Abstract
This paper uses two-dimensional asymmetric Taylor reaction functions for 16 OECD-countries to account for different reactions to the inflation rate and output by central banks before or after an election of the fiscal authorities in the respective country. Important for such an investigation is not only the period before or after an election takes place but also whether the inflation rate and output are below or above their target or potential value because this information shows whether the central bank systematically deviates from the Taylor rule. Using a Panel-GMM we observe that in the OECD-countries there are political business cycles in monetary policy with respect to the inflation and output response. However, the supporting time horizon differs between both exogenous indicators and state of variables.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.


Notes
To build an aggregate measure of central bank independence a point score is introduced which captures different dimensions of independence as e.g. who appoints the members of the board of the central bank, the budgetary role of central banks or the objective of the central bank (see Bade and Parkin 1988; Grilli et al. 1991 or Eijffinger and Schaling 1995 among others).
Belke and Potrafke (2009) give an excellent overview over the studies in this field so far.
These countries are: Chile, Czech Republic, Finland, Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Israel, Luxembourg, Mexico, New Zealand, Poland, Portugal, Slovenia, Slovak Republic, South Korea and Turkey.
Within the recent financial crisis it was observed that interest rate cuts or implementation of “unconventional” policy measures were executed at even higher than monthly frequencies.
The assumption of a constant inflation target is challenged by Leigh (2008). There are also several studies estimating a time varying equilibrium real interest rate (see e.g. Laubach and Williams 2003; Cuaresma et al. 2004; Clark and Kozicki 2005; Arestis and Chortareas 2007; Mésonnier and Renne 2007 or Garnier and Wilhelmsen 2009). Belke and Klose (2010) investigate this issue in a Taylor rule framework.
Such an approach is also used by Bec et al. (2002) or Bunzel and Enders (2010) to estimate asymmetric Taylor reaction functions if inflation and output are above or below some target value. Klose (2011) merges both studies and shows that there are asymmetries in the ECB reaction depending on a combination of inflation and output asymmetries.
The number of observations can differ if the election day is at the beginning or end of the sample period, so that there are not enough data points before or after. But these differences are in our context negligible.
Note that six of the 16 countries in this sample have introduced inflation targeting in the last years. So they should only react to this measure. However, tackling the output gap is also reasonable for these countries since the output gap is a good indicator of future inflationary pressures that these central banks need to account for besides the current inflation rate.
Since the US-Dollar and US-Dollar exchange rate is constant we use year-on-year money growth for the US instead of an exchange rate.
These countries are: Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Spain.
In January 2011 Estonia became the seventeenth member of the euro area.
References
Abrams B, Iossifov P (2006) Does the Fed contribute to a political business cycle? Public Choice 129:249–262
Alesina A (1988) Macroeconomics and politics. NBER Macroecon Annu 3:13–62
Alesina A, Summers L (1993) Central bank independence and macroeconomic performance: some comparative evidence. J Money, Credit, Bank 25(2):151–162
Arestis P, Chortareas G (2007) Natural equilibrium real interest rate estimates and monetary policy design. J Post Keynesian Econ 29(4):621–643
Bade R, Parkin M (1988) Central bank laws and monetary policy. University of Western Ontario; October 1988
Bec F, Collard F, Salem M (2002) Asymmetries in monetary policy reaction function: evidence for U.S. French and German Central Banks. Stud Nonlinear Dyn Econ 6(2):Art. 3
Belke A, Klose J (2009) Does the ECB rely on a taylor rule? comparing ex-post with real time data, Ruhr Economic Paper No. 133, Essen
Belke A, Klose J (2010) (How) do the ECB and the Fed react to financial market uncertainty? the taylor rule in times of crisis, Ruhr Economic Paper No. 166, Essen
Belke A, Polleit T (2007) How the ECB and the US Fed set interest rates. Appl Econ 39(17):2197–2209
Belke A, Potrafke N (2009) Does governmental ideology matter in monetary policy? a panel data analysis for OECD-countries, Ruhr Economic Paper, No. 94
Berger H, Woitek U (2001) The German political business cycle: money demand rather than monetary policy. Eur J Polit Econ 17:609–631
Berger H, de Haan J, Eijffinger S (2001) Central bank independence: an update of theory and evidence. J Econ Surv 15:3–40
Bunzel H, Enders W (2010) The Taylor rule and “opportunistic” monetary policy, CREATES Research Paper 2010-4, Aarhus (Denmark)
Clarida R, Gali J, Gertler M (1998) Monetary policy rules in practice–some empirical evidence. Eur Econ Rev 42:1033–1067
Clark T, Kozicki S (2005) Estimating equilibrium real interest rates in real-time. N Am J Econ Finan 16(3):395–413
Cuaresma J, Gnan E, Ritzberger-Gruenwald D (2004) Searching for the natural rate of interest: a euro area perspective. Empirica 31:185–204
Drazen A (2000) The political business cycle after 25 years. In: Bernanke BS, Rogoff K (eds.) NBER macroeconomics annual 2000, vol. 15. MIT Press, pp. 75–138
Eijffinger S, de Haan J (1996) The political economy of central-bank independence; Princeton Special Papers in International Economics, No. 19
Eijffinger S, Schaling E (1995) Central bank independence: criteria and indices, Kredit und Kapital, No.13, pp. 185–217
Eijffinger S, Schaling E, Hoeberichts M (1998) Central bank independence: a sensitivity analysis. Eur J Polit Econ 14:73–88
Fuhrer J (1997) Central bank independence and inflation targeting: monetary policy paradigms for the next millennium. N Engl Econ Rev 1/2:19–36
Galbraith J, Giovannoni O, Russo A (2007) The Fed’s real reaction function–monetary policy, inflation, unemployment, inequality and presidential politics, Levy Economics Institute Working Paper, No. 511
Gamber E, Hakes D (1997) The Federal reserve’s response to aggregate demand and aggregate supply shocks: evidence of a partisan political cycle. South Econ J 63(3):680–691
Garnier J, Wilhelmsen B (2009) The natural real interest rate and the output gap in the euro area: a joint estimation. Empir Econ 36(2):297–319
Gerdesmeier D, Roffia B (2005) The relevance of real-time data in estimating reaction functions for the euro area. N Am J Econ Finan 16(3):293–307
Grilli V, Masciandaro D, Tabellini G (1991) Political and monetary institutions and public financial policies in the industrial countries. Econ Policy 6(13):341–392
Hayo B (1998) Inflation culture, central bank independence and price stability. Eur J Polit Econ 14:241–263
Hayo B, Hefeker C (2008) Does central bank independence cause low inflation? a skeptical view, Paolo Baffi Centre Research Paper No. 2008-04
Hibbs D (1977) Political parties and macroeconomic policy. Am Polit Sci Rev 71:1467–1487
Hielscher K, Markwardt G (2011) The role of political institutions for the effectiveness of central bank independence, Cesifo Working Paper No. 3396, Munich
Hodrick R, Prescott E (1997) Postwar U.S. business cycles: an empirical investigation. J Money, Credit, Bank 29(1):1–16
Kaddour H, Lockwood B, Maloney J (1998) Does central bank independence smooth the political business cycle in inflation? some OECD evidence. Manch Sch Econ Soc Stud 66(4):377–395
Klomp J, de Haan J (2010) Inflation and central bank independence: a meta regression analysis. J Econ Surv 24(4):593–621
Klose J (2011) Asymmetric Taylor reaction functions of the ECB: an approach depending on the state of the economy. N Am J Econ Finan 22(2):149–163
Laubach T, Williams J (2003) Measuring the natural rate of interest. Rev Econ Stat 85(4):1063–1070
Leigh D (2008) Estimating the Federal reserve’s implicit inflation target: a state space approach. J Econ Dyn Control 32:2013–2020
Maloney J, Pickering AC, Kaddour H (2003) Political business cycles and central bank independence. Econ J 113(486):C167–C181
Mésonnier J, Renne J (2007) A time-varying “natural” rate of interest for the euro area. Eur Econ Rev 51:1768–1784
Nordhaus W (1975) The political business cycle. Rev Econ Stud 42:169–190
Orphanides A (2001) Monetary policy rules based on real-time-data. Am Econ Rev 91(4):964–985
Sauer S, Sturm J (2007) Using Taylor rules to understand European central bank monetary policy. Ger Econ Rev 8(3):375–398
Sturm J, de Haan J (2001) Inflation in developing countries: does central bank independence matter? Ifo Stud 47:389–403
Taylor J (1993) Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Carnegie-Rochester Conf Public Policy 39:195–214
Tufte E (1978) Political control of the economy. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
The views expressed in this paper are my personal views and do not necessarily coincide with those of the German Council of Economic Experts.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Klose, J. Political business cycles and monetary policy revisited–an application of a two-dimensional asymmetric Taylor reaction function. Int Econ Econ Policy 9, 265–295 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-012-0213-8
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-012-0213-8
Keywords
- Political business cycle
- Monetary policy
- Taylor rule
- Asymmetries
- Panel-GMM
JEL Classification
- E32
- E43
- E52
- E58