Skip to main content
Log in

An international reserves variation threshold to increase loan funding

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Economics and Economic Policy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this article we propose a methodology for the calculation of an international reserves variation threshold that defines the lending decisions of international creditors to developing countries. If the change in net international reserves of the borrowing variation is above that of the threshold, the creditors are willing to lend more. Otherwise, if that change is below the threshold, there will be capital flight. Such a threshold depends on the stocks of debt and international reserves, as well as on the perception of the default risk of the country to honour its debts. Using that threshold, we perform a counterfactual exercise to calculate the time series of international reserve levels that minimize the total cost of reserves holding, namely, the cost of possible illiquidity of the country plus the opportunity cost of holding international reserves. We illustrate the methodology by applying it to five Latin American countries: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Mexico and Peru.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We will use ϕ = 0.44 for this parameter value, as suggested in Duffie and Singleton (2003), p. 124.

  2. We will take values between 5% and 15% of the GDP.

  3. This can be measured as the sum of the average normal risk premium (average normal EMBI spread) and the term premium (difference between the three-year U.S. Treasury bond and the US T-bill rate).

References

  • Aizenman J, Lee J (2007) International reserves: Precautionary versus mercantilist views, theory and evidence. Open Econ Rev 18:191–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alberola E, Erce A, Serena J (2016) International reserves and gross capital flows. J Int Money Financ 60:151–171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano C (2008) Default risk and income fluctuations in emerging economies. Am Econ Rev 98(3):690–712

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Bassat A, Gottlieb D (1992) Optimal international reserves and sovereign risk. J Int Econ 33:345–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bianchi J, Hatchondo JC, Martinez L (2018) International reserves and rollover risk. Am Econ Rev 108(9):2629–2670

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo G, Izquierdo A, Loo-Kung R (2013) Optimal holdings of international reserves: self-insurance against sudden stop. Monetaria (CEMLA) 1 (1):1–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Cuadra G, Sanchez JM, Sapriza H (2010) Fiscal policy and default risk in emerging markets. Rev Econ Dyn 13:452–469

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dooley MP, Folkerts-Landau D, Garber P (2003) An essay on the revived bretton woods system. National Bureau of Economic Research (WP 9971)

  • Duffie D, Singleton KJ (2003) Credit risk: pricing, measurement and management. Princeton University Press, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein M (1999) Self-protection for emerging market economies. National Bureau of Economic Research (WP 6907)

  • Frenkel JA, Jovanic B (1981) Optimal international reserves: a stochastic framework. Econ Js 91(362):507–514

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanson JA (1974) Optimal international borrowing and lending. Am Econ Rev 64(4):616–630

    Google Scholar 

  • Heller HR (1966) Optimal international reserves. Econ J 76 (302):296–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jeanne O, Rancière R (2011) The optimal level of international reserves for emerging market countries: a new formula and some applications. Econ J 121:905–930

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kato M, P CR, Semmler W (2018) Does international-reserves targeting decrease the vulnerability to capital flights? Res Int Bus Financ 44:64–75

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim JI (2008) Sudden stops and optimal self-insurance. IMF Working Paper (WP/08/144)

  • Kim YJ (2017) Sudden stops, limited enforcement, and optimal reserves. Int Rev Econ Financ 51:273–282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korinek A (2016) Undervaluation through foreign reserve accumulation: static losses, dynamic gains. J Int Money Financ 64:104–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy-Yeyati E (2009) Optimal debt? On the insurance value of international debt flows to developing countries. Open Econ Rev 20:489–507

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maldonado W, Tourinho O, Valli J (2007) Endogenous foreign capital flow in a cge model for brazil: The role of foreign reserves. J Policy Model 29:259–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melvin M, Norrbin SC (2013) Direct foreign investment and international lending (international money and finance (8th edn), Ch. 11 ed). Elsevier Inc.

  • Rodrik D (2006) The social cost of foreign exchange reserves. National Bureau of Economic Research (WP11952)

  • Seiber M (1982) International borrowing by developing countries (Pergamon Policy Studies on International Development ed.). Pergamon Press Inc.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Wilfredo L. Maldonado.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A: Theoretical model for the threshold

In this appendix we provide a theoretical justification for the existence of a strategy function for loans funding (strategy function for loans and the threshold of IR variation).

A representative international investor with expected utility u(W) = W1−γ, (γ ≥ 0 the relative risk aversion coefficient) and initial wealth L > 0 (representing the international liquidity for loans) is deciding the rate of increase of loans to a country. The current debt is D = 1 and the perceived variation of IR is \(\theta \in \mathbb {R} \). The rate of return of investments in the country in r and the recovery rate in case of default of the country is (1 − τ). Thus, the investor must decide the optimal level of new total investments in the country \(D^{\prime }\).

The investor assigns a probability π(𝜃) ∈ [0, 1] to the event “the country defaults”. We will suppose that \(\pi ^{\prime }(\theta )<0\). The final wealth of the investor in case of default is:

$$ W_{1}=L-(D^{\prime}-1)+(1-\tau) D^{\prime}=L+1-\tau D^{\prime} $$
(A.1)

and in the case of non-default:

$$ W_{2}=L-(D^{\prime}-1)+(1+r) D^{\prime}=L+1+r D^{\prime} $$
(A.2)

then, the investor problem is:

$$ \max_{D^{\prime}\geq 0} \pi(\theta) u(W_{1}) +(1-\pi(\theta)) u(W_{2}) $$

Using the first order condition for interior solutions and substituting W1 and W2 from Eqs. A.1 and A.2 we obtain:

$$ \Big(\frac{W_{2}}{W_{1}}\Big)^{-\gamma} = \frac{r^{-1}\tau \pi(\theta)}{1-\pi(\theta)} \Rightarrow \frac{L+1+rD^{\prime}}{L+1-\tau D^{\prime}}=\Big[\frac{r^{-1}\tau \pi(\theta)}{1-\pi(\theta)}\Big]^{-1/\gamma} \equiv K(\theta) $$
(A.3)
$$ \Rightarrow D^{\prime}= \frac{(K(\theta)-1)(L+1)}{(r+\tau K(\theta))}. $$
(A.4)

Notice that the function K(⋅) contains parameters like risk aversion, interest rate and recovery rate in case of default. In addition to those parameters, the optimal value \(D^{\prime }\) includes the market liquidity L. The existence of f(⋅) and ξ of definition (2.2) is a consequence of the following two propositions.

Proposition A.1

If π(𝜃) is a strictly decreasing function, \(\pi (-\infty )=1\) and \(\pi (+\infty )=0\), then K(𝜃) defined in Eq. A.3 is a strictly increasing function and satisfies \(K(-\infty )=0\) and \(K(+\infty )=+\infty \).

Proof

The function r− 1τπ(𝜃)/(1 − π(𝜃)) is strictly decreasing, since π(𝜃) is strictly decreasing; thus, K(𝜃) defined in Eq. A.3 is a strictly increasing function. The other two equalities result from the definition of K(𝜃) and using the values of π(⋅) in \(-\infty \) and in \(+\infty \). □

Proposition A.2

With the hypotheses of Proposition A.1, there exists ξ > 0 such that \([\theta > \xi \Leftrightarrow D^{\prime }>1]\).

Proof

Using (A.4) we have that:

$$ D^{\prime}= \frac{(K(\theta)-1)(L+1)}{(r+\tau K(\theta))} > 1 \Leftrightarrow K(\theta)>\frac{L+1+r}{L+1-\tau}\equiv \rho(L) $$

Since K(𝜃) is a strictly increasing function satisfying \(K(-\infty )=0\) and \(K(+\infty )=+\infty \)., the inequality above implies:

$$ \theta>K^{-1}(\rho(L))\equiv \xi. $$
(A.5)

Since \(x = f(\theta ) = D^{\prime }-1\), we can conclude that ξ and f(𝜃) given in Eqs. A.5 and A.4 respectively depend on the risk aversion, interest rate of loans, rate of recovery in case of default and the market liquidity, just as mentioned in Section 2.

A numerical example illustrates the results of Proposition A.2. Notice that from Eq. A.4, the rate of increase of credit concessions to the country is defined by:

$$ x = D^{\prime}-1 = \frac{(K(\theta)-1)(L+1)}{(r+\tau K(\theta))}-1\equiv f(\theta). $$

If we consider π(𝜃) = (1 + 𝜃)− 1, γ = 0.1, L = 5, r = 0.01 and τ = 0.01, the Fig. 3 shows the graphic of x = f(𝜃). The value of the threshold is ξ ≈ 10.0185

Fig. 3
figure 3

Investment strategy function and the threshold ξ > 0.

We can also provide a numerical example illustrating the existence of a negative threshold. Consider negative values for 𝜃 and suppose that π(𝜃) = 1 + 1.2(𝜃 − 0.55)− 1, γ = 0.4, L = 5, r = 0.01 and τ = 0.01. The Fig. 4 shows the investment strategy function and the threshold level is ξ ≈− 0.7685.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Investment strategy function and the threshold ξ < 0.

Appendix B: Stationarity of {𝜃 t}

In this section we test for stationarity of the time series {𝜃t}. We use the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF), Phillips-Perron (PP) and Kwiatkowski-Phillips-Schmidt-Shin(KPSS) stationarity tests and they indicate that the time series {𝜃t} is stationary with significance of 5%, according to the Table 4.

Table 4 Stationarity test of the time series {𝜃t}

In Table 4, the critical values with significance level of 5% of the ADF and PP tests for Argentina, Brazil, Chile and Peru are -2.89, -3.46 and 1.94 for models with intercept, trend and intercept, and none respectively. For the KPSS the critical values test are 0.46 and 0.15 for models with intercept, and trend and intercept respectively. For Mexico, due to the lower number of observations, the critical values of the ADF and PP tests are -2.93, -3.51 and 1.95 for models with intercept, trend and intercept, and none respectively. For the KPSS test the critical values are 0.46 and 0.15 for models with intercept, and trend and intercept respectively.

Once we have checked the stationarity of the time series, we select the more appropriate model using the Akaike, Schwarz and Hanna-Quinn information criteria (AIC, SIC and HQ respectively). Table 5 shows the results of that selection.

Table 5 Selection criteria for the appropriate dynamic model of {𝜃t}

As we can see, the three criteria points out the AR(1) model as the more appropriate for the time series {𝜃t} in each country except for Chile. For that country, the AIC would select the ARMA(1,1); however, we will use the AR(1), since the SIC and HQ criteria select it, that dynamic model is more parsimonious and the AIC statistics of the ARMA(1,1) is not far from that of the AR(1) model. This will allow us to maintain the uniformity of the dynamics in our analysis.

Appendix C: Optimal versus observed IR levels

In this appendix we show the optimal versus the observed path of IR in each country of our group. Figure 5 exhibits the evolution of those time series.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Optimal vs. actual levels of international reserves stocks (US Millions)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Maldonado, W.L., Guillén, J. & Ribeiro, J. An international reserves variation threshold to increase loan funding. Int Econ Econ Policy 18, 247–265 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-021-00491-9

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-021-00491-9

Keywords

Navigation