Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Upper bounds of inequality of opportunity: theory and evidence for Germany and the US

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Previous estimates of inequality of opportunity (IOp) are lower bounds because of the unobservability of the full set of endowed characteristics beyond the sphere of individual responsibility. Knowing the true size of unfair IOp, however, is important for the acceptance of (some) inequality and the design of redistributive policies as underestimating the true amount of IOp might lead to too little redistribution. This paper suggests a fixed effects estimator for IOp which can be interpreted as an upper bound. We illustrate our approach by comparing Germany and the US based on harmonized micro data. We find significant, sizeable and robust differences between lower and upper bound estimates—both for gross and net earnings based on either periodical or permanent income—for both countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See e.g. Roemer et al. (2003), Dardanoni et al. (2005), Betts and Roemer (2006), Lefranc et al. (2008, 2009), Devooght (2008), Checchi et al. (2010), Checchi and Peragine (2010), Dunnzlaff et al. (2011), Aaberge et al. (2011), Alms et al. (2011) as well as Björklund et al. (2012a).

  2. See, e.g., Katz and Autor (1999) for an overview as well as Autor et al. (2008) and Dustmann et al. (2009) for recent applications to the US and Germany.

  3. An exception is Bourguignon et al. (2007) who simulate the magnitude of omitted variable bias to estimate bounds around the true effect of observed circumstances on income inequality.

  4. There are a number of studies investigating social and economic mobility (see, e.g., Corak and Heisz 1999, Björklund and Jäntti 1997, 2009, Kerm 2004 or Björklund et al. 2012b). However, social or economic mobility is only a partial view on IOp, with only parental education or income level as circumstance variable. In addition, only few measures of social mobility can be directly related to IOp—see Van de gaer et al. (2001). On this, see also the evidence and discussion in Brunori et al. (2013).

  5. According to Alesina and Glaeser (2004), Americans believe that social mobility is important and high in the US, whereas Europeans perceive lower chances to climb the social ladder. Hence, Germans are more in favor of redistribution than Americans (Alesina and Angeletos 2005).

  6. We further discuss—and relax—this assumption in Sect. 5.3. See also Lefranc et al. (2009) for the extension of the EOp framework to explicitly take into account luck.

  7. In contrast, non-parametric methods avoid the arbitrary choice of a functional form on the relationship between outcome, circumstances and effort (e.g. Lefranc et al. 2009, Ferreira and Gignoux 2011 or Aaberge et al. 2011). However, this approach has the drawback that considering more than one circumstance variable is difficult due to practical reasons in the presence of small cell sizes which is usually the case in survey data. Access to large-scale administrative panel data with information on circumstances (family background), which is not available in Germany and rather restrictive in the US, would allow to estimate lower and upper bounds of IOp also non-parametrically.

  8. However, note that when looking at yearly regression of income on observed circumstances, individual coefficients may change but the explained variation does not change (much). In addition, we can usually not reject the null that the respective coefficients are statistically equal at the 5 %-level for any pair of years. These results suggest that neither the effect of (observed) circumstances on the outcome nor the unexplained variation varies a lot over time.

  9. We do this, because the variance of logarithms—in contrast to the MLD and other GE-measures—is not a good measure of inequality because it violates the Pigou–Dalton transfer principle as well as the Lorenz criterion (Foster and Ok 1999).

  10. In principle, it would be possible to provide two lower bounds with and without accounting for the indirect effects—as, e.g., done in Bourguignon et al. (2007).

  11. Note that the estimation of the unit-effect relies on the consistent estimation of coefficients in the FE model. Omitting any effort variables that interact with circumstances biases our results upwards, emphasizing that we should interpret our results as upper bounds of IOp.

  12. A detailed overview of the SOEP is provided by Haisken-DeNew and Frick (2003) and Wagner et al. (2007). Issues concerning sampling and weighting methods or the imputation of information in case of item or unit non-response is well documented by the SOEP Service Group.

  13. Note that the income reference period in both surveys is the year before the interview. Hence, we actually cover the period 1983 until 2008 for Germany and 1981 until 2006 for the US.

  14. Due to the log-linear specification it is not possible to include zero earnings. We decided to only include the longest spell (and not all employment spells) for each individual to focus on EOp in earnings and not to account for selection into and out of employment. It would be possible, and potentially interesting, to apply a two-stage approach by also investigating EOp in labor market participation. We leave this for further research.

  15. This is a rather arbitrary restriction. However, as our robustness checks show the number of time points does not qualitatively change the results. On average, we use 6.9 (7.2) years for Germany (the US).

  16. An even better proxy might be household equivalent disposable income. However, accounting for the household context raises other issues—which have not been addressed in the EOp literature—such as whether an individual is responsible for the choices of her spouse or not. In addition, using net earnings is equivalent to household income for singles and for couples in a collective household model with a sharing rule corresponding to the earnings ratio of the two spouses.

  17. In principle, it would be possible to compute more sophisticated measures of permanent income as, e.g., recently proposed by Aaberge et al. (2011). Comparing the results based on annual and permanent incomes is related to the literature looking at the transitory components to earnings variability (see, e.g., Moffitt and Gottschalk 2012). Looking at permanent incomes is interesting itself because of the possibility for individuals to smooth income shocks over time. In addition, it has the advantage that measurement error [e.g. around 20 % of the total variance according to validation studies of the PSID such as Rodgers et al. (1993)] gets averaged away.

  18. The ‘non-effect’ of race for periodical incomes might be explained with the fact that blacks are more likely to be out of the labor force or even in prison, which leads to underestimated racial wage gaps in cross-sectional data (Chandra 2000).

  19. For brevity, we do not report ‘first-stage’ results for approach (2), i.e. Eqs. (7)–(9), which are qualitatively similar to approach (1) and available upon request.

  20. It should be noted that the upper bounds of IOp decrease if we, e.g., add marital status or number of children, which can be expected to have an indirect impact on annual earnings, in the FE regressions. This provides additional evidence that our results can be interpreted as upper bounds.

  21. This approach is related to approaches estimating what share of inequality can be explained by observable effort variables (see, e.g., Pistolesi 2009). Usually, when measuring the contribution of observable effort, effort is purged from its correlation with observable circumstances. In our approach, effort is purged from both observable circumstances and the individual fixed-effect. Since some (time-invariant) effort possibly belongs to the fixed-effect, inequality due to effort (circumstances) is under(over)-estimated resulting in an upper bound for IOp.

  22. Alms (2008) argues that the ex-post approach treats the unexplained variation as a circumstance which would result in an upper bound. This, however, is only true for a given set of (observed) circumstances. The fact that the ex-post approach gives lower bounds only is also discussed by Aaberge and Colombino (2012). They recognize that for the (ex-post) EOp approach “[...] there might be other exogenous factors that affect individuals’ achievements” which are not captured by the observed circumstances. Hence, the within-type distribution of income might still depend on unobserved circumstances. Their solution (partially) accounts for the within-type inequality and yields an intermediate case with an IOp measure between the lower and the upper bound. Defining the upper bound as in our case (observed vs. unobserved circumstances), gives lower and upper bounds both for the ex-ante and ex-post approaches.

  23. In our application, we have more than 500 types for the lower bound approach. In order to apply the ex-post approach based on percentiles of the earnings distribution, we would need at least 100 observations per cell, i.e. in total more than 50,000 observations per year. Unfortunately, we do not have access to such a large panel data set.

  24. Contrary to Germany, the majority of respondents in the US thinks that larger income differences are necessary as incentives, while 40 % of the respondents think that the most important reason why people live in need is laziness—the numbers are only half as high in Germany.

References

  • Aaberge R, Colombino U (2012) Accounting for family background when designing optimal income taxes: a microeconometric simulation analysis. J Popul Econ 25(2):741–761

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aaberge R, Mogstad M, Peragine V (2011) Measuring long-term inequality of opportunity. J Public Econ 95(3–4):193–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Angeletos G-M (2005) Fairness and redistribution. Am Econ Rev 95(4):960–980

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Giuliano P (2011) Preferences for redistribution. In: Benhabib J, Jackson MO, Bisin A (eds) Handbook of social economics. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 93–132

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Glaeser E (2004) Fighting poverty in the US and Europe: a world of difference. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Alms I (2008) Equalizing income versus equalizing opportunity: a comparison of the United States and Germany. Res Econ Inequal 16:129–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alms I, Cappelen AW, Lind JT, Sørensen E, Tungodden B (2011) Measuring unfair (in)equality. J Public Econ 95(7–8):488–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altonji J, Blank R (1999) Race and gender in the labor market. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 3C. North-Holland Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 3143–3251

    Google Scholar 

  • Autor D, Katz L, Kearney M (2008) Trends in US wage inequality: revising the revisionists. Rev Econ Stat 90(2):300–323

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagger J, Christensen BJ, Mortensen DT (2010) Wage and productivity dispersion: labor quality or rent sharing? working paper

  • Betts J, Roemer J (2006) Equalizing opportunity for racial and socioeconomic groups in the United States through educational finance reform. In: Woessmann L, Peterson P (eds) Schools and the equal opportunity problem. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 209–238

    Google Scholar 

  • Björklund A, Jäntti M (1997) Intergenerational income mobility in Sweden compared to the United States. Am Econ Rev 87(5):1009–1018

    Google Scholar 

  • Björklund A, Jäntti M (2009) Intergenerational income mobility and the role of family background. In: Salverda W, Nolan B, Smeeding T (eds) Handbook of economic inequality. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 491–522

    Google Scholar 

  • Björklund A, Jäntti M, Lindquist MJ (2009) Family background and income during the rise of the welfare state: brother correlations in income for Swedish men born 1932–1968. J Public Econ 93(5–6):671–680

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Björklund A, Jäntti M, Roemer J (2012a) Equality of opportunity and the distribution of long-run income in Sweden. Soc Choice Welf 39(2–3):675–696

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Björklund A, Roine J, Waldenström D (2012) Intergenerational top income mobility in Sweden: capitalist dynasties in the land of equal opportunity? J Public Econ 96(5–6):474–484

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blackburn ML (2007) Estimating wage differentials without logarithms. Labour Econ 14(1):73–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon F, Ferreira FHG, Menéndez M (2007) Inequality of opportunity in Brazil. Rev Income Wealth 53(4):585–618

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunori P, Ferreira FHG, Peragine V (2013) Inequality of opportunity, income inequality and economic mobility: some international comparisons, IZA DP No. 7155

  • Chandra A (2000) Labor-market dropouts and the racial wage gap: 1940–1990. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 90(2):333–338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Checchi D, Peragine V (2010) Inequality of opportunity in Italy. J Econ Inequal 8(4):429–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Checchi D, Peragine V, Serlenga L. (2010) Fair and unfair income inequalities in Europe, IZA Discussion Paper No. 5025

  • Corak M, Heisz A (1999) The intergenerational earnings and income mobility of Canadian men: evidence from longitudinal income tax data. J Hum Resour 34(3):504–533

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dardanoni V, Fields GS, Roemer J, Sánchez-Puerta ML (2005) How demanding should equality of opportunity be, and how much have we achieved? In: Morgan S, Grusky D, Fields G (eds) Mobility and inequality: frontiers of research in sociology and economics. Stanford University Press, Stanford, pp 59–82

    Google Scholar 

  • Devooght K (2008) To each the same and to each his own: a proposal to measure responsibility-sensitive income inequality. Economica 75(298):280–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dolls M, Fuest C, Peichl A (2012) Automatic stabilizers and economic crisis: Us vs. Europe. J Public Econ 96(3):279–294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunnzlaff L, Neumann D, Niehues J, Peichl A (2011) Equality of opportunity and redistribution in Europe. Res Econ Inequal 19:99–129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dustmann C, Ludsteck J, Schönberg U (2009) Revisiting the German wage structure. Q J Econ 124(2):843–881

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferreira FHG, Gignoux J (2011) The measurement of inequality of opportunity: theory and an application to Latin America. Rev Income Wealth 57(4):622–657

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleurbaey M (1995) Three solutions for the compensation problem. J Econ Theory 65(2):505–521

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleurbaey M (2008) Fairness, responsibility, and welfare. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Fleurbaey M, Peragine V (2013) Ex ante versus ex post equality of opportunity. Economica 80(317):118–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fong C (2001) Social preferences, self-interest, and the demand for redistribution. J Public Econ 82(2):225–246

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster JE, Ok EA (1999) Lorenz dominance and the variance of logarithms. Econometrica 67(4):901–908

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster J, Shneyerov A (2000) Path independent inequality measures. J Econ Theory 91(2):199–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haisken-DeNew J, Frick J (2003) DTC: desktop compendium to the German socio-economic panel study (GSOEP). DIW

  • Hugget M, Ventura G, Yaron A (2011) Sources of lifetime inequality. Am Econ Rev 101(7):2923–2954

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz L, Autor D (1999) Changes in the wage structure and earnings inequality. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 3A. North-Holland Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1463–1558

    Google Scholar 

  • Krueger AB, Summers LH (1988) Efficiency wages and the inter-industry wage structure. Econometrica 56(2):259–294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lefranc A, Pistolesi N, Trannoy A (2008) Inequality of opportunities vs. inequality of outcomes: are Western societies all alike? Rev Income Wealth 54(4):513–546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lefranc A, Pistolesi N, Trannoy A (2009) Equality of opportunity and luck: definitions and testable conditions, with an application to income in France. J Public Econ 93(11–12):1189–1207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lillard LA, Weiss Y (1979) Components of variation in panel earnings data: American scientists, 1960–70. Econometrica 47(2):437–454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luongo P (2010) The implication of partial observability of circumstances on the measurement of EOp, mimeo. University of Bari, Bari

  • Magnac T, Pistolesi N, Roux S (2013) Post schooling human capital investments and the life cycle variance of earnings, IDEI Working Papers 765

  • Meghir C, Pistaferri L (2010) Earnings, consumption and lifecycle choices. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 4b. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 773–854

    Google Scholar 

  • Moffitt RA, Gottschalk P (2012) Trends in the transitory variance of male earnings: methods and evidence. J Hum Resour 47(1):204–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2011) Growing income inequality in OECD countries: what drives it and how can policy tackle it? OECD Forum on Tackling Inequality, Paris 2 May

  • Ooghe E, Peichl A (2011) Fair and efficient taxation under partial control: theory and evidence, CESifo Working Paper Series 3518

  • Piketty T (1995) Social mobility and redistributive politics. Q J Econ 110(3):551–584

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piketty T, Saez E (2007) How progressive is the US federal tax system? A historical and international perspective. J Econ Perspect 21(1):3–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pistolesi N (2009) Inequality of opportunity in the land of opportunities, 1968–2001. J Econ Inequal 7(4):411–433

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodgers W, Brown C, Duncan GJ (1993) Errors in survey reports of earnings. Hours worked and hourly wages. J Am Stat Assoc 88(424):1208–1218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roemer JE (1993) A pragmatic theory of responsibility for the egalitarian planer. Philos Public Aff 22(2):146–166

    Google Scholar 

  • Roemer JE (1998) Equality of opportunity. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Roemer JE, Aaberge R, Colombino U, Fritzell J, Jenkins SP, Marx I, Page M, Pommer E, Ruiz-Castillo J, Segundo MJS, Trans T, Wagner GG, Zubiri I (2003) To what extent do fiscal regimes equalize opportunities for income acquisition among citizens? J Public Econ 87(3–4):539–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schnabel K, Alfeld C, Eccles J, Köller O, Baumert J (2002) Parental influence on students’ educational choices in the U.S.A. and Germany: different ramifications—same effect? J Vocat Behav 60:178–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shorrocks A (1980) The class of additively decomposable inequality measures. Econometrica 48(3):613–625

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solon G (1999) Intergenerational mobility in the labor market. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 3A. North-Holland Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1761–1800

    Google Scholar 

  • Van de gaer D (1993) Equality of opportunity and investment in human capital. Working Paper, KU Leuven

  • Van de gaer D, Schokkaert E, Martinez M (2001) Three meanings of intergenerational mobility. Economica 68:519–537

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Kerm P (2004) What lies behind income mobility? Reranking and distributional change in Belgium, Western Germany and the USA. Economica 71(281):223–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner GG, Frick JR, Schupp J (2007) The German socio-economic panel (SOEP): scope, evolution and enhancements. Schmoller’s Jahrbuch J Appl Soc Sci Stud 127(1):139–169

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful for financial support by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft DFG (GRK1461 and PE1675). We would like to thank two anonymous referees, Marc Fleurbaey (the Editor), Rolf Aaberge, Ingvild Almås, Paolo Brunori, Koen Caminada, Koen Decanq, Philipp Doerrenberg, Dan Hamermesh, David Jaeger, Peter Kuhn, Dirk Neumann, Nico Pestel, Erwin Ooghe, Andrew Oswald, John Roemer, Sebastian Siegloch, Chris Taber, Alain Trannoy and Philippe Van Kerm as well as seminar and conference participants in Ann Arbor, Bonn, Canazei, Cologne, Marseille, Milan and Rome for helpful comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andreas Peichl.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 67 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Niehues, J., Peichl, A. Upper bounds of inequality of opportunity: theory and evidence for Germany and the US. Soc Choice Welf 43, 73–99 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-013-0770-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-013-0770-y

Keywords

Navigation