Abstract
We present a dynamic game of search and learning about the productivity of competing fishing locations. Perfect Bayesian Nash equilibrium search patterns for non-cooperating fishermen and members of an information sharing cooperative are compared with first-best outcomes. Independent fishermen do not internalize the full value of information, and do not replicate first-best search. A fishing cooperative faces a free-riding problem, as each coop member prefers that other members undertake costly search for information. Pooling contracts among coop members may mitigate, but are not likely to eliminate free-riding. Our results explain the paucity of information sharing in fisheries and suggest regulators use caution in advocating cooperatives as a solution to common pool inefficiencies in fisheries.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.



Notes
According to U.S. Department of Agriculture (2012), there were 37 fishing cooperatives operating in the US in 2010. See Kitts and Edwards (2003) for a discussion of US legislation, the Fisheries Collective Marketing Act of 1934 and the American Fisheries Act of 1998, that allow the formation of fishing cooperatives.
Management problems ranging from bycatch, to the design of marine protected areas have been linked to problems of information acquisition and information sharing in fisheries (Abbott and Wilen 2010; Marcoul and Weninger 2008; Costello and Deacon 2007; Curtis and McConnell 2004). The North Pacific Fishery Management Council (2011) discusses the use of fishing cooperatives in the Gulf of Alaska Pollock fishery to reduce incidental catch of Chinook salmon, stating cooperatives will “facilitate information sharing and fleet coordination that could be important to achieving Chinook avoidance (pp. 3, emphasis added).” Amendment 16 to the Northeast Multispecies Fisheries Management Plan pushes for expansion of the use of fishing cooperatives (New England Fishery Management Council 2010).
Palmer (1990) finds that radio transmissions of Maine lobster fishermen convey detailed information about lobster size and fishing locations during pre-molting periods when lobster are hidden in rocks and less accessible to trap gear, i.e., information is shared when it has little value.
Gatewood (1984) identifies an example of such a synergy in the Alaskan purse seine fishery, where managers tightly control the length of openings. The author notes that “While it is true that one boat can scout as wide an area in four days as four boats can in one day, the utility of the information collected by the four boats scouting the day before the opening is much greater, provided they share what each has observed (pp. 362).” It is important to note that the information gathering setting for salmon seiner’s differs from the one that is modeled in this paper.
Halibut are bottom fish that are not observable with sonar equipment; fishing success is not known until gear is soaked and retrieved and captured fish are counted.
The model can be extended to consider correlation in beliefs (Marcoul and Weninger 2008). Correlated beliefs alter search behavior quantitatively. Our main insights regarding the efficiency of independent search and free-riding within fishing coops do not change under correlated beliefs.
Adding a third choice, “stay at port,” complicates notation with few additional insights for information sharing.
Alternate specifications for the congestion penalty were explored, e.g., site specific congestion penalties whose size was a function of the observed payoff signal (\(\kappa _j=\kappa (s_{i,j})\)). We found no qualitative change in the results and therefore maintain the simpler formulation.
The common prior is a standard assumption in the literature and a good starting point for our analysis. For a thorough description of the literature on the common prior assumption see Morris (1995).
Though analytic solutions are preferred, two of the first-best expected payoff functions, \(W_{1,2}\) and \(W_{2,1}\), have no closed form solution. As such, we turn to numeric methods to analyze equilibrium search patterns and provide comparative dynamics on model parameters.
Our approach follows the “new institutional economics” viewpoint, which emphasizes the role of transactions costs, property rights, and agency relationships for understanding organizational structure (Fama 1980; Williamson 1975; Alchian and Demsetz 1972). A comprehensive review of contracts that assign rights and residual claims within a fishing cooperative is beyond the scope of this paper. See Fama and Jensen (1983) for additional discussion of contracting in producer organizations.
The shape and location of \(\bar{V}^c\) and \(V_i\) will also depend on beliefs. Our numerical simulations reveal that \(V_i\) can exceed \(\bar{V}^c\) over some regions of the belief space. This result arises because information, which is more available in a coop, lowers belief variance, which implies lower probability of extreme high payoff outcomes.
References
Abbott J, Wilen JE (2010) Voluntary cooperation in the commons? Evaluating the sea state program with reduced form and structural models. Land Econ 86(1):131–154
Alchian A, Demsetz H (1972) Production, information costs, and economic organization. Am Econ Rev 62(5):777–795
Andersen R (1980) Hunt and conceal: information management in newfoundland deep-sea trawler fishing. In: Tefft SK (ed) Secrecy: a cross-cultural perspective. Human Science Press, New York, pp 205–228
Carpenter J, Seki E (2005) Do social preferences increase productivity? Field experimental evidence from fishermen in Toyama Bay. IZA DP No. 1697. Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn
Costello C, Deacon R (2007) The efficiency gains from fully delineating rights in an ITQ fishery. Mar Res Econ 22(4):347–361
Costello C, Gaines SD, Lynham J (2008) Can catch shares prevent fisheries collapse? Science 321(5896):1678–1681
Costello C, Polasky S (2008) Optimal harvesting of stochastic spatial resources. J Environ Econ Manage 56(1):1–18
Curtis RE, McConnell KE (2004) Incorporating information and expectations in fishermen’s spatial decisions. Mar Resour Econ 19:131–143
Fama EF (1980) Agency problems and the theory of the firm. J Politi Econ 88:88–307
Fama EF, Jensen MC (1983) Separation of ownership and control. J Law Econ XXVI:301–325
Freixas X, Kihlstrom R (1984) Risk aversion and information demand. In: Boyer M, Kihlstrom RE (eds) Bayesian models in economic theory. North-Holland Pub. Co., New York, pp 93–104
Gaspart F, Seki E (2003) Cooperation, status seeking and competitive behaviour: theory and evidence. J Econ Behav Organ 51(1):51–77
Gatewood J (1984) Cooperation, competition, and synergy: information-sharing groups among Southeast Alaskan salmon seiners. Am Ethnol 11(2):350–370
Gibbons R (1992) Game theory for applied economists. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ
Gilman EL, Dalzell P, Martin S (2006) Fleet communication to abate fisheries bycatch. Mar Policy 30:360–366
Haynie AC, Hicks RL, Schnier KE (2009) Common property, information, and cooperation: commercial fishing in the Bering Sea. Ecol Econ 69:406–413
Heintzelman M, Salant SW, Schott S (2009) Putting free-riding to work: a partnership solution to the common-property problem. J Environ Econ Manage 57:309–320
Holland D (2010) Markets, pooling and insurance for managing bycatch in fisheries. Ecol Econ 70:121–133
Holland D, Jannot JE (2012) Bycatch risk pools for the us west coast groundfish fishery. Ecol Econ 78:132–147
Kaffine DT, Costello C (2011) Utilization of spatially connected renewable resources. BE J Econ Anal Policy 11:15 (Contributions) doi:10.2202/1935-1682.2714
Kitts A, Edwards S (2003) Cooperatives in US fisheries: realizing the potential of the fishermen’s collective marketing act. Mar Policy 27:357–366
Knapp G (2008) The Chignik salmon cooperative, FAO Fisheries Technical Paper No. 504. In: Townsend R, Shotton R, Uchida H (eds) Case studies in fisheries self-governance. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome, pp 335–348
Lynham J (2006) Schools of fishermen: a theory of information sharing in spatial search. Department of Economics, UCSB Working Paper
MacCall AD (1990) Dynamic geography of marine fish populations. University of Washington Press, Seattle
Mangel M, Clark C (1986) Search theory in natural resource modeling. Nat Resour Model 1:1–54
Marcoul P, Weninger Q (2008) Search and active learning with correlated information: empirical evidence from mid-Atlantic clam fishermen. J Econ Dyn Control 32(6):1921–1948
McConnell K, Price M (2006) The lay system in commercial fisheries: origin and implications. J Environ Econ Manage 51(3):295–307
Morris S (1995) The common prior assumption in economic theory. Econ Philos 11:227–253
National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (2010) National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA) catch share policy. Available online: http://www.nmfs.noaa.gov/sfa/domes_fish/catchshare/index.htm
New England Fishery Management Council (2010) New England Fisheries Management Council (NEFMC): final amendment 16 to the northeast multispecies fishery management plan. Available online: http://www.nefmc.org/nemulti/index.html
North Pacific Fishery Management Council (2011) (NPFMC) Discussion paper on cooperatives: gulf of Alaska chinook salmon bycatch. Available online at: http://www.fakr.noaa.gov/npfmc/current_issues/bycatch/211GOAChinookCoops.pd
Orbach MK (1977) Hunters, seamen and entrepreneurs: the tuna seinermen of San Diego. University of California Press, Berkeley
Palmer CT (1990) Telling the truth (up to a point): radio communication among Maine lobstermen. Hum Org 49(2):157–163
Smith M (2000) Spatial search and fishing location choice: methodological challenges of empirical modeling. Am J Agric Econ 82(5):1198–1206
Uchida H, Baba O (2008) Fishery management and the pooling arrangement in the Sakuraebi Fishery in Japan. In: Case studies in fisheries self-governance, pp 175–190
Uchida H, Wilen JE (2005) Harvester cooperative. Pooling arrangements and market power. Department of Agriculture and Resource Economics, UC Davis Working Paper
U.S. Department of Agriculture (2012) United States Department of Agriculture: business and cooperative programs: number of cooperatives and memberships by major business activities 2009. Available online: http://www.rurdev.usda.gov/rbs/coops/data.htm
Wilen JE, Richardson EJ (2008) Rent generation in the Alaskan pollock conservation cooperative. In: Case studies in fisheries self-governance, pp 361–368
Williamson O (1975) Markets and hierarchies: analysis and antitrust implications. The Free Press, New York
Wilson J (1990) Fishing for knowledge. Land Econ 66(1):12–29
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
The authors thank Charles Zheng, Michael Springborn, and seminar participants at the North American Association of Fisheries Economists Forum 2009, Applied Agriculture and Economics Association Meeting 2009, and Heartland Environmental and Resource Economics Workshop 2009 for helpful suggestions. Weninger acknowledges financial support from the National Science Foundation under grant SES # 0527728.
Electronic supplementary material
Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.
Appendices
Appendix 1: Belief Updating
Three belief updating scenarios are possible in this model: no signal, one signal, or two signals about the profitability of a fishing site. Under the independence assumption—payoffs across sites are independent—a signal from site \(k\) provides no new information about site \(j\). As such, updated beliefs at site \(j\) equal the prior belief, regardless of the information observed in the signal \(s_{i,k}\).
Suppose, instead, that a single signal from site \(j\) is observed. For prior beliefs \(\mu _{i,j},\ \sigma ^2_{i,j}\), and single payoff signal \(s_{i,j}\), the updated beliefs of fisherman \(i\) at site \(j\) are given as,
where \(\theta _{i,j}=\sigma ^2/(\sigma ^2+\sigma ^2_{i,j})\in [0,1]\) weights the new information contained in the signal against prior beliefs. As uncertainty is resolved, more weight is placed on the prior.
Suppose now that two signals are available to fisherman \(i\) from site \(j\); one from fisherman \(i\) and the other from \(-i\). Then updated beliefs at \(j\) are given as,
where \(\bar{s}_j\) denotes the average payoff signal observed at site \(j\) and \(\theta _{i,j}=\sigma ^2/(\sigma ^2+2\sigma ^2_{i,j})\in [0,1]\) again weights the new information (from two signals) against prior beliefs.
Appendix 2: Bayesian Nash Equilibrium
This section solves the date \(t_2\) Bayesian game for independent risk neutral fishermen. We solve for the thresholds \(s_i^U, s_i^L, s_{-i}^U\), and \(s_{-i}^L\) from (4), which separate feasible signals into regions. There are four possible scenarios to consider depending on the period 1 site choices. We present the calculations for the case where both fishermen fish site 1 in the first fishing period. The analysis of the remaining cases follows analogously and is not repeated.
We begin by specifying how fishermen form beliefs about beliefs. Since both fishermen fished site 1 in the first period, \(i\)’s belief about \(-i\)’s private information should be a function of \(s_{i,1}\), i.e., \(i\)’s private information obtained from fishing site 1. The best information available about \(-i\)’s beliefs comes from \(i\)’s updated beliefs. As such, each fisherman believes they share the same updated beliefs about sites 1 and 2.
Suppose \(s_{-i}^U\) and \(s_{-i}^L\) exist such that the representative fisherman’s counterpart plays the strategy outlined in Eq. (4). For the representative fishermen with \(s_{i,1} \in [s_i^L,\ s_i^U]\) to play a mixed strategy at \(t_2, a'_i \in (0,1)\), it must be the case that, based on his conjecture about his counterpart’s strategy, he is indifferent between fishing site 1 and site 2. Setting the expected payoff of fishing these sites equal and solving for \(a'_{-i}\) finds,
Using the same method, we can calculate the mixed fishing strategy for the representative fisherman, \(a'_i\).
In a BNE, each player’s action must be optimal subject to their Bayesian updated belief about the strategy of their rival. Using \(a'_i\) and \(a'_{-i}\), we derive four equations that define the parameters \(s_i^U, s_i^L, s_{-i}^U\), and \(s_{-i}^L\) that will satisfy a BNE.
The representative fisherman believes that his counterpart is indifferent between mixing and fishing site 1 when \(a'_{-i}\) exactly equals one (his counterpart knows that this is the representative fisherman’s belief). For site 1 to be strictly dominant, it must be that site 1 is still preferred even under the worst case (when both fish the site). Using this fact, the updating rules in Appendix 1, and the strategy profile in Eq. (4), the representative fisherman’s upper signal threshold \(s_i^U\) must satisfy
where \(\theta _{i,1}=\sigma ^2/(\sigma ^2+\sigma ^2_{i,1})\).
Similarly, fisherman \(i\) believes his counterpart is indifferent between mixing and fishing site 2 when \(a_{-i}\) exactly equals zero (his counterpart knows that this is the representative fisherman’s belief). For site 2 to be strictly dominant, it must be that site 2 is still preferred even under the worst case (when both fish the site). Using this fact and given the strategy profile, the representative fisherman’s lower signal threshold \(s_i^L\) must satisfy
Using the same argument, we construct the following for fisherman \(-i\):
The thresholds that satisfy the BNE , \(s_i^U, s_i^L, s_{-i}^U\), and \(s_{-i}^L\), defined by Eqs. (12)–(15), must simultaneously hold.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Evans, K.S., Weninger, Q. Information Sharing and Cooperative Search in Fisheries. Environ Resource Econ 58, 353–372 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-013-9701-8
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-013-9701-8
Keywords
- Search
- Information sharing
- Bayesian learning
- Fisheries cooperatives
JEL Classification
- Q22
- D8