Abstract
In this paper, we address the question of when portfolio selection based on Value-at-risk encourages diversification [in the sense of Ibragimov (Quant Financ 9(5):565–580, 2009)]. Specifically, we give sufficient conditions for the case when losses follow a Lévy process. When the process has finite variation, these conditions are also necessary. We then specialize our results to the case when losses have tempered stable distributions.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.
References
Aas, K., Haff, I.H., Dimakos, X.K.: Risk estimation using the multivariate normal inverse Gaussian distribution. J Risk 8(2), 39–60 (2006)
Artzner, P., Delbaen, F., Eber, J., Heath, D.: Coherent measures of risk. Math Financ 9(3), 203–228 (1999)
Clark, P.K.: A subordinated stochastic process model with finite variance for speculative prices. Econometrica 41(1), 135–155 (1973)
Cont, R., Tankov, P.: Financial Modelling with Jump Processes. Boca Raton: Chapman & Hall (2004)
Daníelsson, J., Jorgensen, B.N., Samorodnitsky, G., Sarma, M., de Vries, C.G.: Fat tails, VaR and subadditivity. J Econ 172(2), 283–291 (2013)
Embrechts, P., Klüppelberg, C., Mikosch, T.: Modelling Extremal Events or Insurance and Finance. Berlin: Springer (1997)
Garcia, R., Renault, E., Tsafack, G.: Proper conditioning for coherent var in portfolio management. Manag Sci 53(3), 483–494 (2007)
Grabchak, M.: Limit theorem for tempered stable and related distributions. (2012a). arXiv:1201.6006
Grabchak, M.: On a new class of tempered stable distributions: moments and regular variation. J Appl Probab 49(4), 1015–1035 (2012b)
Grabchak, M.: Inversions of Lévy measures and the relation between long and short time behavior of Lévy processes. J Theor Probab (2013). doi:10.1007/s10959-012-0476-6
Grabchak, M., Molchanov, S.A.: Limit theorems and phase transitions for two models of summation of iid random variables depending on parameters. Doklady Math 88(1), 431–434 (2013)
Grabchak, M., Samorodnitsky, G.: Do financial returns have finite or infinite variance? A paradox and an explanation. Quant Financ 10(8), 883–893 (2010)
Ibragimov, R.: Efficiency of linear estimators under under heavy-tailedness: convolutions of \(\alpha \)-symmetric distributions. Econ Theory 23(3), 501–517 (2007)
Ibragimov, R.: Portfolio diversification and value at risk under thick-tailedness. Quant Financ 9(5), 565–580 (2009)
Ibragimov, R., Walden, J.: Portfolio diversification under local deviations from power laws. Insur Math Econ 42(2), 594–599 (2008)
Ibragimov, R., Walden, J.: Optimal bundling strategies under heavy-tailed valuations. Manag Sci 56(11), 1963–1976 (2010)
Ibragimov, R., Walden, J.: Value at risk and efficiency under dependence and heavy-tailedness: models with common shocks. Ann Financ 7(3), 285–318 (2011)
Jorion, P.: Value at Risk: The New Benchmark for Managing Financial Risk, 3rd edn. New York: McGraw-Hill (2006)
Kallenberg, O.: Foundations of Modern Probability, 2nd edn. New York: Springer (2002)
Kim, Y.S., Giacometti, R., Rachev, S.T., Fabozzi, F.J., Mignacca, D.: Measuring financial risk and portfolio optimization with a non-Gaussian multivariate model. Ann Oper Res 201(1), 325–343 (2012)
Koponen, I.: Analytic approach to the problem of convergence of truncated Lévy flights towards the Gaussian stochastic process. Phys Rev E 52(1), 1197–1199 (1995)
Maejima, M., Nakahara, G.: A note on new classes of infinitely divisible distributions on \(\mathbb{R}^d\). Electron Commun Probab 14, 358–371 (2009)
Mandelbrot, B., Taylor, H.M.: On the distribution of stock price differences. Oper Res 15(6), 1057–1062 (1967)
Mantegna, R.N., Stanley, H.E.: Stochastic process with ultraslow convergence to a Gaussian: the truncated Lévy flight. Phys Rev Lett 73(22), 2946–2949 (1994)
Marshall, A.W., Olkin, I., Arnold, B.C.: Inequalities: Theory of Majorization and Its Applications, 2nd edn. New York: Springer (2011)
McNeil, A.J., Frey, R., Embrechts, P.: Quantitative Risk Management: Concepts, Techniques and Tools. Princeton: Princeton University Press (2005)
Rachev, S.T. (Ed.): Handbook of Heavy Tailed Distributions in Finance. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science (2003)
Rachev, S.T., Kim, Y.S., Bianchi, M.L., Fabozzi, F.J.: Financial Models with Levy Processes and Volatility Clustering. London: Wiley (2011)
Rosiński, J.: Tempering stable processes. Stoch Process Appl 117(6), 677–707 (2007)
Rosiński, J., Sinclair, J.L.: Generalized tempered stable processes. Banach Center Publ 90, 153–170 (2010)
Samorodnitsky, G., Taqqu, M.: Stochastic monotonicity and Slepian-type inequalities for infinitely divisible and stable random vectors. Ann Probab 21(1), 143–160 (1993)
Samorodnitsky, G., Taqqu, M.: Levy measures of infinitely divisible random vectors and Slepian inequalities. Ann Probab 22(4), 1930–1956 (1994)
Sato, K.: Lévy Processes and Infinitely Divisible Distributions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (1999)
Acknowledgments
The author wishes to thank Dr. Weidong Tian for the benefit of several discussions and the anonymous referee whose suggestions lead to a great improvement in the presentation of this paper.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendix
Appendix
The proof of Theorem 1 is based on the following result, which is a specialization of Theorems 2.1 and 3.2 in Samorodnitsky and Taqqu (1994) [see also Theorem 2.2 in Samorodnitsky and Taqqu (1993)].
Lemma 1
Let \(\{X_t:t\ge 0\}\) and \(\{Y_t:t\ge 0\}\) be Lévy processes such that \(X_1\sim ID_0(0,M_X,0)\) and \(Y_1\sim ID_0(0,M_Y,0)\) with \(M_X((-\infty ,0])=M_Y((-\infty ,0])=0\). We have
if and only if
Proof (Proof of Theorem 1)
[Proof of Theorem 1] We only prove results related to Schur-convexity of \(g_r(\cdot )\) as proofs of the other results are similar.
We begin with the case when \(\mu \in \fancyscript{P}\). By positivity, we have \(\mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (X_{\varvec{u},t})\le \mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (X_{\varvec{v},t})\) for all \(t>0\) and all \(\gamma \in (0,1)\) if and only if \(P(X_{\varvec{u},t}>r)\le P(X_{\varvec{v},t}>r)\) for all \(t>0\) and all \(r>0\). By Lemma 1, this holds if and only if \(g_r(\varvec{u})=M_{\varvec{u}}((r,\infty )) \le M_{\varvec{v}}((r,\infty ))=g_r(\varvec{v})\) for all \(r>0\). This holds for all \(\varvec{u},\varvec{v}\in \mathbb R^n_+\) with \(\varvec{u}\prec \varvec{v}\) if and only if \(g_r(\cdot )\) is Schur-convex for all \(r>0\).
Now assume that \(\mu \in \fancyscript{S}\). By symmetry, \(\mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (X_{\varvec{u},t})\le \mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (X_{\varvec{v},t})\) for all \(t>0\) and all \(\gamma \in (.5,1)\) if and only if \(P(X_{\varvec{u},t}>r)\le P(X_{\varvec{v},t}>r)\) for all \(t>0\) and all \(r>0\).
First, consider the case when \(\int _{\mathbb R}\left( |x|\wedge 1\right) M(\mathrm{d}x)<\infty \). For any \(\varvec{w}\in \mathbb R^n_+\) and any \(t>0\), the distribution of \(X_{\varvec{w},t}\) is symmetric around zero and thus \(X_{\varvec{w},t} \mathop {=}\limits ^{d}X_{\varvec{w},t}^{(1)}-X^{(2)}_{\varvec{w}, t}\) where \(\{X_{\varvec{w},t}^{(1)}:t\ge 0\}\) and \(\{X_{\varvec{w},t}^{(2)}:t\ge 0\}\) are independent Lévy processes with \(X^{(1)}_{\varvec{w},1},X^{(2)}_{\varvec{w},1}\mathop {\sim }\limits ^{\mathrm{iid}}ID_0(0,M'_{\varvec{w}},0)\) and
where \(M_{\varvec{w}}\) is as in (7). Note that \(|X_{\varvec{w},t}|\mathop {=}\limits ^{d}X^{(1)}_{\varvec{w},t}+X^{(2)}_{\varvec{w},t}\sim ID_0(0,2M'_{\varvec{w}},0)\). If \(r>0\) then, by symmetry,
Thus,
is equivalent to
By Lemma 1 this is equivalent to
Since \(M'_{\varvec{u}}((r,\infty )) = g_{r}(\varvec{u})\) and \(M'_{\varvec{v}}((r,\infty )) =g_{r}(\varvec{v})\), this is equivalent to
which is equivalent to \(g_r(\cdot )\) being Schur-convex for each \(r>0\).
Now, consider the case \(\int _{\mathbb R}\left( |x|\wedge 1\right) M(\mathrm{d}x)=\infty \). Assume that \(g_r(\cdot )\) is Schur-convex for each \(r>0\). Here the Lévy measure is not well behaved near zero, so we begin by truncating it. For a vector \(\varvec{w}\in \mathbb R_+^n\) define
Let \(\{X^{(m)}_{\varvec{w},t}:t\ge 0\}\) be a Lévy process where \(X^{(m)}_{\varvec{w},1}\sim ID(0,M^{(m)}_{\varvec{w}},0)\). Since \(M^{(m)}_{\varvec{w}}\) is symmetric, \(\int _{\mathbb R} \left( |x|\wedge 1\right) M^{(m)}_{\varvec{w}}(\mathrm{d}x)<\infty \), and \(M_{\varvec{w}}^{(m)}((r,\infty ))=g_{r\vee (1/m)}(\varvec{w})\) is Schur-convex for all \(r>0\), we can use arguments as in the previous case to show that
We now remove the truncation by taking limits. Using standard results for convergence of infinitely divisible distributions (see e.g. Theorem 15.14 in Kallenberg (2002)) it is straightforward to show that \(X^{(m)}_{\varvec{u},t}\mathop {\rightarrow }\limits ^{d}X_{\varvec{u},t}\) and \(X^{(m)}_{\varvec{v},t}\mathop {\rightarrow }\limits ^{d}X_{\varvec{v},t}\) as \(m\rightarrow \infty \). Further, so long as \(\varvec{u},\varvec{v}\ne \varvec{0}\), we have \(M_{\varvec{u}}(\mathbb R)=M_{\varvec{v}}(\mathbb R)=\infty \) and thus, by Theorem 27.4 in Sato (1999), both \(X_{\varvec{u},t}\) and \(X_{\varvec{v},t}\) have continuous distributions. Hence, for every \(t>0\) and \(r>0\),
If \(\varvec{u}=\varvec{0}\) or \(\varvec{v}=\varvec{0}\) then \(\varvec{u}=\varvec{v}=\varvec{0}\) and the result is immediate.
Before proving Corollary 1, we give the following fact, which follows from the proof of Proposition A.6 in Ibragimov (2009).
Lemma 2
Let \(X_1,X_2,\ldots ,X_n\) and \(Y_1,Y_2,\ldots ,Y_n\) be two sets of independent random variables all having symmetric unimodal densities. If \(\mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (X_i)\le \mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (Y_i)\) for all \(=1,2,\ldots ,n\) and all \(\gamma \in (.5,1)\) then \(\mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (\sum _{i=1}^nX_i)\le \mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (\sum _{i=1}^nY_i)\) for all \(\gamma \in (.5,1)\).
Proof (Proof of Corollary 1)
We focus on the case \(t=1\) as the other cases are similar. If \(a=0\) the result follows by Theorem 1. Now assume that \(a\ne 0\). Let \(Z_{1},\ldots , Z_{n}\mathop {\sim }\limits ^{\mathrm{iid}}N(0,1)\) and let \(Y_{1},\ldots ,Y_{n}\mathop {\sim }\limits ^{\mathrm{iid}}ID(0,M,0)\) be independent sequences of random variables. If \(X_{1}, \ldots ,X_{n}\mathop {\sim }\limits ^{\mathrm{iid}}\mu \) then \((X_1,\ldots ,X_n)\mathop {=}\limits ^{d}(\sqrt{a}Z_1+Y_1, \ldots ,\sqrt{a}Z_n+Y_n)\). For any \(\varvec{w}\in \mathbb R^n_+\) we have \(X_{\varvec{w}} \mathop {=}\limits ^{d}\sqrt{a} Z_{\varvec{w}} + Y_{\varvec{w}}\). If \(\varvec{u}\prec \varvec{v}\) then Theorem 1 implies that \(\mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (Y_{\varvec{u}})\le \mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (Y_{\varvec{v}})\) and Proposition A.7 in Ibragimov (2009) implies that \(\mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (\sqrt{a}Z_{\varvec{u}})\le \mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (\sqrt{a}Z_{\varvec{v}})\). By Proposition A.5 in Ibragimov (2009) both \(Z_{\varvec{u}}\) and \(Y_{\varvec{u}}\) have symmetric and unimodal densities. Thus the result follows by Lemma 2.
Proof (Proof of Proposition 1.)
[Proof of Proposition 1.] If \(f_r(\cdot )\) is convex then \(g_r(\cdot )\) is Schur-convex by Proposition C.1 on page 92 in Marshall et al. (2011). Now assume that \(M\) has a continuous Lebesgue density \(m\). This implies that \(f_r(s)\) is a continuous function of \(s\) and thus it is convex if and only if \(g_r(\cdot )\) is Schur-convex by Proposition C.1 on page 92 and Proposition C.1.c on page 95 of Marshall et al. (2011). By Leibniz’s rule \(f_r(s)\) is differentiable in \(s\) and
From here, the fact that a differentiable function is convex if and only if its derivative is non-decreasing gives the equivalence between the convexity of \(f_r(\cdot )\) and the non-increasing of \(x^2m(x)\). Conditions for \(g_r(\cdot )\) to be Schur-concave can be shown in a similar way using the corresponding properties of concave and Schur-concave functions.
Proof (Proof of Corollary 3)
[Proof of Corollary 3] By Theorem 30.1 in Sato (1999), \(W_Y\sim ID(0,M^*,0)\) where \(M^*\) has a continuous density \(m^*(x)\) given by
Thus
From here the result follows by Corollary 2.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Grabchak, M. Does value-at-risk encourage diversification when losses follow tempered stable or more general Lévy processes?. Ann Finance 10, 553–568 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-014-0249-6
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-014-0249-6