Review of World Economics

, Volume 153, Issue 1, pp 39–69 | Cite as

Out-migration and economic cycles

Original Paper

Abstract

Out-migration concerns foreigners who decide to leave a country where they used to live. Taking advantage of the OECD bilateral IMS database, we analyze the short-run determinants of out-migration using a panel of Schengen countries between 1995 and 2011. We find that out-migration is counter-cyclical: foreign nationals tend to leave host countries with high unemployment, while they are likelier to stay in good times (i.e. low unemployment). Typically, a 10 % increase in the unemployment rate leads to a 5 % increase in out-migration. Thus, short-term economic fluctuations have the same qualitative effect as restrictive migration policies in economic downturns. However, we find mixed evidence for the role of economic cycles in the potential destination countries of those flows. Movers appear to be sensitive to unemployment changes in their country of origin, but they do not seem to be sensitive to business cycles in potential destinations.

Keywords

Migration Outflows Business cycle 

JEL Classifications

F22 J61 015 

References

  1. Anderson, J. E. (2011). The gravity model. Annual Review of Economics, 3(1), 133–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Anderson, J. E., & van Wincoop, E. (2003). Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the border puzzle. American Economic Review, 93(1), 170–192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Aydemir, A., & Robinson, C. (2008). Global labour markets, return, and onward migration. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne D’économique, 41(4), 1285–1311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Beine, M., Docquier, F., & Ozden, C. (2011). Diasporas. Journal of Development Economics, 95(1), 30–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Beine, M., Bourgeon, P., & Bricongne, J. C. (2013). Aggregate fluctuations and international migration (CESifo working paper series 4379). CESifo Group Munich.Google Scholar
  6. Bellemare, C. (2007). A life-cycle model of outmigration and economic assimilation of immigrants in Germany. European Economic Review, 51(3), 553–576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Bertoli, S. (2010). Networks, sorting and self-selection of Ecuadorian migrants. Annals of Economics and Statistics, 68–69, 261–288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Bertoli, S., & Fernandez-Huertas Moraga, J. (2013). Multilateral resistance to migration. Journal of Development Economics, 102(C), 79–100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Bertoli, S., & Rapoport, H. (2015). Heaven’s swing door: Endogenous skills, migration networks, and the effectiveness of quality-selective immigration policies. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 117(2), 565–591.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Bertoli, S., Brucker, H., & Moraga, J. F. H. (2013). The European crisis and migration to Germany: Expectations and the diversion of migration flows (IZA discussion papers 7170). Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA).Google Scholar
  11. Bijwaard, G. E., & Wahba, J. (2014). Do high-income or low-income immigrants leave faster? Journal of Development Economics, 108, 54–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Bijwaard, G. E., Schluter, C., & Wahba, J. (2014). The impact of labor market dynamics on the return migration of immigrants. Review of Economics and Statistics, 96(3), 483–494.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Borjas, G. J. (1987). Self-selection and the earnings of immigrants. American Economic Review, 77(4), 531–553.Google Scholar
  14. Borjas, G. J., & Bratsberg, B. (1996). Who leaves? The outmigration of the foreign-born. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 78(1), 165–176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Card, D., Dustmann, C., & Preston, I. (2012). Immigration, wages, and compositional amenities. Journal of the European Economic Association, European Economic Association, 10(1), 78–119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Castles, S. (2006). Gusteworkers in Europe: A resurrection. International Migration Review, 40(4), 741–766.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Constant, A., & Massey, D. S. (2003). Self-selection, earnings, and out-migration: A longitudinal study of immigrants to Germany. Journal of Population Economics, 16(4), 631–653.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Coulombe, S. (2006). Internal migration, asymmetric shocks, and interprovincial economic adjustments in Canada. International Regional Science Review, 29(2), 199–223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. De Haas, H., Fokkema, T., & Fihri, M. F. (2015). Return migration as failure or success? Journal of International Migration and Integration, 16(2), 415–429.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Docquier, F., Ozden, Ç., & Peri, G. (2014). The labour market effects of immigration and emigration in OECD countries. Economic Journal, 124(579), 1106–1145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Dustmann, C., & Görlach, J. S. (2014). Selective outmigration and the estimation of immigrants’ earnings profiles. In B. R. Chiswick & P. W. Miller (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of migration. North-Holland: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  22. Dustmann, C., & Görlach, J. S. (2016). The economics of temporary migrations. Journal of Economic Literature, 54(1), 98–136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Dustmann, C., & Weiss, Y. (2007). Return migration: Theory and empirical evidence from the UK. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 45(2), 236–256.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Dustmann, C., Fadlon, I., & Weiss, Y. (2011). Return migration, human capital accumulation and the brain drain. Journal of Development Economics, 95(1), 58–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Gibson, J., & McKenzie, D. (2011). Eight questions about brain drain. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(3), 107–128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Grogger, J., & Hanson, G. H. (2011). Income maximization and the selection and sorting of international migrants. Journal of Development Economics, 95(1), 42–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Hatton, T. J. (2014). Public opinion on immigration: Has the recession changed minds? (IZA discussion papers 8248). Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA).Google Scholar
  28. Kırdar, M. G. (2009). Labor market outcomes, savings accumulation, and return migration. Labour Economics, 16(4), 418–428.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Mayr, K., & Peri, G. (2009). Brain drain and brain return: Theory and application to eastern–western Europe. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, 9(1), 1–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. McFadden, D. (1974). The measurement of urban travel demand. Journal of Public Economics, 3, 303–328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. McKenzie, D., & Rapoport, H. (2010). Self-selection patterns in Mexico–US migration: The role of migration networks. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 92(4), 811–821.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. McKenzie, D., Theoharides, C., & Yang, D. (2014). Distortions in the international migrant labor market: Evidence from filipino migration and wage responses to destination country economic shocks. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 6(2), 49–75.Google Scholar
  33. OECD. (2009). International migration and the economic crisis: Understanding the links and shaping policy responses, international migration outlook 2009, pp. 11–76, OECD.Google Scholar
  34. OECD. (2013). International migration outlook 2013 (Technical report). Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development, ParisGoogle Scholar
  35. Ortega, F., & Peri, G. (2013). The effect of income and immigration policies on international migration. Migration Studies, 1(1), 47–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Roy, A. D. (1951). Some thoughts on the distribution of earnings. Oxford Economic Papers, 3(2), 136–46.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Kiel Institute 2016

Authors and Affiliations

  • Rémi Bazillier
    • 1
  • Francesco Magris
    • 2
  • Daniel Mirza
    • 2
    • 3
  1. 1.Univ. Paris 1 and Univ. Orléans, LEO, CNRS UMR 7322OrléansFrance
  2. 2.Univ. François Rabelais de Tours, LEO, CNRS UMR 7322OrléansFrance
  3. 3.CEPIIParisFrance

Personalised recommendations