nature (2020) “New Biodiversity Targets Cannot Afford to Fail,” Nature 578:337–338

  • Nordhaus W (2015) “Climate Clubs: Overcoming Free-Riding in International Climate Policy. “ Am Economic Rev 105(4):1339–1370

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pearce DW, Perrings CA (1995) “Biodiversity Conservation and Economic Development: Local and Global Dimensions. In: Perrings CA, Mäler K-G, Folke C, Holling CS, Jansson B-O (eds) Biodiversity Conservation: Problems and Policies. Kluwer, Dordrecht, pp 23–40

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Pope D and Uri Simonsohn (2011) Round Numbers as Goals: Evidence From Baseball, SAT Takers, and the Lab. Psychol Sci 22(1):71–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rockström J et al (2009) Safe Operating Space for Humanity. Nature 461(7263):472–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schelling TC (1960) The Strategy of Conflict. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Secretariat to the Convention on Biological Diversity (1995) A Call to Action: Decisions and Ministerial Statement from the Second Meeting of the Conference of the Parties to the Convention on Biological Diversity, Montreal: Secretariat of the Convention on Biological Diversity

  • Secretariat to the Convention on Biological Diversity (2020) Global Biodiversity Outlook 5. Secretariat to the Convention on Biological Diversity, Montreal

    Google Scholar 

  • Seijts GH, Gary P, Latham (2000) The Effects of Goal Setting and Group Size on Performance in a Social Dilemma. Can J Behav Sci 32(2):104–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaw MN (2003) International Law. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Simpson R, David RA, Sedjo, and John W. Reid (1996) Valuing Biodiversity for Use in Pharmaceutical Research. J Polit Econ 104(1):163–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Secretariat of the Convention on Biological Diversity (1995) A Call to Action. United Nations Environment Program, Montréal

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler RH (1988) The Ultimatum Game. J Economic Perspect 2(4):195–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner UJ (2001) The Design of Stable International Environmental Agreements: Economic Theory and Political Economy. J Economic Surveys 15(3):377–411

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waldron A et al (2020) “Protecting 30% of the Planet for Nature: Costs, Benefits, and Economic Implications,” https://www.conservation.cam.ac.uk/files/waldron_report_30_by_30_publish.pdf

  • Weitzman ML (1998) The Noah’s Ark Problem. Econometrica 66(6):1279–1298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson EO (2016) Half-Earth: Our Planet’s Fight for Life. Liveright, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Winands S, Karin Holm-Müller, and Hans-Peter Weikard (2013) The Biodiversity Conservation Game with Heterogeneous Countries. Ecol Econ 89:14–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woodley S, Bertzky B, Crawhall N, Dudley N, Londoño JM, MacKinnon K, Redford K, Sandwith T (2012) “Meeting Aichi Target 11: What Does Success Look Like for Protected Area Systems? Parks 18(1):23–36

    Google Scholar 

  • de Zeeuw A (2015) International Environmental Agreements. Annual Rev Resource Econ 7(1):1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Scott Barrett.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Barrett, S. A Biodiversity Hotspots Treaty: The Road not Taken. Environ Resource Econ 83, 937–954 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-022-00670-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-022-00670-5

Navigation