Understanding time-inconsistent heterogeneous preferences in economics and finance: a practice theory approach
- 32 Downloads
Abstract
This paper introduces an innovative framework for decision making by individuals with inconsistent preferences. Practices, associations of individuals with a preference set shared by its members, provide context and unify preferences across an economy so that decision-makers are situated in social and economic structures. Our framework models the time evolution of certain attributes, emerging from the practice framework, that govern individuals’ decisions and their intertemporal variation. A novel feature is that preferences are able to rank other preference sets without the need to aggregate them. Instead, the selection of a preference set is treated as a decision in its own right. Our framework explains decision making paradoxes such as the disposition effect and agency cost considerations that are frequently encountered in the behavioural finance and economics literature.
Keywords
Intertemporal choice Time-inconsistent preferences Multiple selves Disposition effect Decision theoryJEL Classification
D81 D91 G40Notes
Acknowledgements
The authors would like to thank Anthony Ferner as well as participants at the 2014 Bachelier Finance Society conference, the 2014 BAFA conference, and from seminars at De Montfort University, Coventry University, the University of Durham and the University of Lancaster for their helpful comments and suggestions on earlier versions of this paper. We gratefully acknowledge the contribution of Yulia Rodionova and Syed Mansoob Murshed in the development of this paper.
References
- Agastya, M., & Slinko, A. (2015). Dynamic choice in a complex world. Journal of Economic Theory, 158, 232–258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Ainslie, G. W. (1992). Picoeconomics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
- Akerlof, G., & Kranton, R. E. (2000). Economics and identity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 715–753.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Akerlof, G. A., & Kranton, R. E. (2005). Identity and the economics of organizations. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(1), 9–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Ambrus, A., & Rozen, K. (2015). Rationalising choice with multi-self models. The Economic Journal, 125(585), 1136–1156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm-glow giving. The Economic Journal, 100(401), 464–477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Barberis, N., & Xiong, W. (2009). What drives the disposition effect? An analysis of a long-standing preference-based explanation. Journal of Finance, 64(2), 751–784.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Barberis, N., & Xiong, W. (2012). Realization utility. Journal of Financial Economics, 104(2), 251–271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Barseghyan, L., Molinari, F., O’Donoghue, T., & Teitelbaum, J. C. (2013). The nature of risk preferences: Evidence from insurance choices. American Economic Review, 103(6), 2499–2529.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Benabou, R., & Tirole, J. (2002). Self-confidence and personal motivation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 871–915.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Benhabib, J., Bisin, A., & Schotter, A. (2010). Present-bias, quasi-hyperbolic discounting, and fixed costs. Games and Economic Behavior, 69(2), 205–223.Google Scholar
- Bleichrodt, H., Rohde, K. I., & Wakker, P. P. (2009). Non-hyperbolic time inconsistency. Games and Economic Behavior, 66(1), 27–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Chatterjee, K., & Krishna, R. V. (2009). A ‘dual self’ representation for stochastic temptation. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 1(2), 148–167.Google Scholar
- Cherepanov, V., Feddersen, T., & Sandroni, A. (2013). Rationalization. Theoretical Economics, 8(3), 775–800.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cho, S. Y., Arthurs, J. D., Townsend, D. M., Miller, D. R., & Barden, J. Q. (2016). Performance deviations and acquisition premiums: The impact of CEO celebrity on managerial risk-taking. Strategic Management Journal, 37(13), 2677–2694.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cres, H., Gilboa, I., & Vieille, N. (2011). Aggregation of multiple prior opinions. Journal of Economic Theory, 146(6), 2563–2582.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Danan, E., Gajdos, T., Hill, B., & Tallon, J. (2014). Aggregating tastes, beliefs, and attitudes under uncertainty. HEC Paris research paper no. ECO/SCD-2014-1057.Google Scholar
- Dasgupta, P., & Maskin, E. (2005). Uncertainty and hyperbolic discounting. American Economic Review, 95(4), 1290–1299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- DiMaggio, P., & Powell, W. W. (1983). The iron cage revisited: Collective rationality and institutional isomorphism in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48(2), 147–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Dittmann, I., & Maug, E. (2007). Lower salaries and no options: The optimal structure of executive pay. Journal of Finance, 62(1), 303–343.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Evren, O., & Minardi, S. (2017). Warm glow giving and freedom to be selfish. The Economics Journal, 127(603), 1381–1409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Evren, O., & Ok, E. A. (2011). On the multi-utility representation of preference relations. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 47(4), 554–563.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Gilboa, I., Maccheroni, F., Marinacci, M., & Schmeidler, D. (2010). Objective and subjective rationality in a multiple prior model. Econometrica, 78(2), 755–770.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Green, J.R., & Hojman, D. (2007). Choice, rationality and welfare measurement. Discussion paper, Harvard Institute of Economic Research.Google Scholar
- Green, J.R., & Hojman, D. (2015). Monotonic aggregation of preferences and the rationalization of choice functions. Working paper, University of Chile, Department of Economics.Google Scholar
- Harford, J., & Li, K. (2007). Decoupling CEO wealth and firm performance: The case of acquiring CEOs. Journal of Finance, 62(2), 917–949.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Harris, C., & Laibson, D. (2012). Instantaneous gratification. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(1), 205–248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Harvey, C. M. (1989). Prescriptive models of psychological effects on risk attitudes. Annals of Operation Research, 19(1), 141–170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hu, W.-Y., & Scott, J. S. (2007). Behavioral obstacles in the annuity market. Financial Analyst Journal, 63(6), 71–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Jensen, M. (2005). Agency costs of overvalued equity. Financial Management, 34(1), 5–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Koszegi, B. (2006). Ego utility, overconfidence and task choice. Journal of the European Economic Association, 4(4), 673–707.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Koszegi, B., & Rabin, M. (2009). Reference-dependent consumption plans. American Economic Review, 99(3), 909–936.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kuhnen, C. M., & Tymula, A. (2012). Feedback, self-esteem, and performance in organizations. Management Science, 58(1), 94–113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Laibson, D. (1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), 444–477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Lilley, A., & Slonim, R. (2014). The price of warm glow. Journal of Public Economics, 114, 58–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (1992). Anomalies in intertemporal choice: Evidence and an interpretation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 573–597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- MacIntyre, A. (1985). After virtue: A study in moral theory (2nd ed.). London: Duckworth.Google Scholar
- Manzini, P., & Mariotti, M. (2007). Sequentially rationalizable choice. American Economic Review, 97(5), 1824–1839.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Mitchell, R. K., Agle, B. R., & Wood, D. J. (1997). Toward a theory of stakeholder identification and salience: Defining the principle of who and what really counts. Academy of Management Review, 22(4), 853–886.Google Scholar
- Nehring, K. (2009). Imprecise probabilistic beliefs as a context for decision-making under ambiguity. Journal of Economic Theory, 144(3), 1054–1091.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Noor, J. (2009). Hyperbolic discounting and the standard model: Eliciting discount functions. Journal of Economic Theory, 144(5), 2077–2083.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Odean, T. (1998). Are investors reluctant to realize their losses? Journal of Finance, 53(5), 1775–1798.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Pagel, M. (2013). Expectations-based reference-dependent life-cycle consumption. Working paper no. 47138, University Library of Munich, Germany.Google Scholar
- Prelec, D. (2004). Decreasing impatience: A criterion for non-stationary time preference and ‘hyperbolic’ discounting. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 106(3), 511–532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Qu, X. (2017). Separate aggregation of beliefs and values under ambiguity. Economic Theory, 63(2), 503–519.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Read, D., & Read, N. L. (2004). Time discounting over the lifespan. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 94(1), 22–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Roll, R. (1986). The hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers. Journal of Business, 59(2), 197–216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Sayman, S., & Onculer, A. (2009). An investigation of time inconsistency. Management Science, 55(3), 470–482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Scholten, M., & Read, D. (2010). The psychology of intertemporal trade-offs. Psychological Review, 117(3), 925–944.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Shefrin, H., & Statman, M. (1985). The disposition to sell winners too early and ride losers too long: Theory and evidence. Journal of Finance, 40(3), 777–790.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Sydnor, J. (2010). (Over)insuring modest risks. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2(4), 177–199.Google Scholar
- Thaler, R. (1981). Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency. Economics Letters, 8(3), 201–207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Tversky, A. (1969). Intransitivity of preferences. Psychological Review, 76(1), 31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5(4), 297–323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Weber, M., & Camerer, C. F. (1998). The disposition effect in securities trading: An experimental analysis. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 33(2), 167–184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar