Advertisement

Understanding time-inconsistent heterogeneous preferences in economics and finance: a practice theory approach

  • Panagiotis Andrikopoulos
  • Nick Webber
S.I.: Application of O. R. to Financial Markets
  • 68 Downloads

Abstract

This paper introduces an innovative framework for decision making by individuals with inconsistent preferences. Practices, associations of individuals with a preference set shared by its members, provide context and unify preferences across an economy so that decision-makers are situated in social and economic structures. Our framework models the time evolution of certain attributes, emerging from the practice framework, that govern individuals’ decisions and their intertemporal variation. A novel feature is that preferences are able to rank other preference sets without the need to aggregate them. Instead, the selection of a preference set is treated as a decision in its own right. Our framework explains decision making paradoxes such as the disposition effect and agency cost considerations that are frequently encountered in the behavioural finance and economics literature.

Keywords

Intertemporal choice Time-inconsistent preferences Multiple selves Disposition effect Decision theory 

JEL Classification

D81 D91 G40 

Notes

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Anthony Ferner as well as participants at the 2014 Bachelier Finance Society conference, the 2014 BAFA conference, and from seminars at De Montfort University, Coventry University, the University of Durham and the University of Lancaster for their helpful comments and suggestions on earlier versions of this paper. We gratefully acknowledge the contribution of Yulia Rodionova and Syed Mansoob Murshed in the development of this paper.

References

  1. Agastya, M., & Slinko, A. (2015). Dynamic choice in a complex world. Journal of Economic Theory, 158, 232–258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Ainslie, G. W. (1992). Picoeconomics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  3. Akerlof, G., & Kranton, R. E. (2000). Economics and identity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 715–753.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Akerlof, G. A., & Kranton, R. E. (2005). Identity and the economics of organizations. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(1), 9–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Ambrus, A., & Rozen, K. (2015). Rationalising choice with multi-self models. The Economic Journal, 125(585), 1136–1156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm-glow giving. The Economic Journal, 100(401), 464–477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Barberis, N., & Xiong, W. (2009). What drives the disposition effect? An analysis of a long-standing preference-based explanation. Journal of Finance, 64(2), 751–784.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Barberis, N., & Xiong, W. (2012). Realization utility. Journal of Financial Economics, 104(2), 251–271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Barseghyan, L., Molinari, F., O’Donoghue, T., & Teitelbaum, J. C. (2013). The nature of risk preferences: Evidence from insurance choices. American Economic Review, 103(6), 2499–2529.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Benabou, R., & Tirole, J. (2002). Self-confidence and personal motivation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 871–915.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Benhabib, J., Bisin, A., & Schotter, A. (2010). Present-bias, quasi-hyperbolic discounting, and fixed costs. Games and Economic Behavior, 69(2), 205–223.Google Scholar
  12. Bleichrodt, H., Rohde, K. I., & Wakker, P. P. (2009). Non-hyperbolic time inconsistency. Games and Economic Behavior, 66(1), 27–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Chatterjee, K., & Krishna, R. V. (2009). A ‘dual self’ representation for stochastic temptation. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 1(2), 148–167.Google Scholar
  14. Cherepanov, V., Feddersen, T., & Sandroni, A. (2013). Rationalization. Theoretical Economics, 8(3), 775–800.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Cho, S. Y., Arthurs, J. D., Townsend, D. M., Miller, D. R., & Barden, J. Q. (2016). Performance deviations and acquisition premiums: The impact of CEO celebrity on managerial risk-taking. Strategic Management Journal, 37(13), 2677–2694.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Cres, H., Gilboa, I., & Vieille, N. (2011). Aggregation of multiple prior opinions. Journal of Economic Theory, 146(6), 2563–2582.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Danan, E., Gajdos, T., Hill, B., & Tallon, J. (2014). Aggregating tastes, beliefs, and attitudes under uncertainty. HEC Paris research paper no. ECO/SCD-2014-1057.Google Scholar
  18. Dasgupta, P., & Maskin, E. (2005). Uncertainty and hyperbolic discounting. American Economic Review, 95(4), 1290–1299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. DiMaggio, P., & Powell, W. W. (1983). The iron cage revisited: Collective rationality and institutional isomorphism in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48(2), 147–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Dittmann, I., & Maug, E. (2007). Lower salaries and no options: The optimal structure of executive pay. Journal of Finance, 62(1), 303–343.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Evren, O., & Minardi, S. (2017). Warm glow giving and freedom to be selfish. The Economics Journal, 127(603), 1381–1409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Evren, O., & Ok, E. A. (2011). On the multi-utility representation of preference relations. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 47(4), 554–563.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Gilboa, I., Maccheroni, F., Marinacci, M., & Schmeidler, D. (2010). Objective and subjective rationality in a multiple prior model. Econometrica, 78(2), 755–770.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Green, J.R., & Hojman, D. (2007). Choice, rationality and welfare measurement. Discussion paper, Harvard Institute of Economic Research.Google Scholar
  25. Green, J.R., & Hojman, D. (2015). Monotonic aggregation of preferences and the rationalization of choice functions. Working paper, University of Chile, Department of Economics.Google Scholar
  26. Harford, J., & Li, K. (2007). Decoupling CEO wealth and firm performance: The case of acquiring CEOs. Journal of Finance, 62(2), 917–949.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Harris, C., & Laibson, D. (2012). Instantaneous gratification. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(1), 205–248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Harvey, C. M. (1989). Prescriptive models of psychological effects on risk attitudes. Annals of Operation Research, 19(1), 141–170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Hu, W.-Y., & Scott, J. S. (2007). Behavioral obstacles in the annuity market. Financial Analyst Journal, 63(6), 71–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Jensen, M. (2005). Agency costs of overvalued equity. Financial Management, 34(1), 5–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Koszegi, B. (2006). Ego utility, overconfidence and task choice. Journal of the European Economic Association, 4(4), 673–707.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Koszegi, B., & Rabin, M. (2009). Reference-dependent consumption plans. American Economic Review, 99(3), 909–936.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Kuhnen, C. M., & Tymula, A. (2012). Feedback, self-esteem, and performance in organizations. Management Science, 58(1), 94–113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Laibson, D. (1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), 444–477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Lilley, A., & Slonim, R. (2014). The price of warm glow. Journal of Public Economics, 114, 58–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (1992). Anomalies in intertemporal choice: Evidence and an interpretation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 573–597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. MacIntyre, A. (1985). After virtue: A study in moral theory (2nd ed.). London: Duckworth.Google Scholar
  39. Manzini, P., & Mariotti, M. (2007). Sequentially rationalizable choice. American Economic Review, 97(5), 1824–1839.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Mitchell, R. K., Agle, B. R., & Wood, D. J. (1997). Toward a theory of stakeholder identification and salience: Defining the principle of who and what really counts. Academy of Management Review, 22(4), 853–886.Google Scholar
  41. Nehring, K. (2009). Imprecise probabilistic beliefs as a context for decision-making under ambiguity. Journal of Economic Theory, 144(3), 1054–1091.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Noor, J. (2009). Hyperbolic discounting and the standard model: Eliciting discount functions. Journal of Economic Theory, 144(5), 2077–2083.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Odean, T. (1998). Are investors reluctant to realize their losses? Journal of Finance, 53(5), 1775–1798.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Pagel, M. (2013). Expectations-based reference-dependent life-cycle consumption. Working paper no. 47138, University Library of Munich, Germany.Google Scholar
  45. Prelec, D. (2004). Decreasing impatience: A criterion for non-stationary time preference and ‘hyperbolic’ discounting. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 106(3), 511–532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Qu, X. (2017). Separate aggregation of beliefs and values under ambiguity. Economic Theory, 63(2), 503–519.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Read, D., & Read, N. L. (2004). Time discounting over the lifespan. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 94(1), 22–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Roll, R. (1986). The hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers. Journal of Business, 59(2), 197–216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Sayman, S., & Onculer, A. (2009). An investigation of time inconsistency. Management Science, 55(3), 470–482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Scholten, M., & Read, D. (2010). The psychology of intertemporal trade-offs. Psychological Review, 117(3), 925–944.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Shefrin, H., & Statman, M. (1985). The disposition to sell winners too early and ride losers too long: Theory and evidence. Journal of Finance, 40(3), 777–790.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Sydnor, J. (2010). (Over)insuring modest risks. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2(4), 177–199.Google Scholar
  53. Thaler, R. (1981). Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency. Economics Letters, 8(3), 201–207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Tversky, A. (1969). Intransitivity of preferences. Psychological Review, 76(1), 31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5(4), 297–323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Weber, M., & Camerer, C. F. (1998). The disposition effect in securities trading: An experimental analysis. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 33(2), 167–184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Centre for Financial and Corporate Integrity (CFCI)Coventry UniversityCoventryUK
  2. 2.School of MathematicsUniversity of BirminghamBirminghamUK

Personalised recommendations