“Ever tried. Ever failed. No matter. Try again. Fail again. Fail better.” Beckett, Worstward Ho (1983)
Beckett, Worstward Ho (1983)
Abstract
This article synthesizes a number of the findings and themes emerging from the various case studies presented about the efficacy of the transplantation process of the EU consumer acquis in some of the EU accession and new Member States. Specifically, the article examines the process of incorporation through the lens of the domestication of the consumer rules either through the making of the local consumer laws or their subsequent enforcement in the case study jurisdictions. The overall conclusions from the case studies are that accession pressures are an important impetus for legal reform in consumer law, that there is limited tailoring of the rules in their transposition, and that there is slow take up by local actors in the resolution of consumer problems. The article suggests that getting it right in the law-making process in tailoring the rules to local needs or the extant local law may not be crucial for their subsequent efficacy, both because deliberations about the efficacy and fit of the rules may be irresolvable ex ante and because the relevant collocutors often do not exist at the time of original enactment of the consumer laws. Yet if the transplanted rules can be enlivened through local institutions as spaces for contestation of the rights and responsibilities that arise under consumer law, they can be domesticated or contextualized precisely through processes of ongoing contestation. From that perspective, it is institutional diversity in implementation in different jurisdictions, remedial hybridity and EU monitoring of the efficacy of local solutions that can help unblock suboptimal local outcomes.
This is a preview of subscription content,
to check access.Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
Note that the (largely) functional question of the style of social control over economic life can be conceptually distinct from the (largely) historical question of legal origin.
Thus, Rodrik (2000) specifically criticizes the use of developed nation templates and best-practices in the process of institution building precisely for this reason.
I thank Hans Micklitz for this point.
In the context of post-conflict or divided societies, an interesting counter-point is provided by the literature suggesting that “consumerism” is a source of political possibilities and a force for overcoming the politics of division on bases such as class or ethnicity (Whitman 2007, pp. 397, 343).
In the essay quoted earlier, Veblen observed that an evolutionary economic account would be “the theory of a process of cultural growth as determined by the economic interest, a theory of a cumulative sequence of economic institutions stated in terms of the process itself” (Veblen 1898, p. 393).
Note that evolutionary in this context can be intended in its ordinary relatively non-technical meaning of the identification and following of change over time. However, to the extent that there are mechanisms for generating (or at least maintaining) diversity among different implementation institutions, as well as mechanisms for the identification and selection of improvements from among those, then it can also have a more focused interpretation (cf Granovetter 1985, p. 503).
By contrast, Josipović reports a form of peer review by an expert group charged by the EU Commission to assess the already enacted provisions on collective action in the Croatian act, with proposals for amendments to resolve existing shortcomings.
Case C-472/10 Nemzeti Fogyasztóvédelmi Hatóság v Invitel Távközlési Zrt., 26.4.2012 (CJEU).
Case C-415/11 Mohamed Aziz v Catalunyacaixa, 14.3.2013 (CJEU).
Such flexibility might be provided by instruments such as the EU Commission report evaluating the operation of the UCPD, mentioned by Cseres and Balogh and Namyslowska, though both contributions suggest a greater focus on the enforcement deficiencies at national level, as opposed to the deficiencies of the EU instrument itself in the Commission’s first evaluation report.
I thank Hans Micklitz for this point.
On the successful use of the Ombudsman institution in Scandinavian countries for the implementation of the consumer acquis see the work of Bakardjieva Engelbrekt (2003).
Karanikić-Mirić suggests that these might be the reasons for which an on-going EU consultancy project on consumer policy in Serbia is suggesting the broadening of administrative powers and competences, including those of the inspectorates. Consistent with the theme of questioning of existing arrangements, Fejős reports a process of review of the role of that institution.
Karanikić-Mirić notes that the consumer law curriculum in university legal education continues to be non-existent.
The question of the decision-making, punitive, and remedial powers of administrative agencies appears to have presented constitutional problems in a number of the states of former Yugoslavia, and at least with respect to the competition agency (if not others), jurisdictions such as Serbia and Croatia have crossed the rubicon (Fejős).
On this point, a number of authors have noted the significance of Directive 2006/2004 on cooperation between national authorities responsible for the enforcement of consumer protection.
One might also pose the reverse question about the CPCA’s pursuit of the case against the principal electricity distributor in Albania discussed by Djurović: apart from its consumer protection aspect, the case surely also touches on the problems of funding for the USO, investment in the network, as well as security and stability of supply, which may or may not be considered by a consumer agency.
Tools such as the database of unfair contract terms as found by courts in different jurisdictions mentioned by Gavrilović can aid such processes.
References
Bakardjieva Engelbrekt, A. (2003). Fair trading law in flux? National legacies, institutional choice and the process of Europeanisation (Doctoral Dissertation, Stockholm University).
Bakardjieva Engelbrekt, A. (2006). Grey zones, legitimacy deficits and boomerang effects: On the implications of extending the acquis to Central and Eastern Europe. Swedish Yearbook of European Law, 1, 1–36.
Bakardjieva Engelbrekt, A. (2009). Toward an institutional approach to comparative economic law? In A. Bakardjieva Engelbrekt & J. Nergelius (Eds.), New directions in comparative law (pp. 213–251). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Berkowitz, D., Pistor, K., & Richard, J.-F. (2003). Economic development, legality, and the transplant effect. European Economic Review, 47, 165–195.
Botta, M., & Svetlicnii, A. (2012). Article 102 TFEU as a tool of market regulation: Excessive enforcement against excessive pricing in the new EU Member States and candidate countries. European Competition Journal, 8, 473–496.
Cafaggi, F., & Gorywoda, L. (2013). Conceptual considerations. In The Europeanization of private law in Central and Eastern European countries: Preliminary findings and research agenda, EUI Law Working Paper 2013-07.
Calliess, G.-P., & Renner, M. (2009). Between law and social norms: The evolution of global governance. Ratio Juris, 22, 260–280.
Cappelletti, M., Seccombe, M., & Weiler, J. (Eds.). (1986). Integration through law: Europe and the American federal experience. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter.
de Burca, G. (2013). EU external relations: The governance mode of foreign policy. In B. van Vooren, S. Blockmans, & J. Wouters (Eds.), The EU’s role in global governance: The legal dimension (pp. 39–58). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Djurović, M. (2011). Serbian contract law: Its development and the new Serbian civil code. European Review of Contract Law, 7, 65–77.
Gal, M. (2010). When the going gets tight: Institutional solutions when antitrust enforcement resources are scarce. Loyola University of Chicago Law Journal, 41, 417–441.
Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. The American Journal of Sociology, 91, 481–510.
Jarvis, C. (1999). The rise and fall of pyramid schemes in Albania. IMF Working Paper 99/98. Available at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/1999/wp9998.pdf. Accessed 10 July 2013.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2008). The economic consequences of legal origin. Journal of Economic Literature, 46, 285–332.
Legrand, P. (1997). The impossibility of legal transplants. Maastricht Journal of European & Comparative Law, 4, 111–124.
Legrand, P. (2006). Antivonbar. Journal of Comparative Law, 1, 13–40.
Mahoney, J., & Thelen, K. (2010). A theory of gradual institutional change. In J. Mahoney & K. Thelen (Eds.), Explaining institutional change: Ambiguity, agency, and power (pp. 1–37). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mattei, U. (1994). Efficiency in legal transplants: An essay in comparative law and economics. International Review of Law and Economics, 14, 3–19.
Micklitz, H.-W. (2009). The visible hand of European regulatory private law—The transformation of European private law from autonomy to functionalism in competition and regulation. Yearbook of European Law, 28, 3–59.
Micklitz, H-W. (2013a). The case of consumer law. In The Europeanization of private law in Central and Eastern European countries: Preliminary findings and research agenda, EUI Law Working Paper 2013-07.
Micklitz, H-W. (2013b). Herd behaviour and third party impact as a legal concept – On tulips, pyramid games and asset-backed securities. In S. Grundmann, F. Moslein & K. Reisenhuber (Eds.), Contract governance: Dimensions in law and interdisciplinary research. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Forthcoming.
Pistor, K. (2011). Contesting property rights: Towards an integrated theory of institutional and system change. Global Jurist, 11(2), 1–26. Frontiers, Article 6.
Putnam, R. (1993). Making democracy work: Civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Reich, N. (2007). Horizontal liability in EC Law—“Hybridisation“ of remedies for compensation in case of breaches of EC rights. Common Market Law Review, 44, 705–742.
Rodrik, D. (2000). Institutions for high-quality growth: What they are and how to acquire them. Studies in Comparative International Development, 35, 3–31.
Sabel, C. (1994). Learning by monitoring: The institutions of economic development. In N. Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.), The handbook of economic sociology (pp. 137–165). Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Sabel, C., & Zeitlin, J. (2008). Learning from difference: The new architecture of experimentalist governance in the EU. European Law Journal, 14, 271–327.
Sabel, C., & Zeitlin, J. (2010). Experimentalist governance in the EU: Towards a new architecture. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Sacco, R. (1991). Legal formants: A dynamic approach to comparative law (Part II). American Journal of Comparative Law, 39, 343–401.
Stolker, C. J. J. M. (1997). Drafting a new civil code for Albania—Some personal experiences contrasted with the World Bank's initial lessons. available at https://openaccess.leidenuniv.nl/bitstream/handle/1887/1302/174_031.pdf?sequence=1
Svetiev, Y. (2007). Antitrust governance: The new wave of antitrust. Loyola University of Chicago Law Journal, 38, 593–694.
Svetiev, Y. (2010). Networked competition governance in the EU: Delegation, decentralization or experimentalist architecture? In C. Sabel & J. Zeitlin (Eds.), Experimentalist governance in the EU: Towards a new architecture (pp. 79–120). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Svetiev, Y. (2012). W(h)ither private law in face of the regulatory deluge. In H-W. Micklitz & Y. Svetiev (Eds.), Self-Sufficient European regulatory private law: A viable concept?, EUI Law Working Paper 2012-31, (http://hdl.handle.net/1814/24534)
Teubner, G. (1998). Good faith in British law or how unifying law ends up in new divergences. Modern Law Review, 61, 11–32.
Tulmets, E. (2010). Experimentalist governance in EU external relations: Enlargement and European neighbourhood policy. In C. Sabel & J. Zeitlin (Eds.), Experimentalist governance in the EU: Towards a new architecture (pp. 297–324). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Veblen, T. (1898). Why is economics not an evolutionary science? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 12, 373–397.
Wai, R. (2002). Transnational liftoff and juridical touchdown: The regulatory function of private international law in an era of globalization. Columbia Journal of Transnational Law, 40, 209–274.
Weiler, J. (1981). The Community system: the dual character of supranationalism. Yearbook of European Law, 1, 267–306.
Wheeler, R. (2000). Legal transfer and the legitimation of law: Implications of farm family property provisions in Albanian legislation. University of Wisconsin–Madison Land Tenure Center Working Paper No. 39, Available at http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/12776/1/ltcwp39.pdf
Whitman, J. (2007). Consumerism versus producerism: A study in comparative law. Yale Law Journal, 117, 340–406.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
The author wishes to acknowledge the support of the ERC funded project on European Regulatory Private Law hosted at the EUI Law Department in the research and writing of this article. I am grateful to Hans Micklitz and a journal referee for detailed comments on an earlier draft, but the usual disclaimer applies.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Svetiev, Y. How Consumer Law Travels. J Consum Policy 36, 209–230 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10603-013-9239-8
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10603-013-9239-8