Skip to main content
Log in

New retail versus traditional retail in e-commerce: channel establishment, price competition, and consumer recognition

  • S.I.: RealCaseOR
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The concept “new retail” in e-commerce is to establish an offline channel and integrate it with the online retail channel. The development of new retail encounters three main problems: locations of the offline stores, the price competition with the traditional online retail, and the difficulty in consumer recognition in the two channels. In this paper, we present a duopoly model consisting of a new retail firm and an online firm, which sell the same product in two periods. The two firms compete for the market share using the behavior-based pricing (BBP), which means that in the second period each firm offers different prices to consumers with different purchasing histories/behaviors in the first period. We also solve the benchmark pricing model, where the histories/behaviors are not considered. The results of this paper provide valuable insights to the development of new retail in e-commerce. In the Nash equilibrium, each price of the new retail firm is higher than the corresponding price of the online firm due to a higher channel cost for the offline stores and high-speed deliveries. Under certain condition, the new retail firm will establish an offline channel with a larger hassle cost, which is a measure of the easiness of reaching the offline stores by the consumers, in the BBP model than that in the benchmark model. Interestingly, the difficulty in consumer recognition results in that the new retail firm occupies more market share and may obtain higher profit.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Acquisti, A., & Varian, H. R. (2005). Conditioning prices on purchase history. Marketing Science, 24(3), 367–381.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amrouche, N., & Yan, R. (2016). A manufacturer distribution issue: How to manage an online and a traditional retailer. Annals of Operations Research, 244(2), 257–294.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ansari, A., Mela, C. F., & Neslin, S. A. (2008). Customer channel migration. Journal of Marketing Research, 45(1), 60–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caillaud, B., & De Nijs, R. (2014). Strategic loyalty reward in dynamic price discrimination. Marketing Science, 33(5), 725–742.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cattani, K., Gilland, W., Heese, H. S., & Swaminathan, J. (2006). Boiling frogs: Pricing strategies for a manufacturer adding a direct channel that competes with the traditional channel. Production and Operations Management, 15(1), 40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, K.-Y., Kaya, M., & Özer, Ö. (2008). Dual sales channel management with service competition. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 10(4), 654–675.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y. (2008). Dynamic price discrimination with asymmetric firms. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 56(4), 729–751.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiang, W.-Y. K., Chhajed, D., & Hess, J. D. (2003). Direct marketing, indirect profits: A strategic analysis of dual-channel supply-chain design. Management Science, 49(1), 1–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Colombo, S. (2016). Imperfect behavior-based price discrimination. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 25(3), 563–583.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ding, Q., Dong, C., & Pan, Z. (2016). A hierarchical pricing decision process on a dual-channel problem with one manufacturer and one retailer. International Journal of Production Economics, 175, 197–212.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esteves, R. B. (2010). Pricing with customer recognition. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 28(6), 669–681.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esteves, R. B., & Cerqueira, S. (2017). Behavior-based pricing under imperfectly informed consumers. Information Economics and Policy, 40, 60–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (2000). Customer poaching and brand switching. RAND Journal of Economics, 31(4), 634–657.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., & Villas-Boas, J. M. (2006). Behavior-based price discrimination and customer recognition. Handbook on economics and information systems (pp. 377–436).

  • Gao, F., & Su, X. (2016). Omnichannel retail operations with buy-online-and-pick-up-in-store. Management Science, 63(8), 2478–2492.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrig, T., Shy, O., & Stenbacka, R. (2011). History-based price discrimination and entry in markets with switching costs: A welfare analysis. European Economic Review, 55(5), 732–739.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrig, T., Shy, O., & Stenbacka, R. (2012). A welfare evaluation of history-based price discrimination. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 12(4), 373–393.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hu, W., & Li, Y. (2012). Retail service for mixed retail and e-tail channels. Annals of Operations Research, 192(1), 151–171.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, G., Ding, Q., Dong, C., & Pan, Z. (2018). Joint optimization of pricing and inventory control for dual-channel problem under stochastic demand. Annals of Operations Research. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-018-2863-6.

  • Jing, B. (2016). Behavior-based pricing, production efficiency, and quality differentiation. Management Science, 63(7), 2365–2376.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, B., Hou, P.-W., Chen, P., & Li, Q.-H. (2016). Pricing strategy and coordination in a dual channel supply chain with a risk-averse retailer. International Journal of Production Economics, 178, 154–168.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, K. J., & Jain, S. (2015). Behavior-based pricing: An analysis of the impact of peer-induced fairness. Management Science, 62(9), 2705–2721.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, Q., Li, B., Chen, P., & Hou, P. (2017). Dual-channel supply chain decisions under asymmetric information with a risk-averse retailer. Annals of Operations Research, 257(1–2), 423–447.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, Y., & Zhang, Z. J. (2006). Research note? The benefits of personalized pricing in a channel. Marketing Science, 25(1), 97–105.

    Google Scholar 

  • Netessine, S., & Rudi, N. (2006). Supply chain choice on the internet. Management Science, 52(6), 844–864.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ofek, E., Katona, Z., & Sarvary, M. (2011). bricks and clicks: The impact of product returns on the strategies of multichannel retailers. Marketing Science, 30(1), 42–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pazgal, A., & Soberman, D. (2008). Behavior-based discrimination: Is it a winning play, and if so, when? Marketing Science, 27(6), 977–994.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rhee, K. E., & Thomadsen, R. (2016). Behavior-based pricing in vertically differentiated industries. Management Science, 63(8), 2729–2740.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaffer, G., & Zhang, Z. J. (2000). Pay to switch or pay to stay: Preference-based price discrimination in markets with switching costs. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 9(3), 397–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shin, J., & Sudhir, K. (2010). A customer management dilemma: When is it profitable to reward one’s own customers? Marketing Science, 29(4), 671–689.

    Google Scholar 

  • Soleimani, F., Khamseh, A. A., & Naderi, B. (2016). Optimal decisions in a dual-channel supply chain under simultaneous demand and production cost disruptions. Annals of Operations Research, 243(1–2), 301–321.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsay, A. A., & Agrawal, N. (2004). Channel conflict and coordination in the e-commerce age. Production and Operations Management, 13(1), 93–110.

    Google Scholar 

  • Villas-Boas, J. M. (1999). Dynamic competition with customer recognition. The Rand Journal of Economics, 30(4), 604–631.

    Google Scholar 

  • Villas-Boas, J. M. (2004). Price cycles in markets with customer recognition. RAND Journal of Economics, 35(3), 486–501.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, J. (2011). The perils of behavior-based personalization. Marketing Science, 30(1), 170–186.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The paper is supported in part by the University Grants Council under grant number PolyU 152207/17E.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chi To Ng.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

The o-firm’s profit is \(\pi _o^\prime =(p_o^\prime -c_o)\frac{2(p_n^\prime -p_o^\prime )-v(1 -\alpha )}{2(h_o-h_n)}\). The optimal \(p_o^\prime \) is given by the first order condition: \(p_o^\prime =\frac{2c_o+2p_n^\prime -v(1-\alpha )}{4}\). The n-firm’s profit is \(\pi _n^\prime =(p_n^\prime -c_n)(1-\frac{2(p_n^\prime -p_o^\prime ) -v(1-\alpha )}{2(h_o-h_n)})\). The optimal \(p_n^\prime \) is given by the first order condition: \(p_n^\prime =\frac{2c_n-2h_n+2h_o+2p_o^\prime +v(1-\alpha )}{4}\). Solve the two equations we obtain \(p_o^\prime \) and \(p_n^\prime \). The cutoff value \(\theta ^\prime \) and the profits of the two firms are obtained by substituting \(p_o^\prime \) and \(p_n^\prime \). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 2

Substituting \(c_n-c_o=A(h_o-h_n)^2\), conditions \(2(c_n-c_o)-4(h_o-h_n)-v(1-\alpha )<0\) and \(2(c_n-c_o)+2(h_o-h_n)-v(1-\alpha )>0\) determine that \(\frac{\sqrt{4+2Av(1-\alpha )}-2}{2A}\le (h_o-h_n)\le \frac{2+\sqrt{4+2Av(1-\alpha )}}{2A}\).

Substituting \(c_n-c_o=A(h_o-h_n)^2\) into the n-firm’s profit, we have:

\(\pi _n^\prime =\frac{[-2A(h_o-h_n)^2+4(h_o-h_n)+v(1-\alpha )]^2}{36(h_o-h_n)}\). \(\frac{\partial \pi _n^\prime }{\partial (h_o-h_n)}=\frac{[-(2(c_n-c_o)-4(h_o-h_n)-v(1-\alpha )]}{36(h_o-h_n)^2}[-6A(h_o-h_n)^2+4(h_o-h_n)-v(1-\alpha )]\), and \(\frac{[-(2(c_n-c_o)-4(h_o-h_n)-v(1-\alpha )]}{36(h_o-h_n)^2}>0\). \(-6A(h_o-h_n)^2+4(h_o-h_n)-v(1-\alpha )\) is positive and then negative as \(h_o-h_n\) increases when \(v(1-\alpha ) \le \frac{2}{3A}\). Thus, \(\pi _n^\prime \) increases then decreases and \((h_o-h_n)^*\) is at \(\frac{\partial \pi _n^\prime }{\partial (h_o-h_n)}=0\), that is, \((h_o-h_n)^*=\frac{2+\sqrt{4-6Av(1-\alpha )}}{6A}\).

When \(v(1-\alpha )>\frac{2}{3A}\), \(-6A(h_o-h_n)^2+4(h_o-h_n)-v(1-\alpha )\) is negative, so \(\pi _n^\prime \) decreases as \((h_o-h_n)\) increases, \((h_o-h_n)^*=\frac{\sqrt{4+2Av(1-\alpha )}-2}{2A}\). \(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 1

The o-firm’s profit in the o-firm’s first-period market share is \(\pi _{2o}^o=(p_o-c_o)\frac{p_{on}-p_{oo}}{h_o-h_n}\). The optimal \(p_{oo}\) is given by the first order condition: \(p_{oo}=\frac{c_o+p_{on}}{2}\). The n-firm’s profit is \(\pi _{2o}^n=(p_{on}-c_n)(\theta _1-\frac{p_{on}-p_{oo}}{h_o-h_n})\). The optimal \(p_{on}\) is given by the first order condition: \(p_{on}=\frac{c_n-(h_n-h_o)\theta _1+p_{oo}}{2}\). Solving the two equations, we obtain \(p_{oo}^*\) and \(p_{on}^*\). \(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 2

The o-firm’s profit in the n-firm’s first-period market share is \(\pi _{2n}^o=(p_{no}-c_o)(\frac{p_{nn}-p_{no}-v(1-\alpha )}{h_o-h_n}-\theta _1)\). The optimal \(p_{no}\) is given by the first order condition: \(p_{no}=\frac{c_o+p_{nn}-(h_o-h_n)\theta _1-v(1-\alpha )}{2}\). The n-firm’s profit is \(\pi _{2n}^n=(p_{nn}-c_n)(1-\frac{p_{nn}-p_{no}-v(1-\alpha )}{h_o-h_n})\). The optimal \(p_{nn}\) is given by the first order condition: \(p_{nn}=\frac{c_n-(h_n-h_o)+p_{no}+v(1-\alpha )}{2}\). Solving the two equations, we obtain \(p_{no}^*\) and \(p_{nn}^*\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 3

We substitute \(\theta _1, p_{oo}^*, p_{on}^*, p_{no}^*, p_{nn}^*\) into the two firms’ profits. The two variables are \(p_o\) and \(p_n\). The profit functions are concave. The first order conditions give: \(p_o=\frac{c_n+5c_o+3(h_o-h_n)+p_n-3v(1-\alpha )}{7}\) and \(p_n=\frac{5c_n+c_o+5(h_o-h_n)+p_o-v(1-\alpha )}{7}\). Solving the two equations, we obtain \(p_o\) and \(p_n\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 4

\(c_n>c_o\) and \(h_o>h_n\). So, \(p_n-p_o=\frac{2(c_n-c_o)+(h_o-h_n)+v(1-\alpha )}{4}>0\). \(v(1-\alpha )<(h_o-h_n)\), so \(p_{on}-p_{oo}=\frac{18(c_n-c_o)+7(h_o-h_n)-v(1-\alpha )}{48}>0\), \(p_{nn}-p_{no}=\frac{18(c_n-c_o)+23(h_o-h_n)+31v(1-\alpha )}{48}>0\), \(p_{no}-p_{oo}=\frac{6(c_n-c_o)+5(h_o-h_n)+13v(1-\alpha )}{48}>0\), \(p_{on}-p_{nn}=\frac{6(c_n-c_o)+11(h_o-h_n)+19v(1-\alpha )}{48}>0\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 5

The differences between the market shares of the o-firm and the n-firm in the two periods are: \(so_1-sn_1=\frac{2(c_n-c_o)-(h_o-h_n)-v(1-\alpha )}{8(h_o-h_n)}\), and \( so_2-sn_2=\frac{5[2(c_n-c_o)-(h_o-h_n)-v(1-\alpha )]}{8(h_o-h_n)}\). The difference between the profits of the two firms is \(\pi _o-\pi _n= \frac{13[2(c_n-c_o)-(h_o-h_n)-v(1-\alpha )]}{24}\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 6

\(\frac{\partial \pi _n}{\partial (h_o-h_n)}=[1620A^2 (h_o-h_n)^2-3576A (h_o-h_n)+1847]-540Av(1-\alpha )-\frac{263v^2(1-\alpha )^2}{(h_o-h_n)^2}\). \(\frac{\partial ^4 \pi _n}{\partial (h_o-h_n)^4}>0\). \(\frac{\partial ^3 \pi _n}{\partial (h_o-h_n)^3}\) changes from negative to positive as \((h_o-h_n)\) increases. \(\frac{\partial ^2 \pi _n}{\partial (h_o-h_n)^2}\) first decreases from a positive value, then increases, however, we cannot judge the value is positive or negative. We use the compel method. \(\frac{\partial \pi _n}{\partial (h_o-h_n)}\) is larger than \(\frac{135A^2(h_o-h_n)^2-343A(h_o-h_n)+132}{192}\), and smaller than \(\frac{1620A^2(h_o-h_n)^2-3576A(h_o-h_n)+1847}{2304}\). From the monotonicity of the two functions, \(\frac{\partial \pi _n}{\partial (h_o-h_n)}\) increases then decreases. Thus, \((h_o-h_n)^*\) satisfies \(\frac{\partial \pi _n}{\partial (h_o-h_n)}=0\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 7

When \(v(1-\alpha )\le \frac{2}{3A}\), we substitute \(h_o-h_n=\frac{2+\sqrt{4-6Av(1-\alpha )}}{6A}\) into \(\frac{\partial \pi _n}{\partial (h_o-h_n)}\).

If \(\frac{\partial \pi _n}{\partial (h_o-h_n)}\le 0\), that is, \(v(1-\alpha ) \le \frac{53(\sqrt{6817}-2619)}{4096A}\), \(h^*=(h_o-h_n)^* \ge \frac{2+\sqrt{4-6Av(1-\alpha )}}{6A}\).

If \(\frac{\partial \pi _n}{\partial (h_o-h_n)}> 0\), that is, \(v(1-\alpha ) > \frac{53(\sqrt{6817}-2619)}{4096A}\), \(h^*=(h_o-h_n)^* < \frac{2+\sqrt{4-6Av(1-\alpha )}}{6A}\). When \(v(1-\alpha )> \frac{2}{3A}\), we substitute \(h_o-h_n=\frac{\sqrt{4+2Av(1-\alpha )}-2}{2A}\) into \(\frac{\partial \pi _n}{\partial (h_o-h_n)}\). \(\frac{\partial \pi _n}{\partial (h_o-h_n)}\le 0\), \(h^*=(h_o-h_n)^* < \frac{\sqrt{4+2Av(1-\alpha )}-2}{2A}\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 8

\(\varDelta \pi _n=\frac{[v(1-\alpha )-3(h_o-h_n)][6(c_n-c_o)-3(h_o-h_n) -11v(1-\alpha )]}{96(h_o-h_n)}-\frac{[11(h_o-h_n)-6(c_n-c_o) +19v(1-\alpha )]^2}{2304(h_o-h_n)}\)\(>0\), which can be transformed to the form in the proposition. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Wang, X., Ng, C.T. New retail versus traditional retail in e-commerce: channel establishment, price competition, and consumer recognition. Ann Oper Res 291, 921–937 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-018-2994-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-018-2994-9

Keywords

Navigation