Skip to main content
Log in

Taxes versus emissions trading system: evaluating environmental policies that affect multiple types of pollution

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Environmental Economics and Policy Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the interaction of different policies used to control two types of agricultural pollution. Pollution control policy is efficient when both pollution types are controlled by taxes, although a tax increase on one type of pollution can increase the quantity of another type of pollution if farm inputs are substitutes. However, if one of the pollutions is controlled by a local emissions trading scheme, and another pollution type is taxed, then the pollution type which is taxed becomes less responsive to a change in its own tax levels. This policy scenario results in inefficient levels of environmental pollution outcomes unless the cap for the local emissions trading scheme is constantly being shifted in response to the tax.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This assumes that consumers are unaffected by the farmer’s choice of output, because they would source farm products from international markets if they were not available locally.

  2. The assumption of a linear relationship between inputs and pollution levels is made to simplify the mathematics, but is not fundamental to the story. If \(\Phi ^0_j = 0\) pollution doubles when an input doubles, but the damage done by nutrient pollution can increase at a much faster rate due to the convexity of the damage function. Thus, the model allows for arbitrary non-linear relationships between the damage done by nutrient pollution and the amount of an input, which is the key concern when finding an optimal policy. If \(\Phi ^0_j \ne 0\) the pollution emission function can to some extent capture the threshold effects that occur in practice when inputs are increased, as the marginal effect can be much larger than the average effect. In practice, threshold-style non-linear effects may be important for nutrient pollution. Land has a natural capacity to absorb and process a certain amount of nutrient waste, and once this threshold is exceeded additional nutrient waste flows much more rapidly into waterways. This point is discussed further in Sect. 4.

  3. A similar example could focus on the emissions from different breeds of cows, or different sized cows. The amount of methane generated by enteric fermentation can vary significantly across cow breeds and feed-types (Grobler et al. 2014).

  4. Since \(P_\mathrm{N}\) is zero, \(\frac{\mathrm{d N}^+}{\mathrm{d} P_\mathrm{G}}=\sum _{j\in \mathbf {J}}\sum _{i\in \mathbf {I}^j}\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\), which is negative as \(\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}<0\) for all farmers.

  5. Experimental NTS schemes may also be more popular than experimental tax schemes as the permits can easily be given away so the net cost to the farming community is zero.

  6. The coefficients of the quadratic are sufficiently complex that it is not possible to find a simple analytical expression for the conditions when a switch from one land use to another increases N leaching when \(P_\mathrm{G}\) increases. An analytical expression is available in the case that there is a single input: see Yeo et al. (2013).

  7. This assumption is not strictly necessary. In general, if \(x_i\) is different for different farmers, then the switching price \(P_{Gi}^{*}\) will be different for different farmers. If some farmers have identical \(x_i\), then several farmers will switch from one activity to another simultaneously, and the consequent change in output and/or prices will reflect the simultaneous but discrete change by all affected farmers.

References

  • Baumol WJ (1988) The theory of environmental policy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Beavis B, Walker M (1979) Interactive pollutants and joint abatement costs: achieving water quality standards with effluent charges. J Environ Econ Manag 6(4):275–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boadi D, Wittenberg K, Scott S, Burton D, Buckley K, Small J, Ominski K (2004) Effect of low and high forage diet on enteric and manure pack greenhouse gas emissions from a feedlot. Can J Anim Sci 84(3):445–453

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caplan AJ, Silva EC (2005) An efficient mechanism to control correlated externalities: redistributive transfers and the coexistence of regional and global pollution permit markets. J Environ Econ Manag 49(1):68–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Compton JE, Harrison JA, Dennis RL, Greaver TL, Hill BH, Jordan SJ, Walker H, Campbell HV (2011) Ecosystem services altered by human changes in the nitrogen cycle: a new perspective for US decision making. Ecol Lett 14(8):804–815

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doole GJ, Pannell DJ (2012) Empirical evaluation of nonpoint pollution policies under agent heterogeneity: regulating intensive dairy production in the Waikato region of New Zealand. Aust J Agric Resour Econ 56(1):82–101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gasper RR, Selman M, Ruth M (2012) Climate co-benefits of water quality trading in the chesapeake bay watershed. Water Policy 14(5):758–765

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goulder LH (2013) Markets for pollution allowances: what are the (new) lessons? J Econ Perspect 27(1):87–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grobler S, Scholtz M, Van Rooyen H, Mpayipheli M, Neser F (2014) Methane production in different breeds, grazing different pastures or fed a total mixed ration, as measured by a laser methane detector. S Afr J Anim Sci 44(5):12–16

    Google Scholar 

  • Hartmann M, Huber R, Peter S, Lehmann B (2009) Strategies to mitigate greenhouse gas and nitrogen emissions in Swiss agriculture: the application of an integrated sector model. IED Working Paper

  • Jackson RB, Jobbágy EG, Avissar R, Roy SB, Barrett DJ, Cook CW, Farley KA, Le Maitre DC, McCarl BA, Murray BC (2005) Trading water for carbon with biological carbon sequestration. Science 310(5756):1944–1947

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Key ND, Kaplan JD (2007) Multiple environmental externalities and manure management policy. J Agric Resour Econ 32(1):115–134

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehmann P (2012) Justifying a policy mix for pollution control: a review of economic literature. J Econ Surv 26(1):71–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moslener U, Requate T (2007) Optimal abatement in dynamic multi-pollutant problems when pollutants can be complements or substitutes. J Econ Dyn Control 31(7):2293–2316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muhammed SE, Coleman K, Wu L, Bell VA, Davies JA, Quinton JN, Carnell EJ, Tomlinson SJ, Dore AJ, Dragosits U et al (2018) Impact of two centuries of intensive agriculture on soil carbon, nitrogen and phosphorus cycling in the UK. Sci Total Environ 634:1486–1504

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pattanayak SK, McCarl BA, Sommer AJ, Murray BC, Bondelid T, Gillig D, DeAngelo B (2005) Water quality co-effects of greenhouse gas mitigation in us agriculture. Clim Change 71(3):341–372

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell J, Gourley C, Rotz C, Weaver DM (2010) Nitrogen use efficiency: a potential performance indicator and policy tool for dairy farms. Environ Sci Policy 13(3):217–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rotz C, Montes F, Chianese D (2010) The carbon footprint of dairy production systems through partial life cycle assessment. J Dairy Sci 93(3):1266–1282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon CP, Blume L (1994) Mathematics for economists, vol 7. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Stackhouse-Lawson K, Rotz C, Oltjen J, Mitloehner F (2012) Carbon footprint and ammonia emissions of california beef production systems. J Anim Sci 90(12):4641–4655

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stewart A, Little S, Ominski K, Wittenberg K, Janzen H (2009) Evaluating greenhouse gas mitigation practices in livestock systems: an illustration of a whole-farm approach. J Agric Sci 147(4):367–382

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Ungern-Sternberg T (1987) Environmental protection with several pollutants: on the division of labor between natural scientists and economists. J Inst Theor Econ (JITE)/Z für Gesamte Staatswiss 143(4):555–567

    Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman ML (1974) Prices vs. quantities. Rev Econ Stud 41:477–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilcock R, Elliott S, Hudson N, Parkyn S, Quinn J et al (2008) Climate change mitigation for agriculture: water quality benefits and costs. Water Sci Technol 58(11):2093–9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woodward RT (2011) Double-dipping in environmental markets. J Environ Econ Manag 61(2):153–169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yeo B-L, Coleman A, Springborn M (2013) Hot air and muddy water: interactions between market-based policy instruments that address climate change and water quality externalities from agroecosystems. University of California, Davis Working Paper

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful for the funding received from the Royal Society of New Zealand and the National Science Foundation (NSF) under Grant No. 1210213. This research is made possible through the support provided by Motu Economics and Public Policy in Wellington, New Zealand and the University of California, Davis Outreach and International Programs Seed Grant. We would also like to thank Debbie Niemeier for her support and would especially thank Suzi Kerr and Michael Springborn for their valuable guidance, suggestions, and comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Boon-Ling Yeo.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Additional results from Sect. 3.1.1

The solution to Eq. 14 presented below is for the case that the farmer ceases using input 2 before input 1 as \(P_\mathrm{G}\) increases. The solution is

$$\begin{aligned} \underline{\theta }^*_{i,j}= \left\{ \begin{array}{lr} \bar{\theta }_{i,j}+\frac{1}{2P_jx_i}A^{-1}_j(P_{\theta }+P^{'}_{E} \Phi ^1_j), &{} 0 \le P_\mathrm{G}< P_1\\ \left( \theta ^{1+}_{ij},0 \right) ',&{} P_1 \le P_\mathrm{G}< P_2\\ \left( 0,0 \right) ',&{} P_2 \le P_\mathrm{G}.\\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(24)

where

$$\begin{aligned} {\theta ^{1+}_{i,j}}= & {} \bar{\theta }^{1}_{ij}+\frac{P^1_{\theta }+ P_\mathrm{N}\phi ^{\rm N1}_{j}+P_{\rm G}\phi ^{\rm G1}_{j}+\alpha ^{12}_j \bar{\theta }^2_{i,j} x_i P_j}{2x_i\alpha ^{11}_{j}P_j},\\ P_1= & {} \frac{\alpha _j^{12}(P_{\theta }^1+P_\mathrm{N}\phi ^{\rm N1}_{j})-2\alpha ^{11}_{j}(P_{\theta }^2+P_\mathrm{N}\phi ^{\rm N2}_{j})-\bar{\theta }^1_{ij}(P_jx_i (4\alpha ^{11}_{j}\alpha ^{22}_{j}-(\alpha ^{12}_{j})^2))}{2\alpha ^{11}_{j}\phi ^{G2}_{j}-\alpha _j^{12}\phi ^{G1}_{j}}, \\ P_2= & {} -\frac{1}{\phi ^{\rm G1}_{j}}(P_j x_i(\alpha _j^{12}\bar{\theta }^2_{ij}+2\alpha ^{11}_{j}\bar{\theta }^1_{ij})+P^1_{\theta }+P_\mathrm{N}\phi ^{N1}_{j}). \end{aligned}$$

Since optimal emissions are \(E^{*}_{ij} = \Phi ^{0}_j + \Phi ^{1}_{ij} \underline{\theta }^*_{i,j}\), the relationship between optimal emissions and pollution prices is also piecewise linear and the derivative matrix \(\frac{\partial E^{*}_{ij}}{\partial P_\mathrm{E}}\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ \begin{array}{cc}\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}} &{} \frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}} \\ \frac{\partial {\rm N}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}} &{} \frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\end{array}\right] = \left\{ \begin{array}{lr} \frac{1}{2P_jx_i} {\Phi ^1_j}^{'} A^{-1}_j \Phi ^1_j, &{} 0< P_\mathrm{G}< P_1\\ \left[ \begin{array}{cc}\frac{(\phi ^{N1}_{j})^2}{2x_i\alpha ^{11}_{j}P_j} &{} \frac{\phi ^{N1}_j\phi ^{{\rm G}1}_{j}}{2x_i\alpha ^{11}_{j}P_j} \\ \frac{\phi ^{{\rm N}1}_j\phi ^{{\rm G}1}_{j}}{2x_i\alpha ^{11}_{j}P_j} &{} \frac{(\phi ^{{\rm G}1}_{j})^2}{2x_i\alpha ^{11}_{j}P_j}\end{array}\right] ,&{} P_1< P_{\rm G} < P_2\\ \left( 0,0 \right) ',&{} P_2 > P_\mathrm{G}.\\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(25)

The proofs of Propositions 2 and 3 come from expanding and inspecting the derivative matrix \(\frac{\partial E^{*}_{ij}}{\partial P_\mathrm{E}}\). The proof of Proposition 1 has two parts. When \(P_\mathrm{G} < P_1\), \(\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}\) and \(\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\) are negative because the matrices A and hence \(A^{-1}\) are negative definite. When \(P_1 \le P_\mathrm{G} \le P_2\) and only one input \((\theta ^1_{ij})\) is used, inspection of Eq. 25 shows the derivatives are negative as \(\alpha ^{11}_{j} <0\).

Appendix 2: Proof that \(\frac{{\rm dGHG}^*}{{\rm d}P_{\rm G}} <0\) when there is an NTS

Proof.

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{dGHG}^*}{\mathrm{d}P_\mathrm{G}}= & {} \sum _{j\in \mathbf {J}}\sum _{i\in \mathbf {I}^j}\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}+\sum _{j\in \mathbf {J}}\sum _{i\in \mathbf {I}^j}\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}\times \frac{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}} \nonumber \\= & {} \sum _{j\in \mathbf {J}}\sum _{i\in \mathbf {I}^j}\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}-\sum _{j\in \mathbf {J}}\sum _{i\in \mathbf {I}^j}\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}\times \frac{\sum _{j\in \mathbf {J}}\sum _{i\in \mathbf {I}^j}\frac{\partial N_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}}{\sum _{j\in \mathbf {J}}\sum _{i\in \mathbf {I}^j}\frac{\partial N_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}} \nonumber \\= & {} \frac{\left( \sum _{j\in \mathbf {J}}\sum _{i\in \mathbf {I}^j}\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) \left( \sum _{j\in \mathbf {J}}\sum _{i\in \mathbf {I}^j}\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}\right) -\left( \sum _{j\in \mathbf {J}}\sum _{i\in \mathbf {I}^j}\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) ^2}{\sum _{j\in \mathbf {J}}\sum _{i\in \mathbf {I}^j}\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}} \end{aligned}$$
(26)

since \(\frac{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}=-\frac{\sum _{j\in \mathbf {J}}\sum _{i\in \mathbf {I}^j}\frac{\partial {\rm N}^*_{i,j}}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}}{\sum _{j\in \mathbf {J}}\sum _{i\in \mathbf {I}^j}\frac{\partial {\rm N}^*_{i,j}}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}}\) and \(\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}=\frac{\partial {\rm GHG}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}\)\(\forall i\).

As the denominator in Eq. (26) is negative, \(\frac{\mathrm{dGHG}^*}{\mathrm{d}P_\mathrm{G}}<0\) if the numerator is positive. The proof is done by induction by considering how the numerator changes when moving from M farmers to \(M+1\) farmers. First, we show that for any individual farmer s\(\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}\ge \left( \frac{\partial {\rm N}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) ^2\). Then, we prove

  1. 1.

    if \(\left( \sum _{i=1}^M\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) \left( \sum _{i=1}^M\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}\right) -\left( \sum _{i=1}^M\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) ^2\ge 0\); and

  2. 2.

    if \(\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}\ge \left( \frac{\partial {\rm N}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) ^2\) for the additional \(M+1\) farmer s; then

  3. 3.

    \(\left( \sum _{i=1}^{M+1}\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) \left( \sum _{i=1}^{M+1}\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}\right) -\left( \sum _{i=1}^{M+1}\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) ^2\ge 0\).

Stage 1

We show that for any farmer s, \(\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}\ge \left( \frac{\partial {\rm N}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) ^2\) whether the farmer uses 1 or 2 inputs. Consider a farmer that uses only 1 input (input 2). From (18), \(\frac{\partial {\rm N}^*_{s,j}}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}=\frac{(\phi ^{\rm N2}_j)^2}{2\alpha ^{22}_jx_sP_j}\); \(\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}^*_{s,j}}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}=\frac{(\phi ^{\rm G2}_j)^2}{2\alpha ^{22}_jx_sP_j}\); and \(\frac{\partial {\rm N}^*_{s,j}}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}=\frac{\phi ^{\rm N2}_j\phi ^{\rm G2}_j}{2\alpha ^{22}_jx_sP_j}\). Hence,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\frac{\partial N_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}-\left( \frac{\partial N_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) ^2= & {} \frac{1}{2\alpha ^{22}_jx_sP_j}\left[ (\phi ^{G2}_j)^2(\phi ^{N2}_j)^2-(\phi ^{N2}_j\phi ^{G2}_j)^2\right] =0. \end{aligned}$$

Second, consider a farmer who uses both inputs. Using the expressions for \(\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\), \(\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}\), and \(\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\) from Eq. 17, it can be shown that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}-\left( \frac{\partial {\rm N}_{s,j}}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) ^2=\frac{[4(\alpha ^{11}_j\alpha _j^{22}-(\alpha ^{12}_j)^2)((\phi ^{{\rm N}1}_j\phi ^{{\rm G}2}_j)-(\phi ^{{\rm N}2}_j\phi ^{{\rm G}1}_j))^2 ]}{4(\alpha ^{11}_j\alpha ^{22}_j-(\alpha ^{12}_j)^2)x_sP_j} \ge 0. \end{aligned}$$

Hence, whether farmer s uses one or two inputs \(\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}\ge \left( \frac{\partial {\rm N}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) ^2\).

Stage 2

To prove the second stage, suppose for some collection of M farmers,

\(\left( \sum _{i=1}^M\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) \left( \sum _{i=1}^M\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{i,j^*}}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}\right) -\left( \sum _{i=1}^M\frac{\partial {\rm N}_{i,j^*}}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) ^2\ge 0\). Let

  1. 1.

    \(A_M=\sum _{i=1}^M\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{i,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\); \(B_M=\sum _{i=1}^M\frac{\partial {\rm N}^*_{i,j}}{\partial P_{\rm N}}\); and \(C_M=\sum _{i=1}^M\left( \frac{\partial {\rm N}^*_{i,j}}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) ^2\)

  2. 2.

    \(a_m=\frac{\partial \mathrm{GHG}_{s,j}^*}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\); \(b_m=\frac{\partial {\rm N}^*_{s,j}}{\partial P_\mathrm{N}}\); and \(c_m=\left( \frac{\partial {\rm N}^*_{s,j}}{\partial P_\mathrm{G}}\right) ^2\).

Note \(a_mA_M\ge 0\), \(b_mB_M\ge 0\), and \(c_mC_M\ge 0\), and let \(\epsilon =A_MB_M-C_M^2 \ge 0\), \(\mu = a_mb_m-c_m^2 \ge 0\). Then,

$$\begin{aligned} (A_M+a_m)(B_M+b_m)=\,\, & {} A_MB_M+a_mb_m+a_mB_M+A_Mb_m \nonumber \\=\,\, & {} (C_M^2+\epsilon )+(c^2_m+\mu )+\frac{(c_m^2+\mu )B_M}{b_m}+\frac{(C_M^2+\epsilon )b_m}{B_M} \nonumber \\= \,\,& {} (C_M^2+\epsilon )+(c^2_m+\mu )+c_mC_M\left( \frac{c_mB_M}{C_Mb_m}+\frac{C_Mb_m}{c_mB_M}\right) +\frac{\mu B_M}{b_m}+\frac{\epsilon b_m}{B_M} \nonumber \\= \,\,& {} C_M^2+c_m^2+c_mC_M \left( \frac{c_mB_M}{C_Mb_m}+\frac{C_Mb_m}{c_mB_M}\right) +(B_M+b_m)\left( \frac{\mu }{b_m}+\frac{\epsilon }{B_M}\right) \nonumber \\\ge\,\, & {} C_M^2+c_m^2+2c_mC_M +(B_M+b_m)\left( \frac{\mu }{b_m}+\frac{\epsilon }{B_M}\right) \nonumber \\\ge \,\,& {} (C_M+c_M)^2. \end{aligned}$$
(27)

as \(\left( \frac{c_mB_M}{C_Mb_m}+\frac{C_Mb_m}{c_mB_M}\right)\)\(\ge 2\) and \(\epsilon\), \(\mu \ge 0\).

Hence, if a collection of M farmers satisfies condition 1, any set of \(M+1\) farmers also satisfies it. Since we showed condition 1 holds when \(M=1\), by induction it must hold for any arbitrary set of farmers. Thus, the numerator of equation 19 is non-negative and so \(\frac{\mathrm{d GHG}^*}{\mathrm{d} P_\mathrm{G}} \le 0\).

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Yeo, BL., Coleman, A. Taxes versus emissions trading system: evaluating environmental policies that affect multiple types of pollution. Environ Econ Policy Stud 21, 141–169 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10018-018-0225-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10018-018-0225-x

Keywords

Navigation