Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Economically optimal risk reduction strategies in the face of uncertain climate thresholds

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Climatic Change Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Anthropogenic greenhouse gas emissions may trigger climate threshold responses, such as a collapse of the North Atlantic meridional overturning circulation (MOC). Climate threshold responses have been interpreted as an example of “dangerous anthropogenic interference with the climate system” in the sense of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC). One UNFCCC objective is to “prevent” such dangerous anthropogenic interference. The current uncertainty about important parameters of the coupled natural – human system implies, however, that this UNFCCC objective can only be achieved in a probabilistic sense. In other words, climate management can only reduce – but not entirely eliminate – the risk of crossing climate thresholds. Here we use an integrated assessment model of climate change to derive economically optimal risk-reduction strategies. We implement a stochastic version of the DICE model and account for uncertainty about four parameters that have been previously identified as dominant drivers of the uncertain system response. The resulting model is, of course, just a crude approximation as it neglects, for example, some structural uncertainty and focuses on a single threshold, out of many potential climate responses. Subject to this caveat, our analysis suggests five main conclusions. First, reducing the numerical artifacts due to sub-sampling the parameter probability density functions to reasonable levels requires sample sizes exceeding 103. Conclusions of previous studies that are based on much smaller sample sizes may hence need to be revisited. Second, following a business-as-usual (BAU) scenario results in odds for an MOC collapse in the next 150 years exceeding 1 in 3 in this model. Third, an economically “optimal” strategy (that maximizes the expected utility of the decision-maker) reduces carbon dioxide(CO2) emissions by approximately 25% at the end of this century, compared with BAU emissions. Perhaps surprisingly, this strategy leaves the odds of an MOC collapse virtually unchanged compared to a BAU strategy. Fourth, reducing the odds for an MOC collapse to 1 in 10 would require an almost complete decarbonization of the economy within a few decades. Finally, further risk reductions (e.g., to 1 in 100) are possible in the framework of the simple model, but would require faster and more expensive reductions in CO2 emissions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alley RB, Marotzke J, Nordhaus WD, Overpeck JT, Peteet DM, Pielke RA, Pierrehumbert RT, Rhines PB, Stocker TF, Talley LD, Wallace JM (2003) Abrupt climate change. Science 299:2005–2010

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andronova NG, Schlesinger ME (2001) Objective estimate of the probability density function for climate sensitivity. Journal of Geophysical Research 106:22.605–22.612

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baehr J, Keller K, Marotzke J (2007) Detecting potential changes in the meridional overturning circulation at 26n in the atlantic. Climatic Change, 10.1007/s10584-006-9153-z, this issue

  • Bradford DF (1999) On the uses of benefit-cost reasoning in choosing policy to ward global climate change. Discounting and intergenerational equity, Resources for the Future pp 37–44

  • Bruckner T, Zickfeld K (2004) Low risk emissions corridors for safeguarding the Atlantic thermohaline circulation. Greenhouse Gas Emissions and Abrupt Climate Change: Positive Options and Robust policies Paris

  • Chao HP (1995) Managing the risk of global climate catastrophe: An uncertainty analysis. Risk Analysis 15:69–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cubasch U, Meehl GA (2001) Climate Change — The scientific basis. Contribution of working group I of the third assessment report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Chapter Projections of future climate change, Cambridge University Press, pp 526–582

  • Goldberg DE (1989) Genetic Algorithms in Search, Optimization, and Machine Learning. Addison-Wesley Longman Publishing Company, Inc

  • Hoeting JA, Madigan D, Raftery AE, Volinsky CT (1999) Bayesian model averaging: A tutorial. Statistical Science 14(4):382–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keller K, Bolker BM, Bradford DF (2004) Uncertain climate thresholds and optimal economic growth. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 48:723–741

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keller K, Hall M, Kim SR, Bradford DF, Oppenheimer M (2005) Avoiding dangerous anthropogenic interference with the climate system. Climatic Change 73:227–238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keller K, Hall MG, Yang Z, Bradford DF (2003) Carbon dioxide sequestration: When and how much? Center for Economic Policy studies Working paper No. 94. Available at: http://www.princeton.edu/simceps

  • Keller K, Tan K, Morel FMM, Bradford DF (2000) Preserving the ocean circulation: Implications for climate policy. Climatic Change 47:17–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keller K, Yohe G, Schlesinger M (2006) Managing the risks of climate thresholds: Uncertainties and needed information. Climatic Change, 10.1007/s10584-006-9114-6, this issue

  • Kelly DL, Kolstad CD (1999) Bayesian learning, growth and pollution. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 23:491–518

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Latif M, Roeckner E, Mikolajewski U, Voss R (2000) Tropical stabilization of the thermohaline circulation in a greenhouse warming simulation. Journal of Climate 13:1809–1813

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lempert RJ (2002) A new decision sciences for complex systems Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 99:7309–7313

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Link PM, Tol RSJ (2004) Possible economic impacts of a shutdown of the thermohaline circulation: An application of FUND. Portugese Economic Journal 3:99–114

    Google Scholar 

  • Moles CG, Banga JR, Keller K (2004) Solving nonconvex climate control problems: Pitfalls and algorithm performances. Applied Soft Computing 5:35–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus WD (1992) An optimal transition path for controlling greenhouse gases. Science 258:1315–1319

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus WD (1994) Managing the global commons: The economics of climate change. The MIT press, Cambridge, Massachusetts

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus WD, Popp D (1997) What is the value of scientific knowledge? An application to global warming using the PRICE model. Energy Journal 18(1):1–45

    Google Scholar 

  • Ouarda TBMJ, Labadie JW (2001) Chance-constrained optimal control for multireservoir system optimization and risk analysis. Stochastic Environmental Research and Risk Assessment 15:185–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey F (1928) A mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal 37:543–559

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Runarsson TP, Yao X (2000) Stochastic ranking for constrained evolutionary optimization. IEEE Transactions on Evolutionary Computation 4(3):284–294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Runarsson TR, Yao X (2005) Search biases in constrained evolutionary optimization — Part C: Applications and reviews. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man and Cybernetics 35(2):233–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider SH, Thompson SL (1981) Atmospheric CO2 and climate — importance of the transient response. Journal of Geophysical Research 86:NC4 3135–3147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stocker TF, Schmittner A (1997) Influence of CO2 emission rates on the stability of the thermohaline circulation. Nature 388:862–865

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tol RSJ (2003) Is the uncertainty about climate change too large for expected cost-benefit analysis? Climatic Change 56(3):265–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toth FL, Bruckner T, Fussel H-F, Leimbach M, G P-H, Schnellnhuber H (1997) The tolerable windows approach to integrated assessments. Proceedings of the IPCC Asia-Pacific Workshop on integrated assessment models (iams)

  • van Manen SE, Brinkhaus M (2005) Quantitative flood risk assessment for polders. Reliability engineering & system safety 90:229–237

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vellinga M, Wood RA (2002) Global climatic impacts of a collapse of the Atlantic thermohaline circulation. Climatic Change 54(3):251–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yohe G (1996) Exercises in hedging against extreme consequences of global change and the expected value of information. Global Environmental Change 6:87–101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zickfeld K, Bruckner T (2003) Reducing the risk of abrupt climate change: Emissions corridors preserving the Atlantic thermohaline circulation. Integrated Assessment 4:106–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David McInerney.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

McInerney, D., Keller, K. Economically optimal risk reduction strategies in the face of uncertain climate thresholds. Climatic Change 91, 29–41 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10584-006-9137-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10584-006-9137-z

Keywords

Navigation