Abstract
We study a model in which a single object is to be allocated among a set of agents whose valuations are interdependent. We define signal-ranking mechanisms and show that if the signal-ranking allocation rule satisfies a combinatorial condition and the valuation functions are additively separable, there exist budget-balanced and ex-post incentive compatible signal-ranking mechanisms. For a restricted setting, we show that the worst-case efficient mechanism of Long et al. (Games Econ Behav 105:9–39, 2017) continues to be worst-case efficient. We also give an example to show that their mechanism is no longer optimal when restrictions are relaxed.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.
Data availability
Not applicable as there is no data or empirical analysis in this paper.
Notes
In some special cases like the sequencing problem it might be possible to reconcile the three properties e.g. Hain and Mitra (2004). Also, Kosenok and Severinov (2008) show that there exists an ex-post efficient mechanism that is interim incentive-compatible, interim individually-rational and ex-post budget balanced when the joint distribution of the values is known and which satisfies Cremer and McLean (1988) conditions and the identifiability condition.
We suppress the dependence of L on s for notational convenience.
The valuation functions \(v_i:[0,1]^n \rightarrow \mathbb {R_+}\), \(i \in N\) satisfy single-crossing if for every \(i, j \in N\), every \(s_{-i} \in S_{-i}\) and every \(s_i > s'_i\),
$$\begin{aligned} v_i (s_i, s_{-i}) - v_i (s'_i , s_{-i}) > v_j (s_i, s_{-i}) - v_j (s'_i , s_{-i}) \end{aligned}$$The valuation functions satisfy the SAS condition. Notice that for any two agents i and j, if \(s_i > s_j\) then \(v_i (s) > v_j(s)\) and vice versa. Also, \(s_i = s_j\) implies \(v_i (s) = v_j (s)\) and vice versa.
See Krishna (2009) where it is shown that single-crossing condition is sufficient for ex-post incentive compatibility of generalized Vickrey auction.
References
Bergemann D, Morris S (2005) Robust mechanism design. Econometrica 73(6):1771–1813
Cremer J, McLean R (1988) Full extraction of the surplus in bayesian and dominant strategy auctions. Econometrica 56:1247–1258
Dasgupta P, Maskin E (2000) Efficient auctions. Quart J Econ 115(2):341–388
d’Aspremont C, Gerard-Varet L (1982) Bayesian incentive compatible beliefs. J Math Econ 10(1):83–103
Eden A, Feldman M, Fiat A, Goldner K (2018) Interdependent values without single-crossing. Proceedings of the 2018 ACM Conference on Economics and Computation (EC’18). ACM, New York, NY, USA, pp 369–369
Green J, Laffont J (1979) Incentives in public decision-making. Elsevier, Amsterdam
Hain D, Mitra M (2004) Simple sequencing problems with interdependent costs. Games Econom Behav 48:271–291
Jehiel P, Moldovanu B (2001) Efficient design with interdependent valuations. Econometrica 69(5):1237–1259
Kosenok G, Severinov S (2008) Individually rational, budget-balanced mechanisms and allocation of surplus. J Econ Theory 140:126–161
Krishna V (2009) Auction theory. Academic Press, Cambridge
Long Y (2019) Optimal budget-balanced ranking mechanisms to assign identical objects. Econ Theor 70:467–502
Long Y, Mishra D, Sharma T (2017) Balanced ranking mechanisms. Games Econom Behav 105:9–39
Milgrom P, Weber R (1982) A theory of auctions and competitive bidding. Econometrica 50(5):1089–1122
Mishra D, Sharma T (2018) A simple budget balanced mechanism. Soc Choice Welfare 169:218–233
Nath S, Zoeter O, Narahari Y, Dance C (2015) Dynamic mechanism design with interdependent valuations. Rev Econ Design 19(3):211–228
Perry M, Reny P (1999) An ex-post efficient auction. Working paper, Hebrew University and University of Chicago
Roughgarden T, Talgam-Cohen I (2016) Optimal and robust mechanism design with interdependent values. ACM Trans Econ Comput 4(3):18:1-18:34
Yenmez M (2015) Incentive compatible market design with applications. Internat J Game Theory 44:543–569
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
This paper is based on one of the papers in my PhD thesis written while at Indian Statistical Institute, Delhi. I would like to thank my supervisor Arunava Sen for his valuable guidance. I also thank Debasis Mishra for his comments.
Appendix
Appendix
The following lemma gives the sufficient condition for a s-ranking allocation rule to be ex-post implementable.
Lemma 1
An s-ranking mechanism is EPIC if the valuation functions \((v_1 (s), v_2 (s), \ldots , v_n (s) )\) are increasing in their own signal.
Proof
We show that the signal-ranking mechanism is EPIC. Consider an arbitrary signal profile s and without loss of generality let \(s_1> s_2> \cdots > s_n\). The payment of agent ranked i is:
If the agent i reports \(s_{i'} > s_i\) such that his rank is \(i' < i\), the payment of the agent is
Let \(\Delta u (s_{i'}, s_i) = v_i (s) \pi _i - p_i (s) - \big ( v_{i'} (s) \pi _{i'} - p_{i'} (s_{i'}, s_{-i'}) \big )\) be the difference between utilities obtained by agent ranked i with signal type \(s_i\) when he reports the true signal and when he falsely reports \(s_{i'}\). Hence,
As the function \(v_i (s_i, s_{-i})\) is increasing in \(s_i\), the expression in (8) is positive. Similarly if \(s_{i'} < s_i\), then also \(\Delta u (s_{i'}, s_i) > 0\). Hence, the mechanism is EPIC. \(\square\)
Proof of Theorem 3:
Let there be an arbitrary s-ranking mechanism \(\pi = (\pi _1, \pi _2, \ldots , \pi _n)\). The efficiency ratio of the mechanism at arbitrary signal profile s is:
The worst-case efficiency ratio is
If the signal profile is such that \(s_1 \ge s_2 \ge \cdots \ge s_n\), then
The minimum value of each of the \(n-1\) ratios is \(\frac{1}{\gamma }\) and the minima occurs at \((s_1,s_2,\ldots ,s_n)=(1,0,0,\ldots , 0)\). Hence,
The optimization problem is:
This optimization problem is equivalent to the optimization problem solved by Long et al. (2017) to find the optimal worst-case efficient ranking mechanism in the class of dominant strategy incentive-compatible and BB mechanisms. This is because all the constraints in both the problems are identical and the objective function above is a monotonic transformation of objective function of their optimization problem. Hence, \(\pi ^*\) also solves our optimization problem and maximizes the worst-case efficiency ratio. \(\square\)
Rights and permissions
Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.
About this article
Cite this article
Vikram, A. Worst-case efficient and budget-balanced mechanism for single-object allocation with interdependent values. Soc Choice Welf (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-023-01479-x
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-023-01479-x