Skip to main content
Log in

An Economic Analysis on Overbilling Incentives and Auditing Programs

  • Published:
Journal of Business Ethics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

An institutional auditing program typically consists of the following steps: a sample audit, the decision to move to the full audit, a settlement offer, and the full audit. Statistical sampling techniques are often used to estimate the overbilling percentage and amount. This paper discusses the optimal settlement offer, the net recovery through auditing, the condition for the auditors to move to the full audit, and how an auditing program can be truly cost-effective. This paper provides an evaluation for the statistical sampling techniques to an auditing program. The economic incentives of a contractor to overbill are also identified. Finally, it presents the key metrics and the managerial implications for auditing managers to design or enhance their auditing programs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. http://dor.mo.gov/faq/business/audit.php#q8.

  2. http://www.window.state.tx.us/taxinfo/audit/auditfun/7sampling.htm.

  3. http://www.aicpa.org/Research/Standards/AuditAttest/DownloadableDocuments/AU-00350.pdf.

  4. http://www.mtc.gov/Audit.aspx?id=4182.

  5. http://www.paralegals.org.

  6. https://www.aicpa.org/Publications/AccountingAuditing/KeyTopics/DownloadableDocuments/Sampling_Guide_Technical_Notes.pdf.

  7. http://www.tax.ny.gov/pdf/publications/sales/pub132.pdf.

References

  • Andreoni, J., Erard, B., & Feinstein, J. (1998). Tax compliance. Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 818–860.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bebchuk, L. (1984). Litigation and settlement under imperfect information. RAND Journal of Economics, 15, 404–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bebchuk, L. (1996). A new theory concerning the credibility and success of threats to sue. Journal of Legal Studies, 25, 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooter, R. D., & Rubinfield, D. L. (1998). Economic analysis of legal disputes and their resolution. Journal of Economic Literature, 27, 1067–1097.

    Google Scholar 

  • Darby, M. R., & Karni, E. (1973). Free competition and the optimal amount of fraud. Journal of Law and Economics, 16(1), 67–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daughety, A. F. (2000). Settlement. In B. Bouckaert & G. De Geest (Eds.), Encyclopedia of law and economics. London: Edward Elgar.

  • Dulleck, U., & Kerschbamer, R. (2006). On doctors, mechanics, and computer specialists: The economics of credence goods. Journal of Economic Literature, 44, 5–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emons, W. (1997). Credence goods and fraudulent experts. RAND Journal of Economics, 28(1), 107–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franzoni, L. A. (1999). Negotiated enforcement and credible deterrence. Economic Journal, 109(458), 509–535.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franzoni, L. A. (2004). Discretion in tax enforcement. Economica, 71, 369–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franzoni, L. A. (2008). Tax compliance. In B. Bouckaert & G. De Geest (Eds.), Encyclopedia of law and economics. London: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hay, B., & Spier, K. (1998). Litigation and settlement. In P. Newman (Ed.), The new Palgrave dictionary of economics and the law. London: MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kennan, J., & Wilson, R. (1991). Bargaining with private information. Journal of Economics Literature, 31, 381–399.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kritzer, H. (1991). The justice broker: Lawyers and ordinary litigation. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lerman, L. G. (1990). Lying to clients. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 138, 659–760.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lohr, S. (1999). Sampling design and analysis. Pacific Grove, CA: Duxbury Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Macho-Stadler, I., & Péres-Castrillo, J. D. (2004). Settlement in tax evasion prosecution. Economica, 71, 349–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCluskey, J. J. (2000). A game theoretic approach to organic foods: An analysis of asymmetric information and policy. Agricultural and Resource Economics Review, 29, 1–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pitchik, C., & Schotter A. (1987). Honesty in a model of strategic information transmission. American Economic Review, 77, 1032–1036.

    Google Scholar 

  • Polinsky, A. M., & Shavell, S. (2007). The theory of public enforcement of law. In A. M. Polinsky & S. Shavell (Eds.), Handbook of law and economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier, North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reinganum, J. F., & Daughety, A. F. (1994). Settlement negotiations with two-sided asymmetric information: Model duality, information distribution and efficiency. International Review of Law and Economics, 14, 283–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richmond, D. R. (2008). For a few dollars more: The perplexing problems of unethical billing practices by lawyers. S.C.L. Review, 63–70.

  • Schweizer, U. (1989). Litigation and settlement under two sided incomplete information. Review of Economic Studies, 56, 163–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spier, K. E. (1992). The dynamics of pretrial negotiation. Review of Economic Studies, 59, 93–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wolinsky, A. (1993). Competition in a market for informed experts’ services. RAND Journal of Economics, 24, 380–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chris Kuo.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Eq. (9):

$$ \begin{aligned} \pi(\rho, 1) &= \rho (p^{\rm H}-c^{\rm H}) + (1-\rho)(p^{\rm H}-c^{\rm L}) - \gamma (1-\rho) m p^{\rm H}\\ &\quad - (\bar{e} - z) (1-\gamma) p^{\rm H}\\ &= \rho (p^{\rm H}-c^{\rm H}) + (1-\rho)(p^{\rm H}-c^{\rm L}) - \gamma (1-\rho) m p^{\rm H}\\ &\quad- (1-\rho) (1-\gamma) m p^{\rm H} + z (1-\gamma) p^{\rm H} \\ \pi(1, 1)&= p^{\rm H}-c^{\rm H} \end{aligned} $$

When π(ρ, 1) > π(1, 1)

$$ \begin{aligned} &(\rho -1 )(p^{\rm H} - c^{\rm H}) + (1-\rho)(p^{\rm H} - c^{\rm L}) - \gamma (1-\rho) m p^{\rm H}\\ &\quad> (1- \rho) (1-\gamma) m p^{\rm H} - z (1-\gamma) p^{\rm H}\\ &(1-\rho) (c^{\rm H} - c^{\rm L}) > (1 -\rho) m p^{\rm H} - z (1-\gamma) p^{\rm H}\\ &(1-\rho) (c^{\rm H} - c^{\rm L}) > (1 -\rho) (p^{\rm H} - p^{\rm L}) - z (1-\gamma) p^{\rm H}\\ & c^{\rm H} - c^{\rm L} > p^{\rm H} - p^{\rm L} - z \frac{1-\gamma}{1 - \rho} p^{\rm H}. \end{aligned} $$

\(\square\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kuo, C. An Economic Analysis on Overbilling Incentives and Auditing Programs. J Bus Ethics 121, 441–449 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-013-1727-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-013-1727-x

Keywords

Navigation