Skip to main content
Log in

Preferential trade agreements and the structure of international trade

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we examine the impact of membership in preferential trade agreements (PTAs) on trade between PTA members. Rather than considering the impact of PTA membership on the volume of trade we consider the impact of membership on the structure of trade. For a large sample of countries over the period 1962–2000 we find that membership in a PTA is associated with an increase in the extent of intra-industry trade. Our results indicate that this is especially the case for PTAs formed between richer countries, with the effects of PTAs between poorer countries found to be smaller.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In what follows we take preferential trade agreements (PTAs) to mean any preferential access for members of such an agreement.

  2. For example, the US has signed agreements with Israel (1985), Jordan (2002), Australia (2004), Morocco (2005) and Peru (2009), while the EU has signed agreements with Turkey (1996), the Faroe Islands (1997), the Palestinian Authority (1997), Tunisia (1999), South Africa (2000), Morocco (2000), Israel (2000), Mexico (2000), Chile (2004), Algeria (2006) and Cote d’Ivoire (2008).

  3. This number includes countries no longer in existence (e.g. Czechoslovakia, ex-Yugolslavia) along with the countries that replaced them (e.g. Czech Republic, Slovakia).

  4. Baier and Bergstrand (2009a) adopt both approaches.

  5. Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) note that theory indicates that trade between two countries is decreasing in their bilateral trade costs relative to the average of the costs of the two countries to trade with all their partners, rather than to absolute trade barriers. This they refer to as multilateral resistance.

  6. They also consider an adjustment to this index that accounts for trade imbalances.

  7. Grubel and Lloyd (1975) also showed that the level of IIT increased after the formation of the Organisation for European Economic Cooperation (OEEC) and the European Economic Community (EEC).

  8. In the former case one is able to examine the coefficients on the level of GDP and population for the exporter and importer separately, while in the latter one considers the product of countries i and j’s the GDPs and populations. Considering these variables separately for countries i and j in this case makes little sense as the ordering of the data will determine whether a particular country is classified as the exporter or importer.

  9. These are the Association of South-East Asian Nations (AFTA), Australia–New Zealand Trade Agreement (ANZCERTA), Asian Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC), Andean Pact (AP), Central American Common Market (CACM), Caribbean Community (CARICOM), European Economic Area (EEA), European Free Trade Agreement (EFTA), European Union (EU), Latin America Integration Agreement (LAIA), Southern Cone Common Market (MERCOSUR) and the North America Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA).

  10. http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/bdd/distances.htm.

  11. http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Landlocked.

  12. http://rtais.wto.org/UI/PublicAllRTAList.aspx.

  13. The reason for considering alternative sources is that the WTO data set only includes PTAs in force, thus excluding a number of PTAs that are no longer in force, but that would have been in the period of interest, examples being the PTAs agreed between the EU-15 and Romania, Bulgaria and others in the 1990s, but which are no longer in force now that these countries are members of the EU.

  14. A number of other approaches have been suggested including Tobit estimation and adding one to the value of trade, which then allows one to calculate the log of trade. More recently, Helpman et al. (2008) have proposed a two-stage estimation procedure. In the first stage a Probit model is estimated relating the probability of country j exporting to country i as a function of observables. Predicted components of this equation are then used in the second stage to estimate the gravity equation in log-linear form. Santos Silva and Tenreyro (2006) have proposed a Poisson Pseudo Maximum Likelihood estimation technique which is consistent in the presence of heteroscedasticity and also provides a natural way of dealing with zero observations.

  15. See Grubel and Lloyd (1971, 1975).

  16. The measures of IIT are calculated at the four-digit level. The paper thus uses more disaggregated data than is often used in the literature, which tends to use data at the one- or two-digit level.

  17. Given the fact that a large number of the observations on GLI and CGLI are zero (i.e. we have a corner solution problem, see Wooldridge, 2009) we also estimate our gravity equation using a Tobit model, as done in a gravity context by Felbermayr and Kohler (2006) for example. The results we obtain using the Tobit model are consistent with those reported, and are thus excluded from the paper for brevity. These results are available upon request however. It would also be possible to adopt the approaches of Helpman et al. (2008) and Santos Silva and Tenreyro (2006) mentioned in footnote 14 to consider the issue of zero values of the IIT index.

  18. This is calculated as (e βPTA − 1).

  19. Since the IIT variable varies between zero and one we can interpret the coefficients on the PTA variable as the change in the share of IIT in total trade.

  20. It would be interesting therefore to examine empirically whether the trade-creating effects of PTAs are stronger between close or more distant trade partners. As far as we know this hasn’t been attempted to date.

  21. To be consistent with the estimates for GLI and CGLI we report the estimated percentage increase in the level of trade following membership in one of the PTAs. This is calculated as in footnote 17.

  22. This result is consistent with Markusen (1986).

  23. The results are consistent with the arguments of Globerman (1992) however.

References

  • Abrams, R. K. (1980). International trade flows under flexible exchange rates. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, 65(3), 3–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aitken, N. D. (1973). The effect of the EEC and EFTA on European trade: A temporal cross-section analysis. American Economic Review, 58(5), 881–892.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, J. E., & van Wincoop, E. (2003). Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the border puzzle. American Economic Review, 93(1), 170–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baier, S. L., & Bergstrand, J. H. (2002). On the endogeneity of international trade flows and free trade agreements. Mimeo.

  • Baier, S. L., & Bergstrand, J. H. (2004). Economic determinants of free trade agreements. Journal of International Economics, 64(1), 29–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baier, S. L., & Bergstrand, J. H. (2009a). Bonus Vetus OLS: A simple method for approximating international trade-cost effects using the gravity equation. Journal of International Economics, 77(1), 77–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baier, S. L., & Bergstrand, J. H. (2009b). Estimating the effects of free trade agreements on trade flows using matching econometrics. Journal of International Economics, 77(1), 63–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baier, S. L., Bergstrand, J. H., Egger, P., & McLaughlin, P. A. (2008). Do economic integration agreements actually work? Issues in understanding the causes and consequences of the growth of regionalism. World Economy, 31(4), 461–497.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R., & Taglioni, D. (2006). Gravity for dummies and dummies for gravity equations (NBER Working Paper no 12516). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Bayoumi, T., & Eichengreen, B. (1997). The generalized gravity equation, monopolistic competition and the factor proportions theory in international trade. Review of Economics and Statistics, 67(3), 474–481.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrand, J. H. (1985). The gravity equation in international trade: Some microeconomic foundations and empirical evidence. Review of Economics and Statistics, 71(1), 143–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrand, J. H. (1990). The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson model, the Linder hypothesis, and the determinants of bilateral intra-industry trade. Economic Journal, 100, 1216–1229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrand, J. H., & Egger, P. (2006). Trade costs and intra-industry trade. Review of World Economics/Weltwirtschaftsliches Archiv, 142(3), 433–458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brada, J. C., & Mendez, J. A. (1983). Economic integration among developed, developing and centrally planned economies: A comparative analysis. Review of Economics and Statistics, 67(4), 549–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caetano, J., & Galego, A. (2007). In search for the determinants of intra-industry trade within an enlarged Europe. South-Eastern Europe Journal of Economics, 5(2), 163–183.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheng, I.-H., & Wall, H. J. (2002). Controlling for heterogeneity in gravity models of trade (Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper no. 1999-010C).

  • Egger, P. (2000). A note on the proper econometric specification of the gravity equation. Economics Letters, 66(1), 25–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger, H., Egger, P., & Greenaway, D. (2008). The trade structure effects of endogenous regional trade agreements. Journal of International Economics, 74(2), 278–298.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eicher, T., Henn, C., & Papageorgiou, C. (2004). Trade creation and diversion revisited: Accounting for model uncertainty and natural trading partner effects. Mimeo.

  • Ekanayake, E. M. (2001). Determinants of intra-industry trade: The case of Mexico. International Trade Journal, 15(1), 89–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R. C., Lipsey, R. E., Deng, H., Ma, A. C., & Mo, H. (2005). World trade flows: 19622000 (NBER Working Paper no. 11040). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Felbermayr, G. J., & Kohler, W. (2006). Exploring the intensive and extensive margins of world trade. Review of World Economics/Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 142(4), 642–674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J. (1997). Regional trading blocs in the world economic system. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J., Stein, E., & Wei, S.-J. (1995). Trading blocs and the Americas: The natural, the unnatural, and the super-natural. Journal of Development Economics, 47(1), 61–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J., Stein, E., & Wei, S.-J. (1996). Regional trading arrangements: Natural or supernatural? American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 86(2), 52–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Globerman, S. (1992). North American trade liberalisation and intra-industry trade. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv/Review of World Economics, 128(3), 487–497.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grubel, H. G., & Lloyd, P. J. (1971). The empirical measurement of intra-industry trade. Economic Record, 47, 494–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grubel, H. G., & Lloyd, P. J. (1975). Intra-industry trade: The theory and measurement of international trade in differentiated products. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E. (1981). International trade in the presence of product differentiation, economies of scale and monopolistic competition: A Chamberlin-Heckscher-Ohlin approach. Journal of International Economics, 11(3), 305–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E., & Krugman, P. (1985). Market structure and foreign trade. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E., Melitz, M., & Rubinstein, Y. (2008). Trading partners and trading volumes. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(2), 441–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, C.-S., & Lee, K.-E. (2003). Regional trade arrangements and intra-industry trade: The case of Mercosur. Asian Journal of Latin American Studies, 16(1), 95–113.

    Google Scholar 

  • Linder, S. B. (1961). An essay on trade and transformation. Stockholm: Almqvist and Wicksell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magee, C. (2003). Endogenous preferential trade agreements: An empirical analysis. Contributions to Economic Analysis and Policy, 2(1), Berkeley Electronic Press.

  • Markusen, J. R. (1986). Explaining the volume of trade: An eclectic approach. American Economic Review, 76(5), 1002–1011.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martincus, C. V., & Estevadeordal, V. (2009). Trade policy and specialisation in developing countries. Review of World Economics/Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 145(2), 251–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matyas, L. (1997). Proper econometric specification of the gravity equation. World Economy, 20(3), 363–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Medvedev, D. (2010). Preferential trade agreements and their role in world trade. Review of World Economics/Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 146(2), 199–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodas-Martini, P. (1998). Intra-industry trade and revealed comparative advantage in the Central American Common Market. World Development, 26(2), 337–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Santos Silva, J., & Tenreyro, S. (2006). The Log of Gravity. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4), 641–658.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen, J. (1962). Shaping the world economy. New York: Twentieth Century Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Urata, S., & Okabe, M. (2009). The impacts of free trade agreements on trade flows: An application of the gravity model approach. In C. C. Findlay & S. Urata (Eds.), Free trade agreements in the Asia Pacific. Singapore: World Scientific.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viner, J. (1950). The customs union issue. New York: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2009). Introductory econometrics: A modern approach. Manson, Ohio: South-Western.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2000). World development report 2000. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2008). World development indicators 2008. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The present paper was prepared as part of the EU FP7 programme project ‘World Input–Output Database: Construction and Applications’ (WIOD). This project is funded by the European Commission, Research Directorate General as part of the Seventh Framework Programme, Theme 8: Socio-Economic Sciences and Humanities. Grant Agreement no. 225 281. The authors would like to thank two anonymous referees and the editor for valuable comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Neil Foster.

About this article

Cite this article

Foster, N., Stehrer, R. Preferential trade agreements and the structure of international trade. Rev World Econ 147, 385–409 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-011-0093-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-011-0093-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation