Skip to main content
Log in

Political parties: insights from a tri-planar model of political economy

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

What is the place of political parties within a democratic system of political economy? Parties are often described as intermediaries that lubricate the political process by facilitating the matching of voter preferences with candidate positions. This line of analysis flows from a bi-planar model of the political process where politicians appeal directly to voters. In this paper, we examine how construction of a meso level of analysis that lies between micro and macro levels might influence the relationship between candidates and voters. This meso level interjects such organizations as political parties between candidates and voters, with those organizations comprising interest groups within a democratic process, as against serving simply as neutral intermediaries. In this case, political parties can exert substantive effects on democratic outcomes as they take on characteristics of interest groups, bringing to mind Michels (Political parties: a sociological study of the oligarchical tendencies of modern democracy, Hearst’s International Library, New York, 1915) analysis of the unavoidably oligopolistic nature of democratic political organization.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for examples, Tirole (1996) for a discussion of party reputation, Alesina (2005), Roland and Zapata (2000) for an analysis of unfettered intraparty competition on electoral effectiveness in Colombia, and Caillaud and Tirole (2002) for a formal model of how political parties “regulate competition among like-minded factions so as to enhance reputation building by, and voter trust in, the politicians standing for a given cause.”.

  2. There is nothing in Pareto’s treatment of non-logical action that is inconsistent with the treatment of expressive voting in Brennan and Lomasky (1993) or with Caplan’s (2007) rendition of voter irrationality, save that Pareto didn’t think irrationality was a useful scientific concept. To the contrary, Pareto was in line with Gigerenzer’s (2008) subsequent treatment of rationality as a product of interaction between an actor and the environment within which the action occurred.

References

  • Aldrich, J. (1995). Why parties? The origin and transformation of political parties in America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. (2005). Institutional reforms: The case of Colombia. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Backhaus, J. G. (1978). Pareto on public choice. Public Choice, 33, 5–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bawn, K., & Thies, M. (2003). A comparative theory of electoral incentives: Representing the unorganized under PR, plurality, and mixed-member electoral systems. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 15, 5–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98, 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. (2006). Principled agents? The political economy of good government. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. (1958). Theory of committees and elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Lomasky, L. (1993). Democracy and decision: The pure theory of electoral preference. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1969). Cost and choice. Chicago: Markham.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burnham, J. (1943). The machiavellians: Defenders of freedom. New York: John Day.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caillaud, B., & Tirole, J. (2002). Parties as political intermediaries. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1453–1489.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cain, B., Ferejohn, J., & Fiorina, M. (1987). The personal vote. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Caplan, B. (2007). The myth of the rational voter. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Jouvenal, B. (1961). Seminar exercise: The chairman’s problem. American Political Science Review, 55, 367–372.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dennett, D. C. (1978). Brainstorms: Philosophical essays on mind and psychology. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A., & Munger, M. (1986). Legislators and interest groups: How unorganized interests get represented. American Political Science Review, 80, 89–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elvik, R. (1995). Explaining the distribution of state funds for national road investments between counties in Norway: Engineering standards or vote trading? Public Choice, 85, 371–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emmett, R. B. (2006). De Gustibus est Disputandum: Frank H. Knight’s Response to George Stigler and Gary Becker. Journal of Economic Methodology, 13, 97–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G. (2008). Rationality for mortals. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1937). Economics and knowledge. Economica, 4, 33–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review, 35, 519–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. 1989 [1974]. The pretense of knowledge. American Economic Review 79, 3–7.

  • Hebert, D., & Wagner, R. E. (2013). Taxation as a quasi-market process: Explanation, exhortation, and the choice of analytical windows. Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice, 31, 163–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hinich, M. J., & Munger, M. C. (1994). Ideology and the theory of public choice. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. (1929). Stability in competition. Economic Journal, 39, 41–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. (2005). Endogenizing fractionalization. Journal of Institutional Economics, 1, 75–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2006). Cooperation and conflict: Evidence on self-enforcing arrangements and heterogeneous groups. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 65, 891–907.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2008). Coordination without command: Stretching the scope of spontaneous order. Public Choice, 135, 67–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lovejoy, A. (1936). The great chain of being. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Madison, J. (1787). Federalist Paper #10. In Clinton Rossiter (Ed.), The Federalist Papers (pp. 77–84). New York: New American Library, 1961.

  • Martin, A., & Wagner, R. E. (2009). Heterogeneity, voting, and the political economy of public policy. Public Finance and Management, 9, 393–415.

    Google Scholar 

  • Michels, R. (1915). Political parties: A sociological study of the oligarchical tendencies of modern democracy. New York: Hearst’s International Library.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D., & Stratmann, T. (1994). Information and persuasive campaigning. Public Choice, 81, 55–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pareto, V. 1935 [1923]. The mind and society. New York: Harcourt Brace.

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics: Explaining economic policy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Potts, J., & Morrison, K. (2007). Meso comes to markets. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 63, 307–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Resnick, M. (1994). Turtles, termites, and traffic jams. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1962). The theory of political coalitions. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roland, G., & Zapata, J. G. (2000). Colombia’s electoral and party system: proposal for reforms. Working Paper.

  • Schattschneider, E. E. (2004). Party government: American government in action. New York: Farrar and Rinehart.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitt, C. 1932 [1996]. The concept of the political. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • Shackle, G. L. S. (1972). Epistemics and economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, D. (2014). Heterogeneity and exchange: Safe-conducts in medieval Spain. Review of Austrian Economics, 27, 183–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J., & Becker, G. S. (1977). De Gustibus Non Est Disputandum. American Economic Review, 67, 76–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stratmann, T. (1992). The effects of logrolling on congressional voting. American Economic Review, 82, 1162–1176.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stratmann, T. (1995). Logrolling in the U.S. congress. Economic Inquiry, 33, 441–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stratmann, T., & Baur, M. (2002). Plurality rule, proportional representation, and the German Bundestag: How incentives to pork-barrel differ across electoral systems. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 506–514.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (1996). A theory of collective reputations (with applications to the persistence of corruption and to firm quality). The Review of Economic Studies, 63(1), 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1965). The politics of bureaucracy. Washington: Public Affairs Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1989). Why democracies produce efficient results. Journal of Political Economy, 97, 1395–1424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1995). The myth of democratic failure: Why political institutions are efficient. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David J. Hebert.

Additional information

We wish to thank participants at the Public Choice Society meetings as well as two anonymous referees for their insightful comments on earlier drafts. All remaining errors are our own.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hebert, D.J., Wagner, R.E. Political parties: insights from a tri-planar model of political economy. Const Polit Econ 29, 253–267 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-018-9256-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-018-9256-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation