Advertisement

Environmental and Resource Economics

, Volume 59, Issue 2, pp 231–255 | Cite as

The Control of Invasive Species on Private Property with Neighbor-to-Neighbor Spillovers

  • Eli P. Fenichel
  • Timothy J. Richards
  • David W. Shanafelt
Article

Abstract

Invasive pests cross property boundaries. Property managers may have private incentives to control invasive species despite not having sufficient incentive to fully internalize the external costs of their role in spreading the invasion. Each property manager has a right to future use of his own property, but his property may abut others’ properties enabling spread of an invasive species. The incentives for a foresighted property manager to control invasive species have received little attention. We consider the efforts of a foresighted property manager who has rights to future use of a property and has the ability to engage in repeated, discrete control activities. We find that higher rates of dispersal, associated with proximity to neighboring properties, reduce the private incentives for control. Controlling species at one location provides incentives to control at a neighboring location. Control at neighboring locations are strategic complements and coupled with spatial heterogeneity lead to a weaker-link public good problem, in which each property owner is unable to fully appropriate the benefits of his own control activity. Future-use rights and private costs suggest that there is scope for a series of Coase-like exchanges to internalize much of the costs associated with species invasion. Pigouvian taxes on invasive species potentially have qualitatively perverse behavioral effects. A tax with a strong income effect (e.g., failure of effective revenue recycling) can reduce the value of property assets and diminish the incentive to manage insects on one’s own property.

Keywords

Asian citrus psyllid Bioeconomics Citrus Dynamic programming Invasive species Property rights Repeat optimal stopping Spatial externalities Value function approximation 

Notes

Acknowledgments

The funding support for the paper is: We thank David Finnoff and two anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments. This publication was made possible by Grant Number 1R01GM100471-01 from the National Institute of General Medical Sciences (NIGMS) at the National Institutes of Health, by the United States Department of Agriculture, Specialty Crop Research Initiative (USDA-SCRI) Award Number 2010-51181-21246, an award from the Saguaro high performance computing center at Arizona State University, and support from Yale’s high performance computing services. Its contents are solely the responsibility of the authors and do not represent the official views of NIGMS or USDA.

References

  1. Adda J, Cooper R (2003) Dynamic economics, quantitative methods plus applications. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  2. Aubert B (1987) Trioza erytreae Del Guercio and Diaphorina citri Kuwayama (Homoptera: Psylloidea), two vectors of the citrus greening disease: biological aspects and possible control strategies. Fruits 42:149–162Google Scholar
  3. Aubert B (1992) High density planting (HDP) of jiaogan mandarine in the lowland area of Shantou (Guangdong China) and implications for greening control. Proceedings of the Asia Pacific international conference on citriculture, Chiang Mai, Thialand, pp 149–157Google Scholar
  4. Aubert B, Quilici S (1987) Monitoring adult psyllas on yellow traps in Reunion island. Tenth conference of the international organization of citrus virologistsGoogle Scholar
  5. Balikcioglu M, Fackler PL, Pindyck RS (2011) Solving optimal timing problems in environmental economics. Resour Energy Econ 33:761–768Google Scholar
  6. Bird PJWN (1987) The transferability and depletability of externalities. J Environ Econ Manag 14:54–57Google Scholar
  7. Born W, Rauschmayer F, Brauer I (2005) Economic evaluation of biological invasions—a survey. Ecol Econ 55:321–336CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Bowles S (2004) Microeconomics behavior. Insitutions and evolution. Princeton University Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  9. Burnett KM (2006) Introductions of invasive species: failure of the weaker link. Agric Resour Econ Rev 35:21–28Google Scholar
  10. Caputo MR (2005) Foundations of dynamic economic analysis: optimal control theory and applications. Cambridge University Press, New YorkCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Catling HD (1970) Distribution of the psyllid vectors of citrus greening disease, with notes of the biology and bionomics of Diaphorina citri. FAO Plant Prot Bull 18:8–15Google Scholar
  12. Ceddia MG, Heikkila J, Peltola J (2009) Managing invasive alien species with professional and hobby farmers: insights from ecological-economic modelling. Ecol Econ 68:1366–1374CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Chiyaka C, Singer BH, Halbert SE, Morris JG, van Bruggen AHC (2012) Modeling huanglongbing transmission within a citrus tree. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 109:12213–12218CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Coase RH (1960) The problem of social cost. J Law Econ 3:1–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Cocco A, Hoy MA (2008) Toxicity of organosilicone adjuvants and selected pesticides to the Asian citrus psyllid (Hempitera: Psyllidae) and its parasitoid Tamarixia radiata (Hymenoptera: Eulophidae). Fla Entomol 91:610–620Google Scholar
  16. Cornes R (1993) Dyke maintenance and other stories: some neglected types of public goods. Q J Econ 108:259–271CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Costello CJ, Kaffine D (2008) Natural resource use with limited-tenure property rights. J Environ Econ Manag 55:20–36Google Scholar
  18. Couture S, Reynaud A (2011) Forest management under fire risk when forest carbon sequestration has value. Ecol Econ 70:2002–2011CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Diamond PA (1982) Aggregate demand management in search equilibrium. J Polit Econ 90:881–894CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Dixit AK, Pindyck RS (1994) Investment under uncertainty. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
  21. Eiswerth ME, Johnson WS (2002) Managing nonindigenous invasive species: insights from dynamic analysis. Environ Resour Econ 23:319–342CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Epanchin-Niell RS, Wilen JE (2012) Optimal spatial control of biological invasions. J Environ Econ Manag 63:260–270Google Scholar
  23. Fenichel EP (2013) Economic considerations for social distancing and behavioral based policies during an epidemic. J Health Econ 32:440–451CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Fenichel EP, Horan RD, Hickling GJ (2010) Bioeconomic management of invasive insect-vectored diseases. Biol Invasions 12:2877–2893CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Fenichel EP, Castillo-Chavez C, Ceddia MG, Chowell G, Hickling GJ, Holloway G, Horan R, Morin B, Perrings C, Springborn M, Velazquez L, Villalobos C (2011) Adaptive human behavior in epidemiological models. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 108:6306–6311CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Finnoff D, Shogren JF, Leung B, Lodge DM (2007) Take a risk: preferring prevention over control of biological invaders. Ecol Econ 62:216–222CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Francis PJ (1997) Dynamic epidemiology and the market for vaccinations. J Public Econ 63:383–406CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Gaff H, Joshi HR, Lenhart S (2007) Optimal harvesting during an invasion of a sublethal plant pathogen. Environ Devel Econ 12:673–686Google Scholar
  29. Geaun JC (1993) On the shiftable externalities. J Environ Econ Manag 24:30–44Google Scholar
  30. Goetz RU, Zilberman D (2000) The dynamcis of spatial pollution: the case of phosphorus runoff from agricultural land. J Econ Dyn Control 24:143–163CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Gottwald TR (2010) Current epidemiological understanding of citrus huanglongbing. Annu Rev Phytopathol 48:110–139CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Gramig BM, Horan RD (2011) Jointly-determined livestock disease dynamics and decentralised economic behavior. Aust J Agric Resour Econ 55:1–18Google Scholar
  33. Gramig BM, Horan RD, Wolf C (2009) Livestock disease indemnity design when moral hazard is followed by adverse selection. Am J Agric Econ 91:627–641CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Halbert SE, Manjunath KL (2004) Asian citrus psyllid (Sternorrhyncha: Psyllidae) and greening disease of citrus: a literature review and assessment of risk in Florida. Fla Entomol 87:330–353CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Hall DG, Hentz MG (2011) Seasonal flight activity by the Asian citrus psyllid in east central Florida. Entomol Exp Appl 139:75–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Hansen LG (2002) Shiftable externalities: a market solution. Environ Resour Econ 21:221–239CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Hansen ZK, Libecap GD (2004) Small farms, externalities, and the dust bowl of the 1930s. J Polit Econ 112:665–694CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Hartman R (1976) The harvesting decision when a standing forest has value. Econ Inq 14:52–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Holmes TC, Liebhold AM, Kovacs KF, Von Holle B (2010) A spatial-dynamic value transfer model of economic losses from a biological invasion. Ecol Econ 70:86–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Homans F, Horie T (2011) Optimal detection strategies for an established invasive pest. Ecol Econ 70:1129–1138CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Horan RD, Perrings C, Lupi F, Bulte EH (2002) Biological pollution prevention strategies under ignorance: the case of invasive species. Am J Agric Econ 84:1303–1310CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Horan RD, Wolf CA, Fenichel EP, Mathews KHJ (2005) Spatial management of wildlife disease. Rev Agric Econ 27:483–490CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Horan RD, Wolf CA, Fenichel EP, Mathews KHJ (2008) Joint management of wildlife and livestock disease. Environ Resour Econ 41:47–70CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Knowler D (2005) Reassessing the costs of biological invasion: Mnemiopsis leidyi in the Black sea. Ecol Econ 52:187–199CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Leung B, Finnoff D, Shogren JF, Lodge DM (2005) Managing invasive species: rules of thumb for rapid assessment. Ecol Econ 55:24–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Lovell SJ, Stone SF, Fernandez L (2006) The economic impacts of aquatic invasive species: a review of the literature. Agric Resour Econ Rev 35:195–208Google Scholar
  47. Lui Y, Tsai J (2000) Effects of temperature on biology and life table parameters of the Asian citrus psyllid, Diaphorina citri Kuwayama (Homoptera: Psyllidae). Ann Appl Biol 137:201–206CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Marten AL, Moore CC (2011) An options based bioeconomic model for biological and chemical control of invasive species. Ecol Econ 70:2050–2061CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Mehta SV, Haight RG, Homans FR, Polasky S, Venette RC (2007) Optimal detection and control strategies for invasive species management. Ecol Econ 61:234–245CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Miranda MJ, Fackler PL (2002) Applied computation economics and finance. MIT Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  51. Morris RA, Murano RP, Spreen TH (2008) Invasive diseases and fruit tree production: economic tradeoffs of citrus greening control on Florida’s citrus industry. Southern Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting, Dallas, TXGoogle Scholar
  52. Muller NZ, Mendelsohn R (2009) Efficient pollution regulation: getting the prices right. Am Econ Rev 99:1714–1739CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. O’Connell NV, Kallsen CE, Klonsky KM, De Moura RL, (2009) Sample costs to establish and orange orchard and produce oranges, San Joaquin Valley South, University of California Cooperative Extension, Davis, CA, p 25Google Scholar
  54. Perrings C, Fenichel EP, Kinzig AP (2010) Globalization and invasive alien species: trade, pests, and pathogens. In: Mooney H, Williamson M, Perrings C (eds) Bioinvasions and globalization. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 42–55Google Scholar
  55. Pimentel D, Lach L, Zuniga R, Morrison D (2000) Environmental and economic costs of nonindigenous species in the United States. BioScience 50:53–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Polasky S (2010) A model of prevention, detection, and control for invasive species. In: Mooney H, Williamson M, Perrings C (eds) Bioinvasions and globalization. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 100–107Google Scholar
  57. Potapov A (2009) Stochastic model of lake system invasion and its optimal control: neurodynamic programming as a solution method. Nat Resour Model 22:257–288CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Potapov A, Lewis MA, Finnoff D (2007) Optimal control of biological invasions in lake networks. Nat Resour Model 20:351–379CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Richards TJ (2009) California citrus in 2009: impact analysis and policy simulation. Report prepared for the California Citrus Mutual, Exeter, CAGoogle Scholar
  60. Richards TJ, Ellsworth P, Tronstad R, Naranjo S (2010) Market-based instruments for the optimal control of invasive insect species: B. Tabaci in Arizona. J Agric Resour Econ 34:349–367Google Scholar
  61. Richards TJ, Shanafelt D, Fenichel EP (in press) Foreclosures and invasive insect spread: the case of the Asian citrus psyllid. Am J Agric EconGoogle Scholar
  62. Roberts MG, Smith G, Grenfell BT (1995) Mathematical models for macroparasites of wildlife. In: Grenfell BT, Dobson AP (eds) Ecology of infectious diseases in natural populations. Cambridge University Press, New York, pp 177–208CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Rogers ME, Stansley PA, Stelinski LL (2011) Florida citrus pest management guide: Asian citrus psyllid and citrus leafminer. University of Florida IFAS Extension, Gainsville, FLGoogle Scholar
  64. Sanchirico JN, Wilen JE (1999) Bioeconomics of spatial exploitation in a patchy environment. J Environ Econ Manag 37:129–150Google Scholar
  65. Sandmo A (1975) Optimal taxation in the presence of externalities. Swed J Econ 77:86–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. Saphores J-DM (2000) The economic threshold with a stochastic pest population: a real options approach. Am J Agric Econ 82:541–555CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Setamou M, Rodriguez D, Saldana R, Schwarzlose G, Palrang D, Nelson SD (2010) Efficacy and uptake of soil-applied imidacloprid in the control of asian citrus psyllid and citrus leafminer, two foliar-feeding citrus pests. J Econ Entomol 103:1711–1719CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. Sharov AA (2004) Bioeconomics of managing the spread of exotic pest species with barrier zones. Risk Anal 24:879–892CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Sharov AA, Liebhold AM (1998) Bioeconomics of managing the spread of exotic pest species with barrier zones. Ecol Appl 8:833–845Google Scholar
  70. Shaw D, Shaw R-D (1991) The resistibility and shiftability of depletable externalities. J Environ Econ Manag 20:224–233Google Scholar
  71. Shogren JF, Crocker TD (1991) Cooperative and noncooperative protection against transferable adn filterable externalities. Environ Resour Econ 1:195–214CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Sims C, Aadland D, Finnoff D (2010) A dynamic bioeconomic analysis of mountain pine beetle epidemics. J Econ Dyn Control 34:2407–2419Google Scholar
  73. Sims C, Finnoff D (2012) The role of spatial scale in the timing of uncertain environmental policy. J Econ Dyn Control 36:369–382CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  74. Smith MD, Sanchirico JN, Wilen JE (2009a) The economics of spatial-dynamic processes: applications to renewable resources. J Environ Econ Manag 57:104–121Google Scholar
  75. Smith MD, Slott JM, McNamara D, Murray AB (2009b) Beach nourishment as a dynamic capital accumulation problem. J Environ Econ Manag 58:58–71Google Scholar
  76. Stavins RN (2011) The problem of the commons: still unsettled after 100 years. Am Econ Rev 101:81–108CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  77. Sun D, Qi L (1999) On NCP-functions. Comput Optim Appl 13:201–220CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  78. Tsai JH, Liu YH (2000) Biology of Diaphorina citri (Homoptera: Psyllidae) on four host plants. J Econ Entomol 93:1721–1725CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  79. USDA NASS (2012) 2012 California land values and cash rents release. United States Department of Agriculture National Agricultural Statistics Service, Sacramento, CAGoogle Scholar
  80. Van den Berg MA, Deacon DE, Thomas CD (1991) Ecology of the citrus psylla, Trioza erytreae (Hemiptera: Triozidae). Phytophylactica 23:195–200Google Scholar
  81. Vlassenbroeck J, Van Dooren R (1988) A Chebyshev technique for solving nonlinear optimal control problems. IEEE Trans Autom Control 33:333–340CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  82. Warziniack T, Finnoff D, Bossenbroek J, Shogren JF, Lodge D (2011) Stepping stones for biological invasion: a bioeconomic model of tranferable risk. Environ Resour Econ 50:605–627CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  83. Xepapadeas A (2010) The spatial dimension in environmental and resource economics. Environ Devel Econ 15:747–758CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  84. Xu H, Ding H, Li M, Qiang S, Guo J, Han Z, Huang Z, Sun H, He S, Wu H, Wan F (2006) The distribution and economic losses of alien species invasion to China. Biol Invasions 8:1495–1500CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2013

Authors and Affiliations

  • Eli P. Fenichel
    • 1
  • Timothy J. Richards
    • 2
  • David W. Shanafelt
    • 3
  1. 1.Yale School of Forestry and Environmental StudiesNew HavenUSA
  2. 2.Morrison School of Agribusiness and Resource ManagementArizona State UniversityMesaUSA
  3. 3.School of Life SciencesArizona State UniversityTempeUSA

Personalised recommendations