Skip to main content
Log in

Cycles in synchronous iterative voting: general robustness and examples in Approval Voting

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We consider synchronous iterative voting, where voters are given the opportunity to strategically choose their ballots depending on the outcome deduced from the previous collective choices. We propose two settings for synchronous iterative voting, one of classical flavor with a discrete space of states, and a more general continuous-space setting extending the first one. We give a general robustness result for cycles not relying on a tie-breaking rule, showing that they persist under small enough perturbations of the behavior of voters. Then we give examples in Approval Voting of electorates applying simple, sincere and consistent heuristics (namely Laslier’s Leader Rule or a modification of it) leading to cycles with bad outcomes, either not electing an existing Condorcet winner, or possibly electing a candidate ranked last by a majority of voters. Using the robustness result, it follows that those “bad cycles” persist even if only a (large enough) fraction of the electorate updates its choice of ballot at each iteration. We complete these results with examples in other voting methods, including ranking methods satisfying the Condorcet criterion; an in silico experimental study of the rarity of preference profiles exhibiting bad cycles; and an example exhibiting chaotic behavior.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A similar argument has been raised by Warren D. Smith and is used by advocates of Approval Voting and Range Voting, see https://www.rangevoting.org/AppCW.html. The argument of Smith is less rigorous than Laslier’s, since the equilibrium assumption is kept implicit.

  2. An example of cycle under the Leader Rule is given as exercise 8.4.4 in Meir (2018), but there are no Condorcet winner.

References

  • Airiau S, Grandi U, Perotto FS (2017) Learning agents for iterative voting. In: International conference on algorithmic decision theory. In: International conference on algorithmic decision theory. Springer, pp 139–152

  • Black D (1986) The theory of committees and elections. Springer (Originally published 1958)

  • Bowman C, Hodge JK, Yu A (2014) The potential of iterative voting to solve the separability problem in referendum elections. Theory Decis 77(1):111–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brams SJ, Fishburn PC (2010) Going from theory to practice: the mixed success of approval voting. In: Handbook on approval voting. Springer, pp 19–37

  • Brams SJ, Sanver MR (2003) Voter sovereignty and election outcomes. http://dev.gtcenter.org/Archive/Conf03/Sovereignty.pdf

  • Brams S, Fishburn PC (2007) Approval voting. Springer Science & Business Media, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Brandt F, Conitzer V, Endriss U, Lang J, Procaccia AD (eds) (2016) Handbook of computational social choice. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Brânzei S, Caragiannis I, Morgenstern J, Procaccia AD (2013) How bad is selfish voting? In: Proceedings of the twenty-seventh AAAI conference on artificial intelligence, pp 138–144

  • Chopra S, Pacuit E, Parikh R (2004) Knowledge-theoretic properties of strategic voting. In: European workshop on logics in artificial intelligence. Springer, pp 18–30

  • De Sinopoli F, Dutta B, Laslier J-F (2006) Approval voting: three examples. Int J Game Theory 35:27–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durand F (2015) Vers des modes de scrutin moins manipulable. Ph.D. thesis. Université Pierre et Marie Curie

  • Durand F, Mathieu F, Noirie L (2016) Can a condorcet rule have a low coalitional manipulability? ECAI IOS Press 2016:707–715

    Google Scholar 

  • Durand F, Fabien M, Ludovic N (2014) Making most voting systems meet the condorcet criterion reduces their manipulability. https://hal.inria.fr/hal-01009134/file/condorcification.pdf

  • Gibbard A (1973) Manipulation of voting schemes: a general result. Econometrica 587–601

  • Grandi U, Hughes D, Rossi F, Slinko A (2019) Gibbard–Satterthwaite games for k-approval voting rules. Math Soc Sci 99:24–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grandi U, Loreggia A, Rossi F, Venable KB, Walsh T (2013) Restricted manipulation in iterative voting: condorcet efficiency and borda score. In: International conference on algorithmic decision-theory. Springer

  • Green-Armytage J, Tideman TN, Cosman R (2016) Statistical evaluation of voting rules. Soc Choice Welf 46(1):183–212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katok A, Hasselblatt B (1995) Introduction to the modern theory of dynamical systems. In: Encyclopedia of mathematics and its applications, vol 54. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (With a supplementary chapter by Katok and Leonardo Mendoza)

  • Koolyk A, Strangway T, Lev O, Rosenschein JS (2017) Convergence and quality of iterative voting under non-scoring rules. In: Proceedings of the 2016 international conference on autonomous agents & multiagent systems

  • Laslier J-F (2009) The Leader Rule: a model of strategic approval voting in a large electorate. J Theor Polit 21(1):113–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laslier J-F (2010) In silico voting experiments. Handbook on approval voting. Springer, Berlin, pp 311–335

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lepelley D, Louichi A, Valognes F (2000) Computer simulations of voting systems. Adv Complex Syst 3(1–4):181–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lev O, Rosenschein JS (2016) Convergence of iterative scoring rules. J Artif Intell Res 57:573–591

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meir R (2018) Strategic voting. Synth Lect Artif Intell Mach Learn 13(1):1–167

    Google Scholar 

  • Meir R (2015) Plurality voting under uncertainty. In: Proceedings of the twenty-ninth AAAI conference on artificial intelligence. AAAI Press, pp 2103–2109

  • Meir R (2017) Iterative voting. Trends Comput Soc Choice 69–86

  • Meir R, Polukarov M, Rosenschein JS, Jennings NR (2017) Iterative voting and acyclic games. Artif Intell 252:100–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meir R, Lev O, Rosenschein JS (2014) A local-dominance theory of voting equilibria. In:Proceedings of the fifteenth ACM conference on economics and computation. ACM, New York, pp 313–330

  • Obraztsova S, Lev O, Polukarov M, Rabinovich Z, Rosenschein JS (2015) Farsighted voting dynamics. In: 1st workshop on algorithmic game theory at IJCAIgame theory at IJCAI

  • Obraztsova S, Markakis E, Polukarov M, Rabinovich Z, Jennings NR (2015) On the convergence of iterative voting: how restrictive should restricted dynamics be? In: Proceedings of the twenty-ninth AAAI conference on artificial intelligence. AAAI Press, pp 993–999

  • Rabinovich Z, Obraztsova S, Lev O, Markakis E, Rosenschein JS (2015) Analysis of equilibria in iterative voting schemes. In: Proceedings of the twenty-ninth AAAI conference on artificial intelligence. AAAI Press

  • Reijngoud A, Endriss U (2012) Voter response to iterated poll information. In: Proceedings of the 11th international conference on autonomous agents and multiagent systems-volume 2. International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems, pp 635–644

  • Satterthwaite MA (1975) Strategy-proofness and arrow’s conditions: existence and correspondence theorems for voting procedures and social welfare functions. J Econ Theory 10(2):187–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sertel MR, Sanver MR (2004) Strong equilibrium outcomes of voting games are the generalized condorcet winners. Soc Choice Welf 22(2):331–347

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walters P (1982) An introduction to ergodic theory, Graduate texts in mathematics, vol 79. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am indebted to Adrien Fauré @AdrienGazouille for a long debate on twitter (in French) that lead me to seek and design the examples for Approval Voting presented here, and to François Durand for introducing me to the Social choice theory, for many discussions on Voting Systems, and for many suggestions that helped me improve this article. It also benefited from relevant comments provided by Adrien Fauré, Jean-François Laslier, Reshef Meir and anonymous referees who I warmly thank.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Benoît R. Kloeckner.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kloeckner, B.R. Cycles in synchronous iterative voting: general robustness and examples in Approval Voting. Soc Choice Welf 59, 423–466 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-022-01395-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-022-01395-6

Navigation