Journal of Economics

, Volume 110, Issue 3, pp 203–224 | Cite as

Time consuming resource extraction in an overlapping generations economy with capital

Article
  • 227 Downloads

Abstract

For worldwide fisheries production, two major trends emerge for the next decades: a significantly larger role for aquaculture and reduced output due to climate change impacts. While the former leads to an increase in cost, the latter affects natural regeneration. To address both impacts, we investigate the relevance of resource extraction costs for a private property fishery in an intertemporal general equilibrium model with capital accumulation, commodity production and a labor market. We show how the extraction cost parameter—in addition to time preference, technology and natural regeneration—matters for the existence (and stability) of an economically feasible, nontrivial stationary state. Higher extraction costs increase the equilibrium resource stock, while a reduced regeneration rate (e.g. due to climate change) decreases the stock. Moreover, resource extraction overshoots its new equilibrium value after the cost shock while after a regeneration shock extraction levels adjust monotonically towards the new equilibrium.

Keywords

Renewable resources Time consuming extraction costs Overlapping generations Resource shocks 

JEL Classification

C62 D90 Q20 

References

  1. Agnani B, Gutiérrez MJ, Iza A (2005) Growth in overlapping generation economies with non-renewable resources. J Environ Econ Manag 50(2):387–407CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Alvarez-Cuadrado F, Van Long N (2011) Relative consumption and renewable resource extraction under alternative property-rights regimes. Resour Energy Econ 33:1028–1053CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Babu PG, Kavi Kumar K (1997) An overlapping generations model with exhaustible resources and stock pollution. Ecol Econ 21:35–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Begon M, Harper JL, Townsend CR (1996) Ecology. Individuals, populations and communities, 3rd edn. Blackwell, MaldenCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bréchet T, Lambrecht S (2011) Renewable resources and capital with a joy-of-giving resource bequest motive. Resour Energy Econ 33:981–994CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Brown GM (2000) Renewable natural resource management and use without markets. J Econ Lit 38(4):875–914CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Clark CW (1990) Mathematical bioeconomics: the optimal management of renewable resources, 2nd edn. Wiley, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  8. Conrad JM (1999) Resource economics. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. de la Croix D, Michel P (2002) A theory of economic growth. Dynamics and policy in overlapping generations. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  10. Diamond P (1965) National debt in a neoclassical growth model. Am Econ Rev 55:1126–1150Google Scholar
  11. Elíasson L, Turnovsky SJ (2004) Renewable resources in an endogenously growing economy: balanced growth and transitional dynamics. J Environ Econ Manag 48:1018–1049CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Farmer K (2000) Intergenerational natural-capital equality in an overlapping-generations model with logistic regeneration. J Econ 72(2):129–152CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Galor O (1992) A two-sector overlapping-generations model: a global characterization of the dynamical system. Econometrica 60(6):1351–1386CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Heaps T, Neher PA (1979) The economics of forestry when the rate of harvest is constrained. J Environ Econ Manag 6:297–319CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Kemp M, Van Long N (1979) The under-exploitation of natural resources: a model with overlapping generations. J Econ Theory 55:214–221Google Scholar
  16. Koskela E, Ollikainen M, Puhakka M (2002) Renewable resources in an overlapping generations economy without capital. J Environ Econ Manag 43(3):497–517CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Krautkraemer JA, Batina RG (1999) On sustainability and intergenerational transfers with a renewable resource. Land Econ 75(2):167–184CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Krutilla K, Reuveny R (2004) A renewable resource-based Ramsey model with costly resource extraction. Environ Resour Econ 27:165–185CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Mourmouras A (1991) Competitive equilibira and sustainable growth in a life-cycle model with natural resources. Scand J Econ 93(4):585–591CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Neher P (1990) Natural resource economics: conservation and exlpoitation. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  21. Neher PA (1974) Notes on the Volterra-quadratic fishery. J Econ Theory 8:39–49Google Scholar
  22. Nourry C (2001) Stability of equilibria in the overlapping generations model with endogenous labor supply. J Econ Dyn Control 25:1647–1663CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. OECD, FAO (2011) OECD–FAO agricultural outlook 2011–2020. Tech. rep, OECD/FAO, ParisGoogle Scholar
  24. Olson LJ, Knapp KC (1997) Exhaustible resource allocation in an overlapping generations economy. J Environ Econ Manag 32:277–292Google Scholar
  25. Perman R, Ma Y, Common M, Maddison D, McGilvray J (2011) Natural resource and environmental economics, 4th edn. Addison Wesley, HarlowGoogle Scholar
  26. Samuelson P (1947) Foundations of economic analysis. Harvard University Press, HarvardGoogle Scholar
  27. Samuelson PA (1958) An exact consumption-loan model of interest rate with or without the social contrivance of money. J Polit Econ 66:467–482CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Schaefer MB (1954) Some aspects of the dynamics of populations important to the management of commercial marine fisheries. Bull Inter Am Trop Tuna Comm 1:25–56Google Scholar
  29. Smith VL (1968) Economics of production from natural resources. Am Econ Rev 58:409–432Google Scholar
  30. Tahvonen O, Kuuluvainen J (2000) The economics of natural resource utilization. In: Folmer H, Gabel HL (eds) Principles of environmental and resource economics, 2nd edn. Edward Elgar, Chelthenham, pp 665–699Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Wien 2012

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsUniversity of GrazGrazAustria

Personalised recommendations