Advertisement

Computational Economics

, Volume 49, Issue 3, pp 343–361 | Cite as

Algorithmic Representations of Managerial Search Behavior

  • William M. Tracy
  • Dmitri G. Markovitch
  • Lois S. Peters
  • B. V. Phani
  • Deepu Philip
Article
  • 247 Downloads

Abstract

We use targeted behavioral experiments to test the extent to which greedy algorithms replicate search behavior. Many simulation models use greedy algorithms to represent a firm’s trial-and-error based exploration (i.e., backward-looking search). This implies that managers always reject changes that decrease performance relative to the status quo. Although we observe significant heterogeneity in backward-looking search behavior, over 50 % of our subjects deviate from greedy search behavior by occasionally preserving performance-decreasing changes. The likelihood of such preservation was inversely related to the magnitude of the performance decrease. While search behavior is likely context specific, our analysis suggests that non-greedy firm search cannot be dismissed outright. Substituting non-greedy algorithms for greedy ones will alter the behavior of some simulation models used in economic research. We recommend that future work in this area report whether key findings are dependent on the use of greedy or non-greedy search algorithms. We also suggest that researchers explicitly discuss which algorithm best represents backward-looking search in the phenomenon under study.

Keywords

Greedy algorithms Search behavior NK models Simulation methods Behavioral experiments 

Notes

Acknowledgments

The authors gratefully acknowledge support for this research from Syndicate Bank Entrepreneurship Research and Training Centre (SBERTC)-IIT Kanpur. The authors are also grateful to David Gautschi, whose input was invaluable at the inception of this research project.

References

  1. Abramson, C., Currim, I. S., & Sarin, R. (2005). An experimental investigation of the impact of information on competitive decision making. Management Science, 51(2), 195–207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Alkemade, F., La Poutré, J. A., & Amman, H. M. (2006). Robust evolutionary algorithm design for socioeconomic simulation. Computational Economics, 28(4), 355–370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Apesteguia, J., Azmat, G., & Iriberri, N. (2012). The impact of gender composition on team performance and decision. Management Science, 58(1), 78–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Arundel, A. (2001). The relative effectiveness of patents and secrecy for appropriation. Research Policy, 30(4), 611–624.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Audia, P. G., Locke, E. A., & Smith, K. G. (2000). The paradox of success: An archival and a laboratory study of strategic persistence following radical environmental change. Academy of Management Journal, 43(5), 837–853.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Auerswald, P., Kauffman, S., Lobo, J., & Shell, K. (2000). The production recipes approach to modeling technological innovation: An application to learning by doing. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 24(3), 389–450.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Axelrod, R. (1997). The complexity of cooperation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  8. Babb, E., Leslie, M., & Van Slyke, M. (1966). The potential of business-gaming methods in research. The Journal of Business, 39(4), 465–472.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Billinger, S., Stieglitz, N., & Schumacher, T. R. (2013). Search on rugged landscapes: An experimental study. Organization Science, 25(1), 93–108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Burton, R., & Obel, B. (2011). Computational modeling for what-is, what-might-be, and what-should-be studies—And triangulation. Organization Science, 22(5), 1195–1202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Davis, J., Eisenhardt, K., & Bingham, C. (2007). Developing theory through simulation methods. Academy of Management Review, 32, 480–499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Cangelosi, V., & Dill, W. (1965). Organizational learning: Observations toward a theory. Administrative Science Quarterly, 10(2), 175–203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Cormen, T., Leiserson, C., & Rivest, R. (1990). Introduction to algorithms. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  14. Ethiraj, S. K., & Levinthal, D. A. (2009). Hoping for A to Z while rewarding only A: Complex organizations and multiple goals. Organization Science, 20(1), 4–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Fang, C., Lee, J., & Schilling, M. A. (2010). Balancing exploration and exploitation through structural design: The isolation of subgroups and organizational learning. Organization Science, 21(3), 625–642.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Fleming, L., & Sorenson, O. (2001). Technology as a complex adaptive system: evidence from patent data. Research Policy, 30(7), 1019–1039Google Scholar
  17. Ganco, M., & Hoetker, G. (2009). NK modeling methodology in the strategy literature: Bounded search on a rugged landscape. Research Methodology in Strategy and Management, 5, 237–268.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Gavetti, G., & Levinthal, D. (2000). Looking forward and looking backward: Cognitive and experiential search. Administrative Science Quarterly, 45(1), 113–137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Gavetti, G., Levinthal, D., & Rivkin, J. (2005). Strategy making in novel and complex worlds, the power of analogy. Strategic Management Journal, 26, 691–712.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Geisendorf, S. (2010). Searching NK fitness landscapes: On the trade off between speed and quality in complex problem solving. Computational Economics, 35(4), 395–406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Harrison, G., & List, J. (2004). Field experiments. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(4), 1009–1055.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Harrison, J., Lin, Z., Carroll, G., & Carley, K. (2007). Simulation modeling in organizational and management research. Academy of Management Review, 32(4), 1229–1245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Kahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics. American Economic Review, 93(5), 1449–1475.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Kauffman, S. (1993). Origins of lrder: Self-organization and selection in evolution. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  25. Kauffman, S., Lobo, J., & Macready, W. (2000). Optimal search on a technology landscape. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 43(2), 141–166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Knudsen, T., & Levinthal, D. (2007). Two faces of search. Organization Science, 18(1), 39–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Kollman, K., Miller, J., & Page, S. (2000). Decentralization and the search for policy solutions. Journal of Law and Economic Organization, 16, 102–128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Lazer, D., & Friedman, A. (2007). Parallel problem solving: The social structure of exploration and exploitation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 52(4), 667–694.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Lenox, M. J., Rockart, S. F., & Lewin, A. Y. (2007). Interdependency, competition, and industry dynamics. Management Science, 53(4), 599–615.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Lippman, S. A., & McCall, J. (1976). The economics of job search: A survey. Economic inquiry, 14(2), 155–189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. List, J. (2006). The behavioralist meets the market: Measuring social preferences and reputation effects in actual transactions. Journal of Political Economy, 114(1), 1–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Lowe, R. A., & Ziedonis, A. A. (2006). Overoptimism and the performance of entrepreneurial firms. Management Science, 52(2), 173–186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Mathieu, J. E., & Schulze, W. (2006). The influence of team knowledge and formal plans on episodic team process–performance relationships. Academy of Management Journal, 49(3), 605–619.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Miller, J., & Page, S. (2007). Complex adaptive systems: An introduction to computational models of social life. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  35. Mitchell, M. (1998). An introduction to genetic algorithms. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
  36. Rivkin, J. (2000). Imitation of complex strategies. Management Science, 46(6), 824–844.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Rivkin, J., & Siggelkow, N. (2002). Organizational sticking points on NK landscapes. Complexity, 7(5), 31–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Russell, S., & Norvig, P. (2009). Artificial intelligence: A modern approach. Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
  39. Siggelkow, N., & Rivkin, J. (2006). When exploration backfires: Unintended consequences of multilevel organizational search. Academy of Management Journal, 49(4), 779–795.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Simon, H. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69, 99–118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Staw, B. (1976). Keep deep in the big muddy: A study of escalating commitment to a chosen course of action. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 16, 27–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Tracy, W., Kumar, M., & Paczkowski, W. (2013). Parametric interdependence, learning-by-doing, and industrial structure. Computational and Mathematical Organization Theory, 19(4), 580–600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Tracy, W. (2014). Paradox lost: The evolution of strategies in Selten’s chain store game. Computational Economics, 43(1), 83–103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2016

Authors and Affiliations

  • William M. Tracy
    • 1
  • Dmitri G. Markovitch
    • 1
  • Lois S. Peters
    • 1
  • B. V. Phani
    • 2
  • Deepu Philip
    • 2
  1. 1.Rensselaer Polytechnic InstituteTroyUSA
  2. 2.Indian Institute of TechnologyKanpurIndia

Personalised recommendations