Advertisement

Constitutional Political Economy

, Volume 27, Issue 4, pp 355–376 | Cite as

Economic globalization and the change of electoral rules

  • Christian Walter Martin
  • Nils D. Steiner
Original Paper

Abstract

This paper takes up an argument from Ronald Rogowski about the “natural affinity” between trade and an electoral system with proportional representation. We draw on literature on the historical determinants of electoral system choice to advance the general argument that trade integration and PR are related because the adoption of PR helps to secure gains from trade. Our specific model of electoral rule changes in the age of globalization predicts that the likelihood of electoral rule change towards more proportionality increases with levels of trade integration in the world economy. The theoretical model draws on a micro model of the distributive effects of increased economic integration. Because more proportional systems are more credibly able to commit to compensate the losers of globalization processes, there will be increased demand to change the electoral system towards more proportionality under economic circumstances that increase the costs of maintaining a closed economy. In accordance with our model, our empirical tests find a positive association between (a) trade integration and the proportionality of the electoral system, (b) proportionality and social spending, and (c) global integration levels and the probability of electoral rules changes that render voting rules more proportional.

Keywords

Electoral reform Trade Economic globalization 

JEL Classification

F15 I38 

References

  1. Adema, W., Fron, P., & Ladaique, M. (2011). Is the European welfare state really more expensive? Indicators on social spending, 19802012; and a manual to the OECD social expenditure database (SOCX). OECD social, employment and migration working papers no. 124. Paris: OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
  2. Alesina, A., & Wacziarg, R. (1998). Openness, country size and government. Journal of Public Economics, 69, 305–321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P., & Walsh, P. (2001). New tools in comparative political economy: The Database of Political Institutions. World Bank Economic Review, 15, 165–176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Boix, C. (1999). Setting the rules of the game: The choice of electoral systems in advanced democracies. American Political Science Review, 93, 609–624.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bormann, N. C., & Golder, M. (2013). Democratic electoral systems around the world, 1946–2011. Electoral Studies, 32, 360–369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Box-Steffensmeier, J. M., & Jones, B. S. (2004). Event history modeling: A guide for social scientists. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Calvo, E. (2009). The comparative road to proportional representation. Partisan biases and electoral regime change under increasing party competition. World Politics, 61, 254–295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Cameron, D. R. (1978). The expansion of the public economy: A comparative analysis. American Political Science Review, 72, 1243–1261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Chang, T. (2002). An econometric test of Wagner’s Law for six countries based on cointegration and error-correction modeling techniques. Applied Economics, 34, 1157–1169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Colomer, J. M. (2005). It’s parties that choose electoral systems (or, Duverger’s Laws upside down). Political Studies, 53, 1–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Cox, G. W. (1997). Making votes count: Strategic coordination in the world’s electoral systems. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Cusack, T. R., Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2007). Economic interests and the origins of electoral systems. American Political Science Review, 101, 373–391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Cusack, T. R., Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2010). Coevolution of capitalism and political representation: The choice of electoral systems. American Political Science Review, 104, 393–403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Dreher, A. (2006). Does globalization affect growth? Evidence from a new index of globalization. Applied Economics, 38, 1091–1110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Dreher, A., Gaston, N., & Martens, P. (2008). Measuring globalisation: Gauging its consequences. New York, NY: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Dunleavy, P., & Margetts, H. (1995). Understanding the dynamics of electoral reform. International Political Science Review, 16, 9–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Duverger, M. (1954). Political parties. London: Methuen.Google Scholar
  18. Ehrlich, S. D. (2007). Access to protection: Domestic institutions and trade policy in democracies. International Organization, 61, 571–605.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Evans, C. L. (2009). A protectionist bias in majoritarian politics: An empirical investigation. Economics and Politics, 21, 278–307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Fernandez, R., & Rodrik, D. (1991). Resistance to reform: Status quo bias in the presence of individual-specific uncertainty. The American Economic Review, 81, 1146–1155.Google Scholar
  21. Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84, 833–850.Google Scholar
  22. Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (2002). Special interest groups. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  23. Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (2005). A protectionist bias in majoritarian politics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 1239–1282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Hellwig, T., & Samuels, D. (2007). Voting in open economies: The electoral consequences of globalization. Comparative Political Studies, 40, 283–306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Iversen, T., & Cusack, T. R. (2000). The causes of welfare state expansion: Deindustrialization or globalization? World Politics, 52, 313–349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2006). Electoral institutions and the politics of coalitions: Why some democracies redistribute more than others. American Political Science Review, 100, 165–181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Katzenstein, P. J. (1985). Small states in world markets: Industrial policy in Europe. Ithaka, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
  28. Keefer, P., & Stasavage, D. (2003). The limits of delegation: Veto players, central bank independence, and the credibility of monetary policy. American Political Science Review, 97, 407–423.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Kim, S. Y. (2007). Openness, external risk, and volatility: Implications for the compensation hypothesis. International Organization, 61, 181–216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1977). Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal plans. The Journal of Political Economy, 85, 473–492.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Legrenzi, G. (2004). The displacement effect in the growth of governments. Public Choice, 120, 191–204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Lijphart, A. (2012). Patterns of democracy: Government forms and performance in thirty-six countries (2nd ed.). New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  33. Magee, S. P., Brock, W. A., & Young, L. (1989). Black hole tariffs and endogenous policy theory: Political economy in general equilibrium. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  34. Mansfield, E. D., Milner, H. V., & Rosendorff, B. P. (2000). Free to trade: Democracies, autocracies, and international trade. American Political Science Review, 94, 305–321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Martin, C. W. (2005). Die doppelte Transformation: Demokratie und Außenwirtschaftsliberalisierung in Entwicklungsländern. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Martin, C. W. (2009). Towards an explanation of electoral rules change. CEU Political Science Journal, 4, 169–191.Google Scholar
  37. Martin, C. W., & Schneider, G. (2007). Pfadabhängigkeit, Konvergenz oder regulativer Wettbewerb: Determinanten der Außenwirtschaftsliberalisierung 1978–2002. In K. Holzinger, H. Jörgens, & C. Knill (Eds.), Transfer, Diffusion und Konvergenz von Politiken, PVS Politische Vierteljahresschrift Sonderheft 38 (pp. 449–469). Wiesbaden: VS Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Milesi-Ferretti, G. M., Perotti, R., & Rostagno, M. (2002). Electoral systems and public spending. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 609–657.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Milner, H. V., & Kubota, K. (2005). Why the move to free trade? Democracy and trade policy in the developing countries. International Organization, 59, 107–143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Naoi, M., & Krauss, E. (2009). Who lobbies whom? Special interest politics under alternative electoral systems. American Journal of Political Science, 53, 874–892.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. E. (2005). The economic effects of constitutions. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  42. Powell, G. B. (2000). Elections as instruments of democracy: Majoritarian and proportional visions. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  43. Rae, D. (1971). The political consequences of electoral laws. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  44. Renwick, A. (2010). The politics of electoral reform: Changing the rules of democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Rodrik, D. (1994). The rush to free trade in the developing world: Why so late? Why now? Will it last? In S. Haggard & S. B. Webb (Eds.), Voting for reform: Democracy, political liberalization, and economic adjustment (pp. 64–88). New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  46. Rodrik, D. (1998). Why do more open economies have bigger governments? Journal of Political Economy, 106, 997–1032.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Rogowski, R. (1987). Trade and the variety of democratic institutions. International Organization, 41, 203–223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Rokkan, S. (1970). Citizens, elections, parties. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.Google Scholar
  49. Roubini, N., & Sachs, J. (1989). Government spending and budget deficits in the industrial economies (working papers 2919). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Retrieved from http://www.nber.org/papers/w2919.pdf.
  50. Sakamoto, T. (1999). Explaining electoral reform: Japan versus Italy and New Zealand. Party Politics, 5, 419–438.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Schmidt, M. (2002). Political performance and types of democracy: Findings from comparative studies. European Journal of Political Research, 41, 147–163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Stein, R. M., & Bickers, K. M. (1994). Congressional elections and the pork barrel. The Journal of Politics, 56, 377–399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Steiner, N. D. (2010). Economic globalization and voter turnout in established democracies. Electoral Studies, 29, 444–459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Steiner, N. D., & Martin, C. W. (2012). Economic integration, party polarization and electoral turnout: Testing for a causal chain. West European Politics, 35, 238–265.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Stratmann, T., & Baur, M. (2002). Plurality rule, proportional representation, and the German Bundestag: How incentives to pork-barrel differ across electoral systems. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 506–514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Taagepera, R., & Shugart, M. S. (1989). Seats and votes. The effects and determinants of electoral systems. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  57. Tsebelis, G. (1995). Decision making in political systems: Veto players in presidentialism, parliamentarism, multicameralism and multipartyism. British Journal of Political Science, 25, 289–325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: How political institutions work. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. World Bank. (2011). World development indicators. Washington, DC: The World Bank.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2015

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.University of KielKielGermany
  2. 2.University of MainzMainzGermany

Personalised recommendations