Abstract
The gap between theoretically predicted trade patterns and actual trade suggests that our understanding of what shapes trade patterns is incomplete. Institutional barriers may be one factor behind this gap, and recent research suggests that institutions are a greater obstacle to trade than tariffs. Using detailed firm-level data, we analyze how institutional quality in recipient countries affects exports by Swedish firms. Our results suggest that weak institutions in recipient countries make exports to these countries less likely and that exports to countries with weak institutions are characterized by relatively short duration and small volume. Analyzing long-term trade flows, we identified a learning process where exporters become less dependent on institutional quality in the target economy over time. More specifically, in addition to previous research that emphasize learning related to knowledge about the contracting partner and rule of law, we extend this notion and show that there is also a learning process where firms acquire knowledge about the general business climate. When learning about the contractual partner and business institutions in recipients countries takes place, exports increase relatively quickly during the first 2 years of exports and thereafter levels out. Hence, firms that are initially sensitive to weak institutions, start small, and learn how to handle foreign institutions are likely to be most successful in maintaining long-term relationships with foreign markets.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
The theoretical models used in these papers relate to the model of Araujo and Ornelas (2007) on trust, export dynamics and institutions.
There is no widely accepted definition of institutions, and different definitions have emerged. We support a commonly used definition formulated by North (1991), who states, “Institutions are the humanly devised constraints that structure political, economic and social interaction”.
For a more detailed discussion, see Williamson (2000).
Ornelas and Turner (2008) show that the hold-up problem is worsened when the contracting partner is located abroad.
In the case of differentiated goods, with one producer per product and single product firms, the extensive margin measured as new export firms or new products coincide. The majority of trade, however, occurs within the intensive margin of trade.
Bernard and Jensen (2004) is an example in which skill intensity has been used to explain selection with respect to internationalization. The idea is that highly productive and skill-intensive firms are more internationalized than other firms. Similarly, exporters have overcome the internationalization barrier and are therefore more likely to engage in international offshoring.
We also had eight different measures of political freedom and democracy; however, the contribution from these variables was marginal. In addition, it is difficult to determine the (decisive) role of politically related variables in the export decisions of firms. Therefore, these variables were dropped from the analysis. For an example of estimations, including the institutional variables capturing political freedom, see Table 6 in the appendix.
For an introduction to factor analysis, see Abdi (2003).
More information on CEPII’s distance measure is found in Mayer and Zignago (2006).
Repeating this estimation using the Heckman estimator yields similar results, see Table 11 in the appendix.
Following Bernard and Jensen (2004), the share of workers with tertiary education is used for the exclusion restrictions.
A Vuong test comparing the ZINB model to a negative binomial model shows support for the ZINB model. Moreover, likelihood-ratio tests comparing the ZINB model with the zero-inflated Poisson model strongly favor the ZINB model.
The phrase “money does not smell” was said by Roman Emperor Vespasian to his son Titus when he ordered a new tax on public bathrooms. This can be interpreted as meaning that if you see an opportunity, you should take it.
In addition, creating summary indices is one way to address multicollinearity among various measurements of institutional quality.
Our industry dummies absorb the direct effect of the industry- specific intensity in buyer–seller interaction.
The durations include new trade flows that end after 1 year, 2–3 years and 4–7 years. Long-lived, (right-hand) truncated flows are represented by export flows with a duration of at least 6–8 years and continuous exporters, that is, firms that export to a country throughout the period of observation.
To reduce clutter, control variables are not displayed in Table 4.
Because the selection of trade partners occurs at the beginning of each spell, we confine the analysis to the volume of exports.
Uncertainty about business institutions may also contribute to uncertainty and low initial volumes.
References
Abdi, H. (2003). Factor rotations in factor analyses. In M. Lewis-Beck, A. Bryman, T. Futing (Eds.), Encyclopedia of social sciences research methods (pp. 1–8). Thousand Oaks: Sage
Aeberhaedt, R., Buono, I., & Fadinger, H. (2011). Learning incomplete contracts and export dynamics: Theory and evidence from French firms (Vienna Economics Papers 1006). University of Vienna, Department of Economics.
Anderson, J. E., & Marcouiller, D. (2002). Insecurity and the pattern of trade: An empirical investigation. Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(2), 342–352.
Anderson, J. E., & Wincoop, E. (2003). Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the border puzzle. American Economic Review, 93(1), 170–192.
Antràs, P. (2003). Firms, contracts, and trade structure. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1375–1418.
Araujo, L., Mion, G., & Orneals, E. (2012). Institutions and export dynamics (CEPR Discussion Paper 8809). London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.
Araujo, L., & Ornelas, E. (2007). Trust-based trade (CEP Discussion Papers dp0820). Centre for Economic Performance, London School of Economics.
Awokuse, T. O., & Yin, H. (2010). Does stronger intellectual property rights protection induce more bilateral trade? Evidence from China’s imports. World Development, 38(8), 1094–1104.
Belloc, M. (2006). Institutions and international trade: A reconsideration of comparative advantage. Journal of Economic Surveys, 20(1), 3–26.
Bergstrand, J. H. (1989). The generalized gravity equation, monopolistic competition, and the factor-proportions theory in international trade. Review of Economics and Statistics, 71(1), 143–153.
Bergstrand, J. H. (1990). The Heckscher–Ohlin–Samuelson model, the Linder hypothesis and the determinants of bilateral intra-industry trade. Economic Journal, 100(403), 1216–1229.
Bernard, A., & Jensen, J. B. (2004). Why some firms export. Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(2), 561–569.
Breusch, T., Kompas, T., Nguyen, H. T. M., & Ward, M. B. (2011a). On the fixed-effects vector decomposition. Political Analysis, 19(2), 123–134.
Breusch, T., Kompas, T., Nguyen, H. T. M., & Ward, M. B. (2011b). FEVD: Just IV or just mistaken. Political Analysis, 19(2), 165–169.
Chang, H. J. (2010). Institutions and economic development: Theory, policy and history. Journal of Institutional Economics, 7(4), 473–498.
Depken, C. A., & Sonora, R. J. (2005). Asymmetric effects of economic freedom on international trade flows. International Journal of Business and Economics, 4(2), 141–155.
Eaton, J., Eslava, M., Krizan, C. J., Kugler, M., & Tybout, J. (2011). A search and learning model of export dynamics. Mimeo. Pennsylvania State University.
Feenstra, R. C. (2004). Advanced international trade: Theory and evidence. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Francois, J., Kepler, J., & Manchin, M. (2007). Institutions, infrastructure, and trade. (Policy Research Working Paper 4152). Washington, DC: World Bank
Greenaway, D., Gullstrand, J., & Kneller, R. (2008). Firm heterogeneity and the gravity of international trade (Discussion Papers No. 08/41). University of Nottingham, GEP.
Greene, W. (2001), Estimating econometric models with fixed effects, New York University, Leonard N. Stern School Finance Department (Working Paper Series 01–10). New York University, Leonard N. Stern School of Business.
Greene, W. (2011a). Fixed effects vector decomposition: A magical solution to the problem of time-invariant variables in fixed effects models? Political Analysis, 19(2), 135–146.
Greene, W. (2011b). Reply to rejoinder by Plümper and Troeger. Political Analysis, 19(2), 170–172.
Grossman, S. J., & Hart, O. D. (1986). The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration. Journal of Political Economy, 94(6), 691–719.
Hart, O., & Moore, J. (1990). Property rights and the nature of the firm. Journal of Political Economy, 98(6), 1119–1158.
Helpman, E., Melitz, M., & Rubinstein, Y. (2008). Estimating trade flows: Trading partners and trading volumes. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(2), 441–487.
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Zoido-Lobatón, P. (1999). Aggregating governance indicators. (Policy Research Working Paper Series 2195). Washington, DC: World Bank
Levchenko, A. (2007). Institutional quality and international trade. Review of Economic Studies, 74(3), 791–819.
Márquez-Ramos, L., Martínez-Zarzosa, I., & Suárez-Burguet, C. (2012). Trade policy versus institutional trade barriers: An application using “Good Old” OLS. Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal 6, 2012–11.
Massini, S., Pern-Ajchariyawong, N., & Lewin, A. Y. (2010). Role of corporate-wide offshoring strategy on offshoring drivers, risks and performance. Industry and Innovation, 17(4), 337–371.
Mayer, T., & Zignago, S. (2006). Notes on CEPII’s distance measures (MPRA Paper 26469).
McCallum, J. (1995). National borders matter: Canada-U.S. regional trade patterns. American Economic Review, 85(3), 615–623.
Méon, P., & Sekkat, K. (2006). Institutional quality and trade: Which institutions? Which trade? (DULBEA working paper 06-06). RS, Universite libre de Bruxelles.
North, D. C. (1991). Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 97–112.
Nunn, N. (2007). Relationship-specificity, incomplete contracts, and the pattern of trade. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(2), 569–600.
Ornelas, E., & Turner, J. L. (2008). Trade liberalization, outsourcing, and the hold-up problem. Journal of International Economics, 74(1), 225–241.
Plümper, T., & Troeger, V. E. (2007). Efficient estimation of time-invariant and rarely changing variables in a finite sample panel with unit fixed effects. Political Analysis, 15(2), 124–139.
Plümper, T., & Troeger, V. E. (2011). Reply to rejoinder by Plümper and Troeger. Political Analysis, 19(2), 170–172.
Ranjan, P., & Lee, J. Y. (2007). Contract enforcement and international trade. Economics and Politics, 19(2), 191–218.
Rauch, J. E. (1999). Networks versus markets in international trade. Journal of International Economics, 48(1), 7–35.
Rauch, J. E., & Watson, T. (2003). Starting small in an unfamiliar environment. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 21(7), 1021–1042.
Roberts, M. J., & Tybout, J. R. (1997). The decision to export in Colombia: An empirical model of entry with sunk costs. American Economic Review, 87(4), 545–564.
Santos Silva, J., & Tenreyro, S. (2006). The log of gravity. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4), 641–658.
Trefler, D. (1995). The case of the missing trade and other mysteries. American Economic Review, 85(5), 1029–1046.
Turrini, A., & Ypersele, T. (2010). Traders, courts, and the border effect puzzle. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 40(2–3), 81–91.
Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic new institutions of capitalism. JNY: Free Press.
Williamson, O. E. (1996). The mechanisms of governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Williamson, O. E. (2000). The new institutional economics: Taking stock, looking ahead. Journal of Economic Literature, 38(3), 595–613.
Acknowledgments
Financial support from Torsten Söderbergs Research Foundation and The Confederation of Swedish Enterprise is gratefully acknowledged.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
About this article
Cite this article
Söderlund, B., Tingvall, P.G. Dynamic effects of institutions on firm-level exports. Rev World Econ 150, 277–308 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-013-0181-2
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-013-0181-2