Skip to main content
Log in

Budgetary choices and institutional rules: veto rules and budget volatility

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Economics of Governance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Studies of the line item veto have traditionally focused on whether it leads to less spending than an all-or-nothing veto and have only produced modest results. However, other impacts that differences in rule choice might effectuate have not been investigated in detail. We examine the role of veto rules for budgetary volatility, the extent to which expenditures vary. Theoretically, we model budget choices given all-or-nothing, line item, and item-reduction vetoes and demonstrate that more encompassing veto authority does not necessarily decrease spending but should result in more political gridlock, implying less volatility. We then analyze the model’s prediction by examining American state budget expenditures from 1978 to 2007. Whether one looks at budget categories or total spending, volatility is greater with the all-or-nothing veto relative to more stringent alternatives. Hence, delegating greater authority to executives such as governors, perhaps unexpectedly, likely strengthens expectations about future budgets while reducing the responsiveness of spending to changing preferences or circumstances.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, in November 2011 the U.S. House budget leaders rolled out their own line item veto plan, which the lower chamber actually approved in February of the next year. However, the lack of Senate Democratic support doomed the proposal, which was never brought to a vote.

  2. The same logic would appear to apply to the U.S. Congress’ 1996 item veto, which required a legislative supermajority to override deleted items and was deemed unconstitutional (on this veto authority, see Berry 2016).

  3. Obviously, much of this empirical work has theoretical underpinnings as well. For example, Kousser and Phillips (2012) are concerned with whether an item veto either provides the governor with negative power, preventing unwanted spending, or is a source of positive power, advancing the chief executive’s initiatives, but find evidence for neither. Along similar lines, while Krause and Melusky (2012) posit and find evidence that executives with unfettered spending authority spend more due to short-term electoral interests, they provide no evidence that veto authority matters.

  4. With respect to the states, most work on the impact of volatility focuses on public performance. For example, Crain (2003) emphasizes how volatility causes public inefficiencies while, more recently, Flink (2018) suggests that public agencies are able to at least compensate somewhat for volatility. While the link between volatility and private investment in the states is not a well-plowed area, there is evidence that uncertainties associated with features such as government budgets are generally problematic (e.g., Azzimonti 2018).

  5. Theoretically, the reversion budget may be any prespecified level (including zero), although it is typically conceptualized as the previous year’s budgetary figure (e.g., Kiewiet and McCubbins 1991). While some theoretical work has specified a zero reversion point (Kiewiet and Krehbiel 2002), this assumption is not empirically justified. Typically, in light of failure to agree on a new budget, a continuing resolution is used with previous funding levels as the focal point or, even in the rare instance of a shutdown, essential services are continued which, for states, are typically a large portion of the budget (e.g., in 2011 it was estimated that approximately 80% of spending continued during Minnesota’s erstwhile shutdown).

  6. We follow Carter and Schap (1990) in modeling the legislature as a unitary actor. Given the majoritarian decision-making process, it can be understood as the chamber median, or the median of the budget committee. Alternatively, it could be the opposition party leader if assuming strong party influence, or the chair of the budget committee if considering the legislative norm of deference (Maltzman 1998). Even if we model the legislature with more players, the main result of our model on the relationship between budgetary volatility and veto authority does not change.

  7. See Crombez et al. (2006) for a graphical presentation of policy outcomes under the all-or-nothing veto in a two-dimensional bargaining situation.

  8. Schap (1988) presents examples demonstrating that a policy outcome under an item veto or an item-reduction veto need not be in the Pareto-efficient set.

  9. For this to be a meaningful result there should be some random factor associated with the status quo. For example, we can think of the status quo as being the prior year’s budget with a random component produced by factors such as macroeconomic shocks or political scandals, etc.

    Alternatively, we can assume that a failure to agree produces a zero reversion budget, i.e., s = 0, and, concomitantly, a true government shutdown. In this instance, pinpointing which veto rule causes higher budget volatility is difficult, as the answer depends upon the distribution of the potential ideal points of players—the relative distances of zero and the proposer’s ideal point from the confirmer’s ideal point matter. However, as discussed, a zero reversion point is not plausible.

  10. We should note, however, that such aggregate spending restrictions do not impact our predictions regarding the impact of the gridlock set’s relative size. However, on the grounds that such restrictions might influence the adoption of the item veto, in our empirical analysis we include a control for whether states have adopted them.

  11. Until 1996, the governor of North Carolina had no approval or veto authority (note that no veto authority also will produce greater volatility, and this is reflected in our coding this state as not having item veto authority).

  12. The results are unchanged using nominal dollars. We employ real dollars because it is more natural to define players’ preferences on dimensions expressed in real dollars.

  13. An alternative specification would be to examine the budget’s unconditional variance. That is, one would regress (growth)2 on Z, and examine whether item veto significantly decreases the unconditional variance. If we use this alternative specification, we get essentially the same result for budgetary category spending but not for total spending: item veto significantly reduces volatility of budgetary category spending, but it does not have a significant effect on volatility of the total spending. As noted above, these results are not inconsistent with our theory. We present the results with this alternative model in the “Appendix”.

  14. Fatas and Mihov (2006) also exploited the variances of the residuals to measure the volatility of fiscal policy. However, while they utilized a two-step procedure, our method is more efficient because we estimate all parameters simultaneously via Maximum Likelihood.

  15. While our panel is not balanced, for notational simplicity we denote the number of periods by T for all units as if the dataset were balanced.

  16. TEL data come from Budget Processes in the States 2008, which is produced by the National Association of State Budget Officers. As of 2007, there are 28 states having some form of limits, usually tied to growth in personal income and population. Among the seven states with no item veto, Nevada accepted TEL in 1979, while Indiana and Rhode Island accepted them in 2006 and 2007, respectively. As for the rest, 18 states have never accepted them. Two sample t test shows that states with the item veto are more likely to have TEL (p value = 0.000).

  17. Since spending data are for state fiscal years (e.g., 2005 spending is for the fiscal year starting in 2004 and ending in 2005), we use lagged versions of the four political variables in our regression analysis. For example, for education spending in state s in year t, we use governor party switch—Democrat in year t − 1.

  18. In light of the possibility that preferences of past players were not captured by the previous budget, we also tried alternative political variables of change, such as upper house to D (whether the party that has majorities in the upper house changed to Democrat), lower house to D (measured analogously), and changes in the % of seats occupied by the opposition party, but these variables did not have significant effects.

  19. While we model growth in spending to analyze its variance, there are studies on spending level that find no differences between Republican and Democratic governors (e.g., Leigh 2008; Beland and Oloomi 2017). However, if Democratic governors pursue more radical changes relative to Republican governors when regaining power from the other party, findings from these studies are not necessarily inconsistent with our result.

References

  • Andersen SC, Mortensen PN (2010) Policy stability and organizational performance: is there a relationship? J Public Adm Res Theor 20(1):1–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azzimonti M (2018) Partisan conflict and private investment. J Monet Econ 93:114–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beland L-P, Oloomi S (2017) Party affiliation and public spending: evidence from U.S. Governors. Econ Inq 55(2):982–995

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry MJ (2016) The modern legislative veto: macropolitical conflict and the Legacy of Chadha. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Case A (2003) Political institutions and policy choices: evidence from the United States. J Econ Lit 41(1):7–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binder SA (2003) Stalemate: causes and consequences of Legislative Gridlock. Brookings Institution, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Bohn H, Inman RP (1996) Balanced budget rules and public deficits: evidence from the U.S. States. NBER Working Papers 5533, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Brown AR (2012) The Item Veto’s Sting. State Politics and Policy Quarterly 12(2):183–203

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carter JR, Schap D (1987) Executive veto, legislative override, and structure-induced equilibrium. Public Choice 52(2):227–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carter JR, Schap D (1990) Line-item veto: Where is thy sting? J Econ Perspect 4(2):103–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crain WM (2003) Volatile states: institutions, policy, and the performance of American state economies. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Crombez C, Groseclose T, Krehbiel K (2006) Gatekeeping. J Polit 68(2):322–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Figueiredo RJP Jr. (2003) Budget institutions and political insulation: why states adopt the item veto. J Public Econ 87(12):2677–2701

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dye TR (1984) Party and policy in the states. J Polit 46(4):1097–1116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fatas A, Mihov I (2006) The macroeconomic effects of fiscal rules in the US states. J Public Econ 90(1–2):101–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flink CM (2018) Ordering chaos: the performing consequences of budgetary changes. Am Rev Public Adm 48(4):291–300

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabel MJ, Hager GL (2000) How to succeed at increasing spending without really trying: the balanced budget amendment and the item veto. Public Choice 102(1–2):19–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gosling JJ (1986) Wisconsin item-veto lessons. Public Adm Rev 46(4):292–300

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hadi AS (1992) Identifying multiple outliers in multivariate data. J R Stat Soc Ser B (Methodol) 54(3):393–396

    Google Scholar 

  • Hadi AS (1994) A modification of a method for the detection of outliers in multivariate samples. J R Stat Soc Ser B (Methodol) 56(2):761–771

    Google Scholar 

  • Harvey AC (1976) Estimating regression models with multiplicative heteroscedasticity. Econometrica 44(3):461–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendrick RM, Garand JC (1991) Expenditure tradeoffs in the US States: a pooled analysis. J Public Adm Res Theor 1(3):295–318

    Google Scholar 

  • Holtz-Eakin D (1988) The line item veto and public sector budgets: evidence from the states. J Public Econ 36(3):269–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Indridason IH (2011) Executive veto power and credit claiming: comparing the effects of the line-item veto and the package veto. Public Choice 3–4:375–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiewiet D Roderick, Krehbiel K (2002) Here’s the president, where’s the party? U.S. appropriations on discretionary domestic spending, 1950–1999. Leviathan 30:115–137

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiewiet D Roderick, McCubbins MD (1991) The logic of delegation: congressional parties and the appropriations process. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Kousser T, Phillips JH (2012) The power of american governors. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Krause GA, Melusky BF (2012) Concentrated powers: unilateral executive authority and fiscal policymaking in the American states. J Polit 74(1):98–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krol R (2007) The role of fiscal and political institutions in limiting the size of state government. Cato J 27(3):431–445

    Google Scholar 

  • Leigh A (2008) Estimating the impact of gubernatorial partisanship on policy settings and economic outcomes: a regression discontinuity approach. Eur J Polit Econ 24(1):256–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maltzman F (1998) Maintaining congressional committees: sources of member support. Legis Stud Q 23(2):197–218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller SM (2013) Administering representation: the role of elected administrators in translating citizens’ preferences into public policy. J Public Adm Res Theor 23(4):865–897

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Primo D (2006) Stop us before we spend again: institutional constraints on government spending. Econ Polit 18(3):269–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer T, Rosenthal H (1978) Political resource allocation, controlled agendas, and the status Quo. Public Choice 33(4):27–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose S (2010) Institutions and fiscal sustainability. Natl Tax J 63(4):807–838

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal H (1990) The setter model. In: Enelow JM, Hinich MJ (eds) Advances in the spatial theory of voting. Cambridge University Press, New York, pp 199–234

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Schap D (1988) In search of efficacious executive veto authority. Public Choice 58(3):247–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stucky TD, Heimer K, Lang JB (2007) A bigger piece of the pie? State corrections spending and the politics of social order. J Res Crime Delinq 44(1):91–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lawrence S. Rothenberg.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Tables 6 and 7 present the results from the alternative specification discussed in footnote 13. The effect of item veto significantly reduces (unconditional) volatility of budgetary category spending, but it does not significantly affect the volatility of the total spending. Also, significant variables have the same sign as before.

Table 6 The effect of item veto on the unconditional volatility of budgetary category spending
Table 7 The effect of item veto on the unconditional volatility of total spending

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Jo, J., Rothenberg, L.S. Budgetary choices and institutional rules: veto rules and budget volatility. Econ Gov 21, 1–25 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-020-00234-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-020-00234-7

Keywords

Navigation