Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

An international multilevel competition policy system

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Economics and Economic Policy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper develops a proposal for an international multilevel competition policy system, which draws on the insights of the analysis of multilevel systems of institutions. In doing so, it targets to contribute bridging a gap in the current world economic order, i.e. the lack of supranational governance of private international restrictions to market competition. Such governance can effectively be designed against the background of a combination of the well-known nondiscrimination principle and a lead jurisdiction model. Put very briefly, competition policy on the global level restricts itself to the selection and appointment of appropriate lead jurisdictions for concrete cross-border antitrust cases, while the substantive treatment remains within the competence of the existing national and regional antitrust regimes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Although it must be emphasised that the problem of an ostensibly unregulated competition among banks and on financial markets is part of the discussion.

  2. Or, in some exceptional instances, the domain of confederations of nation states (like the European Union).

  3. This elaborate discussion cannot be reported here in detail, see instead Budzinski (2008a: 10–150) and the literature quoted therein.

  4. See Barros and Cabral 1994; Head and Ries 1997; Kaiser and Vosgerau 2000; Tay and Willmann 2005; Haucap, Müller and Wey 2006.

  5. See e.g. Jacquemin 1995; Fox 2000; Klodt 2001; ICN 2002; Budzinski 2003a: 4–10; Jenny 2003a, 2003b.

  6. See e.g. Hauser and Schoene 1994; Smets and Van Cayseele 1995; Budzinski 2003a: 11–18; Epstein and Greve 2004; McGinnis 2004; Stephan 2004.

  7. “My overall view is that for a system of antitrust enforcement to remain dynamic, overcentralization must be avoided and some degree of chaos tolerated” (First 2003: 24).

  8. The characterisations ‘upward’ and ‘downward’ do not imply assessments of importance or superiority versus inferiority. In particular, no prejudice about the competence (neither in a positive nor in a normative sense) of a level to exert jurisdiction over an antitrust case is implied. In the context of this paper, top-down only means from centralised to decentralised, e.g. from global to local.

  9. Imagine, e.g., the question of competence allocation between the EU (supranational but regionally limited level) and Canada (national level but not within the regional scope of the EU).

  10. However, the regime is asymmetric. If the government authorities decide not to challenge an arrangement or practice — on whatever grounds — no court supervision occurs.

  11. The European Central Bank represents the most comprehensive example of an independent agency. In competition policy, such a far-reaching independency does not exist, although the Federal Cartel Office of Germany possesses a significant amount of independence (albeit limited by the conditional competence of the Ministry of Economic Affairs to overrule its decisions). In contrast, the EU Competition Directorate is an integral part of the European Commission without formal independence.

  12. The inclusion of consumers represents an important extension of the trade-oriented variant of the nondiscrimination concept.

  13. This represents a modified version of the suggestion by Campbell and Trebilcock (1997: 110–112).

  14. Note that they remain involved in the course of their consultation and cooperation with the appointed lead jurisdiction.

  15. See for an elaborate theoretical analysis Budzinski (2008a: 156–160, 178–217).

  16. The set of possible options is ex ante always indetermined because of the creative abilities of human agents to create formerly unknown — because non-existent — modes of behaviour and institutional arrangements (Wegner 1997; Budzinski 2003b).

  17. For instance, the general necessity of an external monitoring of activities of downward level jurisdictions in an otherwise federal or decentralised regime is also emphasised by Figueiredo and Weingast (2005).

  18. My intention is not focused on names. Any other denomination of this agency would also be fine as long as it is equipped with the described competences.

  19. It remains within the competencies of the decentralised competition policy regimes to develop an institutional solution, which heals the discrimination problem.

  20. Claiming jurisdiction without a sufficient nexus to the respective arrangement can be interpreted as representing an indirect kind of discrimination. It is necessary to include the nexus issue in the supervision and sanction mechanism with respect to competition policy competences on national and subnational-regional levels.

  21. The self-assessment by the enterprises should not entail dangers of forum shopping because when assessing the cross-border effects, the respective enterprises are not choosing between different competition laws (since this decision is made by the ICP). Moreover, an ICP pre-notification of an anticompetitive arrangement or practice without considerable cross-border effects does not generate significant harm because the competence to substantially deal with the arrangement is allocated downwards anyhow. If only one downward level jurisdiction is really affected, the selection of a ‘lead’ jurisdiction is rather simple and indisputable.

  22. Such cases are likely to occur only infrequently. If an arrangement affects more than one decentralised competition policy regime, the participating agencies are required to notify to more than one agency — and, at the same time, they experience the incentive to make use of the one-stop shop via an ICP pre-notification.

  23. However, two decades ago the comprehensive independence of Central Banks in each EU member state would also have been deemed to be unrealistic.

  24. Next to inhabiting the regional gravity of the aggregate turnover of the participating enterprises, a qualification to become appointed lead jurisdiction requires the absence of discriminatory provisions and practices as well as the proven willingness and experience to employ a world welfare standard (see above). This implies that some of the above mentioned countries might face a long way to go until they meet these criteria. Note, however, that the possibility to qualify as lead jurisdiction can entail important incentives to develop national competition policy regimes according to the modern international standards.

  25. The same delimitation of competences could be applied if a vertical (and diagonal) interrelation between a supranational-regional and national regimes exists, like for instance in the EU (common EU competition policy and Member State competition policies).

  26. The Draft International Antitrust Code (DIAC) was presented by the so-called Munich Group in 1995 as a full-fledged proposal for a comprehensive international competition order in the context of the WTO. See for the original proposal Fikentscher and Immenga (1995) as well as for applications inter alia Drexl (1999, 2003) and Podszun (2003: 247–312).

  27. Maybe with the exception of Scherer (1994), whose proposal contains considerable enforcement competences of his International Competition Policy Office (ICPO) in the long run.

  28. Obviously, there is no guarantee that the hurdle does not remain at a prohibitive size and probably some will remain pessimistic about the realisability of the proposal. However, it is less ambitious than other proposals in this regard. Like in the past, significant steps forward in international governance probably need the right ‘window of opportunity’.

  29. Instead of truly highlighting the benefits, these proposals sometimes are rather motivated by the expectation that nothing more than cooperation can be realised.

  30. Case-by-case (bilateral) cooperation is unlikely to remedy these effects: “It seems over-optimistic to imagine that a world-wide framework for competition policy could be built up piecemeal from a network of bilateral agreements. (…) [I]t would be virtually impossible to ensure that all the agreements were compatible with each other” (Meiklejohn 1999: 1247).

  31. I owe the inspiration for the following discussion to two anonymous referees.

  32. If a leniency program is viewed to be an effective cartel detection tool, then the ICP is likely to experience incentives to use its rather limited scope of choice (see section 3.2) to assign a lead jurisdiction that possesses a leniency program because any other practice will effectively undermine the benefits of leniency programs (and deter further whistle blowers). If the rules for allocating competence only allow for non-leniency jurisdictions (for instance, because of the geographical gravity of the cartel in question), then a potential whistle blower is likely to anticipate this.

References

  • Baldwin RE (2001) Eastern Enlargement and ECB Reform. Swed Econ Policy Rev 8(1):15–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Barros PP, Cabral LM (1994) Merger Policy in Open Economies. Eur Econ Rev 38(5):1041–1055

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bode M, Budzinski O (2006) Competing Ways Towards International Antitrust: the WTO versus the ICN. In: Moriati P (ed) Antitrust Policy Issues. New York, Nova, pp 85–107

    Google Scholar 

  • Budzinski O (2003a) Towards an International Governance of Transborder Mergers? NYU J Int Law Pract 36(1):1–52

    Google Scholar 

  • Budzinski O (2003b) Cognitive Rules, Institutions, and Competition. Constit Polit Econ 14(3):215–235

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Budzinski O (2004) The International Competition Network: Prospects and Limits on the Road towards International Competition Governance. Compet Change 8(3):223–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Budzinski O (2008a) The Governance of Global Competition. Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Budzinski O (2008b) Monoculture versus Diversity in Competition Economics. Camb J Econ 32(2):295–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell N, Trebilcock MJ (1997) Interjurisdictional Conflict in Merger Review. In: Waverman L, Comanor WS, Goto A (eds) Competition Policy in the Global Economy. London, Routledge, pp 89–126

    Google Scholar 

  • Dabbah MM (2003) The Internationalisation of Antitrust Policy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Drexl J (1999) Trade-Related Restraints of Competition. In: Zäch R (ed) Towards WTO Competition Rules. Berne, Staempfli/Kluwer, pp 225–260

    Google Scholar 

  • Drexl J (2003) Do We Need “Courage” for International Antitrust Law? Choosing between Supranational and International Law Principles of Enforcement. In: Drexl J (ed) The Future of Transnational Antitrust: From Comparative to Common Competition Law. Berne, Staempfli/Kluwer, pp 311–341

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein RA, Greve MS (2004) In Defense of Small Steps. In: Epstein RA, Greve MS (eds) Competition Laws in Conflict: Antitrust Jurisdiction in the Global Economy. Washington, D.C., AEI Press, pp 333–352

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank (2004) Statute of the ESCB and of the ECB Rules of Procedure. Frankfurt a.M, ECB

    Google Scholar 

  • Figueiredo RJP, Weingast BR (2005) Self-Enforcing Federalism. J Law Econ Organ 21(1):103–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fikentscher W, Immenga U (1995) Draft International Antitrust Code. Baden-Baden, Nomos

    Google Scholar 

  • First H (2003) Evolving Toward What?—The Development of International Antitrust. In: Drexl J (ed) The Future of Transnational Antitrust: From Comparative to Common Competition Law. Berne, Staempfli/Kluwer, pp 23–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox EM (2000) Antitrust and Regulatory Federalism: Races Up, Down, and Sideways. N.Y. Univ Law Rev 75(6):1781–1807

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox EM (2003) International Antitrust and the Doha Dome. VA J Int Law 43(4):911–932

    Google Scholar 

  • Haucap J, Müller F, Wey C (2006) How to Reduce Conflicts over International Antitrust. Conferences on New Political Economy 23:307–343

    Google Scholar 

  • Hauser H, Schoene RE (1994) Is There a Need for International Competition Rules? Aussenwirtschaft 49(2–3):205–222

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1975) The Pretence of Knowledge. Swed J Econ 77(4):433–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Head K, Ries J (1997) International Mergers and Welfare Under Decentralized Competition Policy. Can J Econ 30(4):1104–1123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hefeker C (2002) Monetary Policy in a Union of 27: Enlargement and Reform Options. Intereconomics 37(6):315–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ICN (2002) Report on the Costs and Burdens of Multijurisdictional Merger Review. Napoli, http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/costburd.doc (downloaded in January 2004)

  • Jacquemin A (1995) Towards an Internationalisation of Competition Policy. World Econ 18(6):781–789

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jenny F (2003a) Competition Law and Policy: Global Governance Issues. World Compet 26(4):609–624

    Google Scholar 

  • Jenny F (2003b) International Cooperation on Competition: Myth, Reality and Perspective. Antitrust Bull 48(4):973–1003

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaiser B, Vosgerau HJ (2000) Global Harmonisation of National Competition Policies. In: Vosgerau HJ (ed) Institutional Arrangements for Global Economic Integration. Houndmills, Macmillan, pp 35–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Kerber W (1993) Rights, Innovations and Evolution: The Distributional Effects of Different Rights to Innovate. Rev Polit Econ 5(3):427–452

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kerber W (2003) International Multi-Level System of Competition Laws: Federalism in Antitrust. In: Drexl J (ed) The Future of Transnational Antitrust: From Comparative to Common Competition Law. Berne, Staempfli/Kluwer, pp 269–300

    Google Scholar 

  • Klodt H (2001) Conflict and Conflict Resolution in International Anti-trust: Do we Need International Competition Rules? World Econ 24(7):877–888

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klodt H (2005) Towards a Global Competition Order. Liberal, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Kovacic WE (1992) The Influence of Economics on Antitrust Law. Econ Inq 30(2):294–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kovacic WE (2004) Toward a Domestic Competition Network. In: Epstein RA, Greve MS (eds) Competition Laws in Conflict: Antitrust Jurisdiction in the Global Economy. Washington, D.C., AEI Press, pp 316–332

    Google Scholar 

  • Maher I (2002) Competition Law in the International Domain: Networks as a New Form of Governance. J Law Soc 29(1):111–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGinnis JO (2004) The Political Economy of International Antitrust Harmonization. In: Epstein RA, Greve MS (eds) Competition Laws in Conflict: Antitrust Jurisdiction in the Global Economy. AEI Press, Washington, D.C, pp 126–151

    Google Scholar 

  • Meiklejohn R (1999) An International Competition Policy: Do we Need it? Is it Feasible? World Econ 22(9):1233–1249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Connor KJ (2002) Federalist Lessons for International Antitrust Convergence. Antitrust Law J 70(2):413–441

    Google Scholar 

  • Podszun R (2003) Internationales Kartellverfahrensrecht. Bern, Staempfli

    Google Scholar 

  • Scherer FM (1994) Competition Policies for an Integrated World Economy. Washington, D.C., The Brookings Institution

    Google Scholar 

  • Smets H, Van Cayseele P (1995) Competing Merger Policies in a Common Agency Framework. Int Rev Law Econ 15(4):425–441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephan PB (2004) Against International Cooperation. In: Epstein RA, Greve MS (eds) Competition Laws in Conflict: Antitrust Jurisdiction in the Global Economy. Washington, D.C., AEI Press, pp 66–98

    Google Scholar 

  • Tarullo DK (2000) Norms and Institutions in Global Competition Policy. Am J Int L 94(3):478–504

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tay A, Willmann G (2005) Why (no) Global Competition Policy is a Tough Choice. Quart Rev Econ Finance 45(2–3):312–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trebilcock MJ, Iacobucci E (2004) National Treatment and Extraterritoriality: Defining the Domains of Trade and Antitrust Policy. In: Epstein RA, Greve MS (eds) Competition Laws in Conflict: Antitrust Jurisdiction in the Global Economy. Washington, D.C., AEI Press, pp 152–176

    Google Scholar 

  • Wegner G (1997) Economic Policy From an Evolutionary Perspective—A New Approach. J Inst Theor Econ 153(3):485–509

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson J (2003) Globalization and the Limits of National Merger Control Laws. Kluwer, The Hague

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This contribution is part of the refereed research project International Competition Policy—A Decentralised System of International Merger Control funded by the Volkswagen Foundation, priority area Global Structures and Governance. I thank two anonymous referees for valuable and very helpful comments

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Oliver Budzinski.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Budzinski, O. An international multilevel competition policy system. Int Econ Econ Policy 6, 367–389 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-009-0143-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-009-0143-2

Keywords

JEL

Navigation