Skip to main content
Log in

Peripheral diversity: transfers versus public goods

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper advances the hypothesis that in societies that suffer from ethnolinguistic center-periphery tension it is harder to agree on public goods than on transfers. After micro-founding a new peripheral diversity index, it puts forth a simple theory in which the cost of public goods increases with peripheral ethnolinguistic diversity and tax compliance decreases with overall ethnolinguistic diversity. It then empirically explores the relation between public goods provision, transfers, peripheral diversity and overall diversity. Consistent with the theory, we find that higher levels of peripheral diversity are associated with less provision of public goods, but more transfers, whereas higher levels of overall diversity have a negative association with transfers. Public goods and transfers are therefore substitutes in their reaction to a change in peripheral diversity.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, e.g., La Porta et al. (1999), Alesina et al. (2003), Desmet et al. (2009), and Desmet et al. (2012).

  2. We thus ignore the possible overlap between multiple dimensions of identity.

  3. There are of course cases where the dominant group does not correspond to the biggest group. Examples include the Tutsis during different periods of Rwandan history and the Afrikaners of South Africa before the end of Apartheid.

  4. This is similar to the resemblance function of Greenberg (1956).

  5. Assuming convexity, instead of concavity, would give us an index of polarization. We later return to this issue.

  6. Notice that Condition 3 requires concavity of the function \(f_{cp}(s_{0},\cdot ,\tau )\). Thus, this concavity, together with the other conditions, is sufficient to obtain that the solution to the maximization problem stated in the proposition is given by \(s_{k}^{*}\ge s_{l}^{*}\). However, concavity of \(f_{cp}(s_{0},\cdot ,\tau )\) is not a necessary condition to obtain the solution. For example, if the function \(f_{pc}(\cdot ,s_{k},\tau )\) is “sufficiently” concave, the function \(f_{cp}(s_{0},\cdot ,\tau )\) need not be concave.

  7. For a similar approach used to derive a variety of indices—Greenberg’s A index, Greenberg’s B index, Esteban and Ray’s (1994) polarization index, Reynal-Querol’s (2002) polarization index and a simple version of the peripheral index—see Desmet et al. (2009).

  8. As we will later argue, the price of the public good needs to be high enough. Since \({ PD}\) can be zero, this requires \(\eta >0\).

  9. Greenberg’s B-index can be derived from the same identification-alienation framework. See Desmet et al. (2009).

  10. Our results can be also extended to the case of a corner solution in which the tax rate is \(t=1.\)

  11. Since we assume that transfers are positive, the price of the public good \( { PD}+\eta \) has to be high enough to ensure \(r>0\).

  12. In many countries, especially in Africa and Asia, language coincides with ethnicity.

  13. The dfbeta measures for each variable how influential each observation is. Following Belsley et al. (1980), we drop observations with an absolute value of dfbeta on either Greenberg’s B-index or peripheral diversity greater than \(2/\sqrt{(\# \text {obs})}\).

References

  • Alesina A, Reich B (2015) Nation-building. Harvard University, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Devleeschauwer A, Easterly W, Kurlat S, Wacziarg R (2003) Fractionalization. J Econ Growth 8:155–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashraf Q, Galor O (2013) The ‘Out of Africa’ Hypothesis, Human Genetic Diversity, and Comparative Economic Development. Am Econ Rev 103:1–46

  • Belsley DA, Kuh E, Welsch RE (1980) Regression diagnostics. Wiley, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Desmet K, Ortuño-Ortín I, Weber S (2005) Peripheral diversity and redistribution. CEPR Discussion Paper 5112

  • Desmet K, Ortuño-Ortín I, Weber S (2009) Linguistic diversity and redistribution. J Eur Econ Assoc 7:1291–1318

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desmet K, Ortuño-Ortín I, Wacziarg R (2012) The political economy of linguistic cleavages. J Dev Econ 97:322–338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esteban J-M, Ray D (1994) On the measurement of polarization. Econometrica 62:819–851

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fearon JD (2003) Ethnic and cultural diversity by country. J Econ Growth 8:195–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon RG Jr (2005) Ethnologue: languages of the world, 15th edn. SIL International, Dallas

    Google Scholar 

  • Gray RD, Atkinson QD (2003) Language-tree divergence times support the anatolian theory of Indo-European origin. Nature 426:435–439

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg JH (1956) The measurement of linguistic diversity. Language 32:109–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney J, Lawson R, Hall J (2012) Economic freedom of the world: 2012 annual report. Fraser Institute, Vancouver

    Google Scholar 

  • La Porta R, Lopez de Silanes F, Shleifer A, Vishny R (1999) The quality of government. J Law Econ Organ 15:222–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta R, Lopez de Silanes F, Shleifer A (2008) The economic consequences of legal origins. J Econ Lit 46:285–332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reynal-Querol M (2002) Ethnicity, political systems, and civil wars. J Confl Resolut 46:29–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shannon CE (1949) The mathematical theory of communication. University of Illinois Press, Urbana

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber E (1979) Peasants into Frenchmen: modernization of rural France, 1870–1914. Chatto and Windus, London

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Klaus Desmet.

Additional information

We thank two anonymous referees for thoughtful comments. I. Ortuño-Ortín acknowledges the financial support of the Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation, Project ECO-2013-42710-P, and S. Weber wishes to acknowledge the support of the Ministry of Education and Science of the Russian Federation, Grant No. 14.U04.31.0002, administered through the NES CSDSI.

Appendices

Appendix A: Proof of Proposition 1

To simplify the notation we drop 0 from the subscripts and write \(\tau _{j}\) instead of \(\tau _{0j}\).

(1) First consider the case \(\tau _{k}=\tau _{l}=\tau \). We have to show that \(s_{k}^{*}\ge s_{l}^{*}.\) Suppose, to the contrary, that \( s_{k}^{*}<s_{l}^{*}.\) Let \(s^{\prime }\in {\mathcal {S}}_{kl}({\overline{s}})\) be such that \(s_{j}^{\prime }=s_{j}^{*}\) for all j \(\ne k\), j \( \ne l\) and \(s_{k}^{\prime }=s_{l}^{\prime }=x\equiv \) \(\frac{s_{k}^{*}+s_{l}^{*}}{2}\). Since \({ PA}(s^{\prime },T)<{ PA}(s^{*},T)\), it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} 2f_{pc}(s_{0},x,\tau )+2f_{cp}(s_{0},x,\tau )< & {} f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{k}^{*},\tau )+f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau )\nonumber \\&+\,f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{k}^{*},\tau )+f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau ). \end{aligned}$$
(14)

By Condition 3, functions \(f_{pc}(s_{0},.,\tau )\) and \(f_{cp}(s_{0},.,\tau )\) are concave, which implies

$$\begin{aligned} f_{pc}(s_{0},x,\tau )\ge \frac{1}{2}f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{k}^{*},\tau )+\frac{ 1}{2}f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau ) \end{aligned}$$
(15)

and

$$\begin{aligned} f_{cp}(s_{0},x,\tau )\ge \frac{1}{2}f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{k}^{*},\tau )+\frac{ 1}{2}f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau ). \end{aligned}$$
(16)

It is straightforward to verify that inequalities (14)–(16) can not hold simultaneously. Thus, we have that \( s_{k}^{*}\ge s_{l}^{*}.\) Notice that \(\tau _{l}=\tau _{k}\) implies \( s_{l}^{*}\ge s_{k}^{*}\) and \(s_{k}^{*}\ge s_{l}^{*}\) so that \(s_{k}^{*}=s_{l}^{*}.\)

(2) Now consider the case \(\tau _{k}>\tau _{l}.\) We shall show that \( s_{k}^{*}\ge s_{l}^{*}.\) Suppose, in negation, that \(s_{k}^{*}<s_{l}^{*}.\) Let \(T^{\prime }\in {\mathcal {T}}\), be such that \(\tau _{j}^{\prime }=\tau _{j}\) for all \(j\ne l\) and \(\tau _{l}^{\prime }=\tau _{k}.\) Notice that \(\tau _{j}^{\prime }>\tau _{l}\). Similarly to the previous examination, let \(s^{\prime }\in {\mathcal {S}}_{kl}({\overline{s}})\) be such that \(s_{j}^{\prime }=s_{j}^{*}\) for all j \(\ne k\), j \(\ne l\) and \(s_{k}^{\prime }=s_{l}^{\prime }=\) \(x\equiv \frac{s_{k}^{*}+s_{l}^{*}}{2}.\) We have

$$\begin{aligned} { PA}(s^{\prime },T)<{ PA}(s^{*},T). \end{aligned}$$
(17)

This implies that

$$\begin{aligned}&f_{pc}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k})+f_{pc}(s_{0},x,\tau _{l})+f_{cp}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k})+f_{cp}(s_{0},x,\tau _{l})\\&\quad <f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{k}^{*},\tau _{k})+f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{l})+f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{k}^{*},\tau _{k})+f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{l}),\nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(18)

which is equivalent to

$$\begin{aligned}&f_{pc}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k})-f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{k}^{*},\tau _{k})+f_{cp}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k})-f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{k}^{*},\tau _{k})\\&\quad <f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{l})-f_{pc}(s_{0},x,\tau _{l})+f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{l})-f_{cp}(s_{0},x,\tau _{l}).\nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(19)

The argument used in case 1 above yields

$$\begin{aligned} { PA}(s^{\prime },T^{\prime })>{ PA}(s^{*},T^{\prime }), \end{aligned}$$

which implies that

$$\begin{aligned}&f_{pc}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k})+f_{pc}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k})+f_{cp}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k})+f_{cp}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k}) \\&\quad >f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{k}^{*},\tau _{k})+f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{k})+f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{k}^{*},\tau _{k})+f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{k}).\nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(20)

By rearranging the terms we obtain

$$\begin{aligned}&f_{pc}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k})-f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{k}^{*},\tau _{k})+f_{cp}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k})-f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{k}^{*},\tau _{k})\\&\quad >f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{k})-f_{pc}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k})+f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{k})-f_{cp}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k}).\nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(21)

Inequalities (19) and (21) imply

$$\begin{aligned}&f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{k})-f_{pc}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k})+f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{k})-f_{cp}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k})\\&\quad <f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{l})-f_{pc}(s_{0},x,\tau _{l})+f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{l})-f_{cp}(s_{0},x,\tau _{l}).\nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(22)

Since \(s_{l}^{*}>x\) and \(\tau _{k}>\tau _{l}\), Condition 4 implies that

$$\begin{aligned} f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{k})-f_{pc}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k})> & {} f_{pc}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{l})-f_{pc}(s_{0},x,\tau _{l})\quad \hbox {and} \\ f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{k})-f_{cp}(s_{0},x,\tau _{k})> & {} f_{cp}(s_{0},s_{l}^{*},\tau _{l})-f_{cp}(s_{0},x,\tau _{l}),\nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(23)

and (23) and (21) do not hold simultaneously. Hence we conclude that \(s_{k}^{*}\ge s_{l}^{*}\).

Appendix B: Data sources and diversity indices

Absolute latitude The absolute value of the latitude of a country’s approximate geodesic centroid, as reported by the CIA World Factbook. Source: Ashraf and Galor (2013).

Child mortality Log of child mortality rate per 1000 live births, 1990–2010 average. Source: World Development Indicators, World Bank.

GDP per capita GDP per capita, constant 2005 US$, 1990–2010 average. Source: World Development Indicators, World Bank.

Illiteracy Percentage of people aged 15 and above who are illiterate, 1990–2010 average. Source: World Development Indicators, World Bank.

Improved sanitation Percentage of population with access to improved sanitation facilities, 1990–2010 average. Source: World Development Indicators, World Bank.

Legal origin Socialist, French, German or British legal origin Source: La Porta et al. (2008).

Language data Languages spoken in each country and language trees. Source: Ethnologue: Languages of the World, 15th Edition, SIL International, 2005.

Major religions Share of protestants, catholics and muslims in the population. Source: La Porta et al. (1999).

Measles immunization Percentage of children between the age of 12 and 23 months that have been immunized against measles, 1990–2010 average. Source: World Development Indicators, World Bank.

Population. Total population, 1990–2010 average. Source: World Development Indicators, World Bank.

Population above 65 Population ages 65 and above, % of total, 1990–2010 average. Source: World Development Indicators, World Bank.

School attainment. Log of 1 \(+\) average years of schooling of population aged 25 or above, 1990–2010 average. Source: Barro R. and J.W. Lee v. 1.3, 04/13.

Road density Road network density, km per 1000 inhabitants, 2001–2010 average. Source: World Development Indicators, World Bank.

Terrain roughness The degree of terrain roughness of a country, calculated using geospatial surface undulation data reported by the G-ECON project (Nordhaus 2006) at a 1-degree resolution. Source: Ashraf and Galor (2013).

Transfers Transfers and subsidies as percent of GDP: Average for 1990, 1995, 2000, 2005 and 2010. Source:Gwartney et al. (2012), Economic Freedom Dataset, Fraser Institute.

Table 10 Indices of linguistic diversity: Greenberg’s B-index and peripheral diversity

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Desmet, K., Ortuño-Ortín, I. & Weber, S. Peripheral diversity: transfers versus public goods. Soc Choice Welf 49, 787–823 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-016-1017-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-016-1017-5

Navigation