Skip to main content

Regional currency arrangements in North America

Abstract

Choosing an exchange-rate regime is largely a matter of choosing the variables that will bear the brunt of adjustment to shocks and disturbances. Floating rates, supported by inflation-targeting regimes of varying degrees of transparency, have dominated currency arrangements in North America, especially after the peso crisis of 1994. Although the member countries have pursued their policy goals without formal coordination, their objectives have been very similar. Meanwhile, de facto integration of the three economies has continued, especially in the realm of cross-border production sharing. The result has been reduction of asymmetries and convergence of business cycles, as well as changes in balance of payments behavior and in the sensitivity of trade to the exchange rate. This paper explores the implications for monetary union.

This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Notes

  1. For a detailed assessment of the options available to Canada, see Arndt (2003). For reviews of the basic issues, see Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1994), Carr and Floyd (2000), De Grauwe (2005), Eichengreen (1997), Tavlas (1993) and Tower and Willett (1976).

  2. See, Mayes (2005), for example.

  3. See, among others, European Commission (Emerson et al. 1990), Eichengreen (1997) and Krugman (1993).

  4. See, for example, Berg and Borensztein (2000) and Hausmann et al. (1999).

  5. Tavlas (1993) provides a modern version of the traditional OCA argument.

  6. See Frankel (1999) for a general discussion.

  7. See Frankel and Rose (1998) for a possible scenario.

  8. In a recent study, Kunimoto and Sawchuk (2005) suggest that utilization of NAFTA hovers in the neighborhood of fifty percent, meaning that for a significant share of intra-NAFTA trade the costs associated with MFN tariffs are lower than compliance with NAFTA’s rules of origin.

  9. Whether such deepening is politically acceptable is a major question. A broad segment of Canadian public opinion is concerned about the loss of national identity in the face of U.S. cultural dominance. It is further widely believed that Canada would be very much the junior partner in any joint monetary enterprise. These perceptions are strengthened by political indifference in Washington. Though not identical, the situation is similar in Mexico. In both cases, however, these considerations militate more against formal monetary union with the United States than unilateral linkages to the U.S. dollar.

  10. Courchene and Harris (2000) have asserted, in addition, that the allocation of Canadian productive resources may have been distorted as the depreciation prevented resource reallocation out of “older” manufacturing into more modern, high-tech sectors. Such reallocations would have occurred under fixed rates, where world price moderation would have forced weak Canadian firms out of business. The evidence, however, does not support this assertion; and even if it did, it may merely suggest, as McCallum (2000) has noted, that Canada needed a stronger dollar and not that it needs monetary union with the United States.

  11. Grubel (2000) has also been a forceful critic of Canada’s recent exchange-rate regime, but for reasons that have more to do with hysteresis and the role of labor unions.

  12. See Amano and van Norden (1993), Murray (2000), and Murray et al. (2003), for example. Among the evidence brought to bear has been the well-known Bank of Canada exchange-rate equation with mainly relative price variables on the right-hand side. Murray and Powell (2003) also show that the degree of de facto dollarization is too small to offer justification for official dollarization.

  13. As we shall see below, in the presence of cross-border production, the protection provided by the buffer is limited to the content of Canadian value-added in the country’s trade.

  14. See, for example, Chiquiar and Ramos-Francia (2005) and Torres and Vela (2003).

  15. See Arndt and Huemer (2005) for evidence.

  16. See, for example, Knetter (1993), Goldberg and Knetter (1997), and Krugman (1987).

  17. See De Grauwe (2005) for discussion.

References

  • Amano R, van Norden S (1993) A forecasting equation for the Canada–U.S. Dollar exchange rate. In the exchange rate and the economy. Bank of Canada, Ottawa, pp 266–271

    Google Scholar 

  • Arndt SW (2001) Offshore sourcing and production-sharing in preference areas. In: Arndt SW, Kierzkowski H (eds) Fragmentation: new production patterns in the world economy. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 76–87

    Google Scholar 

  • Arndt SW (2003) The pros and cons of North American monetary integration. In: Harris RG (ed) North American linkages: opportunities and challenges for Canada. University of Calgary Press, Calgary, pp 391–418

    Google Scholar 

  • Arndt SW, Huemer A (2005) Trade, production networks and the exchange rate. Working paper. The Lowe Institute of Political Economy, Claremont McKenna College, Claremont

  • Bayoumi T, Eichengreen B (1994) One money or many? Analyzing the prospects for monetary unification in various parts of the world. Princeton Studies in International Finance 76 (1994)

  • Berg A, Borensztein E (2000) The choice of exchange rate regime and monetary target in highly dollarized economies. International Monetary Fund Working Paper No. 29, February

  • Carr JL, Floyd JF (2000) Real and monetary shocks to the Canadian dollar: do Canada and the United States form an optimum currency area? N Am J Econ Finance 13:1–19

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiquiar D, Ramos-Francia M (2005) Trade and business-cycle synchronization: evidence from Mexican and U.S. manufacturing industries. N Am J Econ Finance 16:187–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Courchene TJ, Harris RG (2000) North American monetary union: analytical principles and operational guidelines. N Am J Econ Finance 11:3–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe P (2005) The economics of monetary integration, 6th edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen B (1997) European monetary unification: theory, practice, and analysis. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Emerson M et al (1990) One market, one money: an evaluation of forming an economic and monetary union. Eur Econ 44

  • Frankel JA (1999) No single currency regime is right for all countries or at all times, Princeton Essays in International Finance, No. 215, August

  • Frankel JA, Rose AK (1998) The endogeneity of the optimum currency area criteria. Econ J 108(449):1009–1025

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldberg PK, Knetter MM (1997) Goods prices and exchange rates: what have we learned? J Econ Lit 35:1243–1272

    Google Scholar 

  • Grubel HG (2000) The merit of a Canada–U.S. Monetary union. N Am J Econ Finance 11(1):19–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann R, Gavin M, Pages-Serra C, Stein E (1999) Financial turmoil and the choice of exchange rate regime. IADB, mimeo

  • Kenen PB (1969) The theory of optimum currency areas: an eclectic view. In: Mundell RA, Swoboda AK (eds) Monetary problems of the International economy. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 41–60

    Google Scholar 

  • Knetter MM (1993) International comparisons of pricing-to-market behavior. Am Econ Rev 83:473–486

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1987) Pricing to markets when the exchange rate changes. In: Arndt SW, Richardson JD (eds) Real financial linkages in open economies. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp 49–70

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1993) Lessons of Massachusetts for EMU. In: Torres F, Giavazzi F (eds) Adjustment and growth in the European monetary union. Cambridge University Press, Oxford, pp 241–261

    Google Scholar 

  • Kunimoto R, Sawchuk G (2005) NAFTA rules of origin, mimeo

  • Mayes DG (2005) Financial stability in a world of cross-border banking, mimeo

  • McCallum J (2000) Engaging the debate: costs and benefits of a North American common currency. Current analysis. Royal Bank of Canada, Toronto, pp 1–9, April

    Google Scholar 

  • McKinnon RI (1963) Optimum currency areas. Am Econ Rev 53:717–725

    Google Scholar 

  • Mundell RA (1961) A theory of optimum currency areas. Am Econ Rev 51:657–665

    Google Scholar 

  • Murray J (2000) Why Canada needs a flexible exchange rate. N Am J Econ Finance 11(1):41–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murray J, Powell J (2003) Dollarization in Canada: where does the buck stop? N Am J Econ Finance 14(2):145–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murray J, Schembri L, St-Amant P (2003) Revisiting the case for flexible exchange rates in North America. N Am J Econ Finance 14(2):207–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tavlas GS (1993) The ‘New’ theory of optimum currency areas. World Econ 16(6):663–685

    Google Scholar 

  • Torres A, Vela O (2003) Trade Integration and synchronization between business cycles of Mexico and the United States. N Am J Econ Finance 14:319–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tower E, Willett TD (1976) The theory of optimum currency areas and exchange rate flexibility. Princeton Special Papers in International Economics 11

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sven W. Arndt.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Arndt, S.W. Regional currency arrangements in North America. IEEP 3, 265–280 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-006-0059-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-006-0059-z

Keywords

  • Floating rates
  • Monetary union
  • OCA
  • Production networks

JEL Classifications

  • F41
  • F15
  • F33