Skip to main content
Log in

Estimating capabilities with random scale models: women’s freedom of movement

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In Sen’s capability approach well-being is evaluated not only in terms of functionings (what they do and who they are) but also in terms of capabilities (what people are free to do and to be). It implies that individuals with the same observed functionings may have different well-being because their choice sets (i.e. capabilities) are different. We utilise a Random Scale Model to measure the latent capability of Italian women to move based on observations of their realized choices. We demonstrate that such models can offer a suitable framework for measuring how individuals are restricted in their capabilities. Our estimations show that the percentage of women predicted to be restricted in their freedom of movement (have restricted capability sets) is 23–25%. If all women were unconstrained, our model predicts that 15–17% of them would choose to do more activities.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Appendix A shows how this is the case for the model presented in Sect. 2.

  2. The multinomial logit is the most used distribution for modelling multinomial discrete variables because of its simple parametric structure. For example, the more general multivariate normal distribution with an arbitrary correlation matrix requires evaluating probabilities given by multidimensional normal integrals that restricts the application to only few alternatives. Ilmakunnas and Pudney (1990) model job opportunities in a similar manner to our modelling of opportunity sets. In a labour supply model, they model job opportunity using both a structural approach and the multinomial distribution approach. They consider both approaches valid, but conclude that “on simple goodness-of-fit grounds ... the heavily-parameterised Multinomial Logit Model is clearly the preferred specification” (p. 193).

  3. See Sect. 3 for a detailed description of the index.

  4. Ben–Akiva and Watanatada (1981) propose an interesting approach using a Random Scale Model when the choice alternatives can be classified into two levels: “main” observed alternatives and latent “elemental” alternatives. For each main alternative there would be a set of (different) latent elemental alternatives available. The main alternatives could for example be labor market sectors, while the set of latent elemental alternatives could be jobs within the sector. This approach is not suitable in our case because each aggregate state (each level of our index) can contain any of the underlying choice sets. There is not a unique elemental set that can be associated with each level of the index.

  5. For a detailed analysis of the sample selection see next section.

  6. We have considered “Driving a car” as an activity in itself. It could also be seen as a resource/conversion factor, because it could be of help in practicing other activities. Nevertheless, in order to be taken into account as a conversion factor, we would have needed some other variables related to the availability of public transport in the area where the woman lives and we do not have such information.

  7. We have also estimated a model based on a four state activity index, but found that the increased number of values complicated our estimation due to empty cells, without changing the general results.

  8. The Italian Survey on Household Income and Wealth (SHIW) includes income, but does not have data on the activities women perform. Italian time use surveys have information on women’s activities, but do not include income or information about the partner.

  9. For a detailed description of the survey and its results see the Istat report http://www.istat.it/it/files/2011/07/Full_text.pdf. Muratore and Sabbadini (2005) describes the different phases for the implementation of the Italian Violence against Women Survey while Istat (2006) provides a description of the methodology.

  10. It is not possible in our data to identify disability. There is only a question about the occupational status of the woman. The possible answers are: working, looking for a first job, looking for a job, student, housewife, unable to work, retired, missing. In the sample there were only 44 women who replied that their occupational status was being unable to work and were therefore excluded.

  11. Estimates are available from the authors upon request.

  12. Our data lack information regarding income and children. We acknowledge that this is an important limitation, because children could restrict women’s activities outside the house (or increase her activities) and income can only be imperfectly proxied by education.

  13. Marginal effects for continuous variables are the derivatives of the Q probabilities (the probability of being observed in one of the states) with respect to a change in the variable. Marginal effects for dummy variables are the changes in the Q probabilities when the dummy goes from 0 to 1. The marginal effect for psychological violence is also for a change from 0 to 1, even though it is continuous. Since most women answer no to all the questions on psychological violence, the median size of this variable is 0 and it is natural to look at the change from 0 to answering yes to one question. Note that the marginal effects for each variable sums to zero across states. The base category for the choice probabilities is activity level 3: doing 4 or more activities, and the base category for the restriction probabilities is the full capability set \(C_{3}\).

  14. See literature discussion in Sect. 4.

  15. Tables with results are available from the authors upon request.

  16. In the first case, there are 1874 women who leave activity level 1 from among those who were previously constrained to this level. It is calculated as the expected value of \(( {1-\hat{P} _1 } )\cdot \hat{r} ( {C_1 } )\), where \(\mathop P \) and \(\mathop r \) are predicted probabilities based on our estimates. In the second case, there are 462 women who leave activity level 1 from among those who were previously constrained to activity level 2 or lower. It is calculated as the expected value of \(( {\left. {\hat{P} _1 } \right| C_2 -P_1 } )\cdot \hat{r} \left( {C_2 } \right) \), where \(\left. {\hat{P}_1 } \right| C_2 \) is the predicted condtional probability of choosing level 1 conditional on being restricted to level 2 or lower.

References

  • Anand P, Hunter G, Carter I, Dowding K, Guala F, Van Hees M (2009) The development of capability indicators. J Hum Dev Capab 10(1):125–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anand P, Santos C (2007) Violence, gender inequalities and life satisfation. Revue d’Economie Politique 117:135–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anand P, Roope L, Gray A (2013) Beyond GDP and HDI: the multi-dimensional measurement of wellbeing and progress. Miemo, Open University and University, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Akiva M, Watanatada T (1981) Application of a continuous spatial choice model. In: Manski CF, McFadden D (eds) Structural analysis of discrete data with econometric applications. The MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 320–343

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloch F, Rao V (2002) Terror as a bargaining instrument: a case study of Dowry violence in rural India. Am Econ Rev 92:1029–1043

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark DA (ed) (2012) Adaptation, poverty and development. Palgrave Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dagsvik JK (2013) Making Sen’s capability approach operational: a random scale framework. Theory Decis 74:75–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Tommaso ML (2007) Measuring the well being of children using a capability approach: an application to Indian data. J Soc Econ 36:436–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Tommaso ML, Shima I, Strøm S, Bettio F (2009) As bad as it gets. Well-being deprivation of sexually exploited trafficked women. Eur J Polit Econ 25:143–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elster J (1983) Sour grapes: studies in the subversion of rationality. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Eswaran M, Malhotra N (2011) Domestic violence and women’s autonomy in developing countries: theory and evidence. Can J Econ Revue canadienne d’Economique 44(4):1222–1263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleurbaey M (2006) Capabilities, functionings, and refined functionings. J Hum Dev 7(3):299–310

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ilmakunnas S, Pudney S (1990) A model of female labour supply in the presence of hours retrictions. J Public Econ 41(2):183–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Istat (2006) La Violenza contro le donne. Indagine multiscopo sulle famiglie “Sicurezza delle donne” Anno 2006. Roma, ISTAT. http://www.cismai.it/documenti/ISTAT_la_violenza_contro_le_donne.pdf Accessed 9 Dec 2017

  • Koopmans TC (1964) On flexibility of future preference. In: Shelly MW II, Bryan GI (eds) Human judgments and optimality. Wiley, New York, pp 243–254

    Google Scholar 

  • Kreps D (1979) A representation theorem for ‘preference for flexibility’. Econometrica 47:565–577

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishnakumar J (2007) Going beyond functionings to capabilities: an econometric model to explain and estimate capabilities. J Hum Dev 8(1):39–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishnakumar J, Ballon P (2008) Estimating basic capabilities: a latent variable approach applied to Bolivia. World Dev 36:992–1010

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luce RD, Suppes P (1965) Preference, utility and subjective probability. In: Luce RD, Bush RR, Galanter E (eds), Handbook of mathematical psychology, vol III, Wiley, New York

  • Luce RD (1959) Individual choice behavior. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Manski CF (1977) The structure of random utility models. Theory Decis 8(3):229–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McFadden D (1973) Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice behaviour. In: Zarembka P (ed), Frontiers in econometrics, Wiley, New York

  • McFadden D (1984) Econometric analysis of qualitative response models. In: Griliches Z, Intrilligator MD (eds), Handbook of econometrics, Vol III, Elsevier, New York

  • Menon N, Johnson MP (2007) ’Patriarchy and paternalism in intimate partner violence: a study of domestic violence in rural India. In: Misra KK, Lowry JH (eds), Recent studies on Indian women: empirical work of social scientists, Rawat Publications, Jaipur

  • Muratore MG, Sabbadini LL (2005) Italian survey on violence against women. Stat J United Nations Econ Commission Eur 22(3, 4):265–278

    Google Scholar 

  • Nussbaum MC (1999) Sex and social justice. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Quandt RE (1956) A probabilistic theory of consumer behavior. Q J Econ 70(4):507–536

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robeyns I (2003) Sen’s capability approach and gender inequality: selecting relevant capabilities. Feminist Econ 9(2–3):62–92

    Google Scholar 

  • Robeyns I (2004) Measuring gender inequality in functionings and capabilities: findings from the British household panel survey. In: Bharati P, Pal M (eds) Gender disparity: manifestations, causes and implications. Anmol Publications, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen AK (1985) Commodities and capabilities. North-Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen A (1991) Welfare, preference and freedom. J Econ 50(1–2):15–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen AK (1992) Inequality re-examined. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen AK (1999) Development as freedom. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen AK (2009) The idea of justice. Allen Lane, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Thurstone LL (1927) A law of comparative judgment. Psychol Rev 79:281–299

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to M. L. Di Tommaso.

Additional information

We would like to thank John K. Dagsvik for suggesting the statistical framework with latent choice sets and for valuable and insightful discussions. We also thanks participants to the seminars at the Department of Economics, University of Reading, Department of Policy Analysis and Public Management, University Bocconi, Milano. This work was supported by the University of Torino, Progetto di Ateneo FreeCap “How to measure and value freedom of choice? Operationalizing Sen’s capability approach with a gender perspective” and by the Italian Ministry of University, MIUR, Programmi di ricerca di rilevante interesse nazionale (PRIN), “Making Sen capabilities approach operational: methodological and empirical aspects”.

Appendices

Appendix A: Expected utility is increasing in opportunities

In the following we discuss in more detail our assertion in Sect. 2 that expected utility is increasing in opportunities. It is based on a discussion of the indirect random scale. This is analogous to indirect utility, which gives the maximal attainable utility when faced with given choice set. It reflects both preferences and the choice set. Towards the end, we also discuss how one might analyse how welfare varies across households, though we do not do this in the present paper.

The conditional indirect random scale \({V}{C}(\varepsilon _1,\ldots ,\varepsilon _{H})\)    will under our distributional assumptions be extreme value distributed. Let \(\bar{V}( {C_s } )\) be the deterministic part (representative part) of the conditional indirect scale, conditional on choice set \(C_{s}\) being available, defined as \(\bar{V}\left( {C_s } \right) =\hbox {E max}_{k\in C_s} U_k\). Due to the distributional assumptions about \(U_{k}\),it is well known that one obtains

$$\begin{aligned} {{\overline{V}}} \left( {C_s } \right) =\log \left( {\sum _{k\in C_s } {\exp \left( {v_k } \right) } } \right) ,\end{aligned}$$
(a1)

where it should be noted that the evaluation \(\hbox {exp}\left( {\nu _k } \right) \) is the same across choice sets.

From equation (C.1) it follows that in our case, with ranked latent capability sets, we have \( \bar{V} \left( {C_1 } \right)<\bar{V} \left( {C_2 } \right)<\cdots < \bar{V} \left( {C_H } \right) \). In other words, the conditional indirect scale is increasing in the size of the opportunity set.

As a measure of the well-being of individuals, it thereby has the desired property of valuing opportunities instead of only choices. In the following analysis of freedom of movement, we will not be using this measure, since we only consider a one-dimensional concept of freedom and thereby can directly say that it is better to have an unconstrained freedom of movement than a constrained one. If we were trying to evaluate different combinations of freedoms, then having a measure of the above type would be valuable. The unconditional representative indirect scale function is defined by

$$\begin{aligned} \hbox {E} \bar{V} \left( C \right) =\mathop \sum \limits _{s=1}^H \bar{V} \left( {C_s } \right) \cdot r\left( {C_s } \right) =\mathop \sum \limits _{s=1}^H r\left( {C_s } \right) \cdot \log \left( {\mathop \sum \limits _{k\in C_s } \hbox {exp}\left( {\nu _k } \right) } \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(a2)

Thus the conditional indirect scale function is the mean value of the chosen functioning restricted to a given capability set \(C_{s}\), whereas the unconditional indirect scale function is the mean value of the conditional indirect scale where the mean is taken over the possible capability sets. By means of \(\hbox {E }{{\overline{V}}} \left( C \right) \) one may analyse how welfare (in an ordinal sense) varies across households (identified by covariate values) for given selected capability sets. See Dagsvik (2013) for more details on this and for a discussion of how to develop a welfare function and a capability adjusted income distribution based on the indirect random scale function.

Appendix B: Identification

In the following we illustrate how identification can be achieved by introducing observed discrete covariates into the preference terms \(\{v_j \}\) and the restriction probabilities. To see that the model can be identified in this case, we show that the unrestricted choice probabilities and the restriction probabilities can be expressed as functions of the observable probabilities, \(Q_{j}\). By this we mean that, within subsamples of observationally identical households, all the probabilities \(r\left( {C_k } \right) \) and \(P_j \left( {C_k } \right) \), \(j\in C_k \), \(k = {1, 2,\ldots , L}\), can in principle be estimated by replacing the respective observable probabilities by their empirical counterparts, provided the subsamples are sufficiently large.

To see that introducing discrete covariates can identify our model, consider a two state model. From Eq. (1) we have

$$\begin{aligned} P_1 \left( {C_2 } \right)= & {} \frac{\exp \left( {X_i \beta } \right) }{1+\exp \left( {X_i \beta } \right) }, \end{aligned}$$
(b1)
$$\begin{aligned} P_2 \left( {C_2 } \right)= & {} \frac{1}{1+\exp \left( {X_i \beta } \right) }. \end{aligned}$$
(b2)

From this, together with Eqs. (3) and (5) we get

$$\begin{aligned} Q_1= & {} r\left( {C_1 } \right) +P_1 \left( {C_2 } \right) \cdot r\left( {C_2 } \right) =\frac{\exp \left( {X_i \beta } \right) +\exp \left( {Z_i \gamma } \right) +\exp \left( {X_i \beta +Z_i \gamma } \right) }{1+\exp \left( {X_i \beta } \right) +\exp \left( {Z_i \gamma } \right) +\exp \left( {X_i \beta +Z_i \gamma } \right) }\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(b3)
$$\begin{aligned} Q_2= & {} P_2 \left( {C_2 } \right) \cdot r\left( {C_2 } \right) =\frac{1}{1+\exp \left( {X_i \beta } \right) +\exp \left( {Z_i \gamma } \right) +\exp \left( {X_i \beta +Z_i \gamma } \right) }. \end{aligned}$$
(b4)

Rewriting Eqs. (b3, b4) as odds-ratios we get

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{Q_1 }{Q_2 }=\exp \left( {X_i \beta } \right) +\exp \left( {Z_i \gamma } \right) +\exp \left( {X_i \beta +Z_i \gamma } \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(b5)

Assume there is one dichotomous explanatory variable in each of the vectors so that \(X_{i}=\{{1,x}_{i}\}\) and \(Z_{i}=\{{1,z}_{i}\}\), with \(x_i \in \left\{ {0,1} \right\} \) and \(z_i \in \left\{ {0,1} \right\} \). This means that we can view women as belonging to one of four groups composed of the four different possible combinations of \(x_{i }\) and \(z_{i}\) (note that as the number of variables increases linearly, the number of possible combinations increases geometrically). We therefore get the following four equations for the four different subgroups among those who might be restricted in their choices:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{Q_1 }{Q_2 }= & {} \exp \left( {\beta _0 } \right) +\exp \left( {\gamma _0 } \right) +\exp \left( {\beta _0 +\gamma _0 } \right) , \qquad \qquad \qquad \quad if \quad x_i =0,\quad z_i =0\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(b6)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{Q_1 }{Q_2 }= & {} \exp \left( {\beta _0 +\beta _1 } \right) +\exp \left( {\gamma _0 } \right) +\exp \left( {\beta _0 +\beta _1 +\gamma _0 } \right) , \quad if \quad x_i =1,\quad z_i =0 \nonumber \\\end{aligned}$$
(b7)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{Q_1 }{Q_2 }= & {} \exp \left( {\beta _0 } \right) +\exp \left( {\gamma _0 +\gamma _1 } \right) +\exp \left( {\beta _0 +\gamma _0 +\gamma _1 } \right) , \quad if \quad x_i =0,\quad z_i =1 \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(b8)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{Q_1 }{Q_2 }= & {} \exp \left( {\beta _0 +\beta _1 } \right) +\exp \left( {\gamma _0 +\gamma _1 } \right) +\exp \left( {\beta _0 +\beta _1 +\gamma _0 +\gamma _1 } \right) , \nonumber \\&\quad if\quad x_i =1,\quad z_i =1 \end{aligned}$$
(b9)

where the parameter vectors are given as \(\beta =\left\{ {\beta _0 ,\beta { }_1} \right\} ^{\prime }\) and \(\gamma =\left\{ {\gamma _0 ,\gamma { }_1} \right\} ^{\prime }.\) This is four equations in four parameters, so there is now a possibility of the model being identified. Since these equations are non-linear, one cannot generally use a simple counting rule to generally establish identifiability, but the above indicates that a fairly small set of discrete explanatory variable should in practice lead to identification without requiring assumptions about who might be at risk of being restricted.

In general, the above model is only identified if we exogenously decide that a subgroup is never restricted, but in our case we have enough discrete explanatory variables to identify the model in the manner described above without needing to specify an unrestricted subgroup.

For continuous variables identification is readily established. Let

$$\begin{aligned} R\left( {X,Z} \right) =Q_1 \left( {X,Z} \right) /Q_2 \left( {X,Z} \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(b10)

Assume that R(XZ) is not constant, as a function of X for given Z and as a function of Z for given X. From (b5) we have that

$$\begin{aligned} R\left( {X,Z} \right) =\frac{Q_1 }{Q_2 }=\exp \left( {X_i \beta } \right) +\exp \left( {Z_i \gamma } \right) +\exp \left( {X_i \beta +Z_i \gamma } \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(b11)

Assume that the function R(XZ) is known for all vectors (X, Z) belonging to some set A. If (b11) holds for all vectors in A we shall show that the vectors of coefficients \(\beta \) and \(\gamma \) are uniquely determined. From (b11) it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial R(X,Z)}{\partial X_k }= & {} \exp (X\beta )\beta _k (1+\exp (Z\gamma )), \nonumber \\ \frac{\partial ^{2}R(X,Z)}{\partial X_k^2 }= & {} \exp (X\beta )\beta _k^2 (1+\exp (Z\gamma )) \end{aligned}$$
(b12)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial R(X,Z)}{\partial Z_k }= & {} \exp (Z\gamma )\gamma _k (1+\exp (X\beta )) \quad \quad \nonumber \\ \frac{\partial ^{2}R(X,Z)}{\partial Z_k^2 }= & {} \exp (Z\gamma )\gamma _k^2 (1+\exp (X\beta )). \end{aligned}$$
(b13)

From (b12) and (b13) it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^{2}R(X,Z)}{\partial X_k^2 }\Bigg /\frac{\partial R(X,Z)}{\partial X_k }=\beta _k \end{aligned}$$
(b14)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^{2}R(X,Z)}{\partial Z_k^2 }\Bigg /\frac{\partial R(X,Z)}{\partial Z_k }=\gamma _k. \end{aligned}$$
(b15)

Since the partial derivatives of R(XZ) are known, the relations above demonstrate that \(\beta _k \) and \(\gamma _k \) are identified for \(k>\) 0. It remains to show that the constant terms \(\beta _0 \) and \(\gamma _0 \) are identified. Note that we can write (b11) as

$$\begin{aligned} R(X,Z)+1= & {} (1+\exp (X\beta ))(1+\exp (Z\gamma ))\nonumber \\= & {} (1+g_1 (X)\exp \beta _0 )(1+g_2 (Z)\exp \gamma _0 ) \end{aligned}$$
(b16)

where \(g_1 \) and \(g_2 \) are known functions, due to the identification results above. Let \({X}'\) be in A and be different from X. Hence, we obtain that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{R(X,Z)+1}{R({X}',Z)+1}=\frac{1+g_1 (X)\exp \beta _0 }{1+g_1 ({X}')\exp \beta _0 } \end{aligned}$$
(b17)

which implies that

$$\begin{aligned} \left( {g_1 ({X}')\cdot \frac{R(X,Z)+1}{R({X}',Z)+1}-g_1 (X)} \right) \exp \beta _0 =1-\frac{R(X,Z)+1}{R({X}',Z)+1}. \end{aligned}$$
(b18)

Similarly, it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} \left( {g_2 ({Z}')\cdot \frac{R(X,Z)+1}{R(X,{Z}')+1}-g_2 (Z)} \right) \exp \gamma _0 =1-\frac{R(X,Z)+1}{R(X,{Z}')+1} \end{aligned}$$
(b19)

where \({Z}'\) is in A and is different from Z. Since by assumption \(\partial R(X,Z)/\partial X\ne 0\) and \(\partial R(X,Z)/\partial Z\ne 0\) the last two equations show that \(\beta _0 \) and \(\gamma _0 \) are identified (the equations only consist of known fuctions in the variables X and Z). Note that establishing that identification is possible in theory does not necessarily mean that it is always achieved in practice.

Appendix C: Sample selection, cumulative distribution of activities, health and psychological violence variables

Tables 9, 10, 11 and 12 show different statistics related to the data.

Table 9 Sample selection
Table 10 Cumulative distribution of the number of activities a woman participates in \(^\mathrm{a}\)
Table 11 Women who are healthy; not having health problems\(^\mathrm{a}\), 17,350 women
Table 12 Women who have been subjected to psychological violence by partner, 17,350 women

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Andreassen, L., Di Tommaso, M.L. Estimating capabilities with random scale models: women’s freedom of movement. Soc Choice Welf 50, 625–661 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-017-1099-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-017-1099-8

Navigation