Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Technology, skill, and growth in a global economy

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Economic Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper develops an endogenous growth model based on a Roy-like assignment model in which heterogeneous workers endogenously sort into different technologies/tasks according to their comparative advantage. By modeling explicit distinction between worker skills and tasks as well as incorporating task-specific technologies, we analyze in depth the technology-skill-growth and offshoring-growth links that are absent in traditional models of endogenous growth. We show that offshoring increases domestic aggregate productivity, welfare and growth due to technology-upgrading mechanism.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Offshoring has been a focal point in political debates over the last decades: see, e.g., Blinder (2006) and Mankiw and Swagel (2006).

  2. Most papers in international trade literature using a Roy-like model have been focusing on wage inequality: see, e.g., recent works by Adao (2016) and Lee (2017). Recent literature of firm heterogeneity and international trade has also largely studied the skill premium: see, e.g., Yeaple (2005) and Burstein and Vogel (2017).

  3. See, e.g., Hsieh et al. (2013). They find that 15–20% of US growth in aggregate labor productivity over 1960 to 2008 can be explained by improved allocation of talent to occupations. See also Kambourov and Manovskii (2008) showing that occupational mobility in the USA has increased significantly since the late 1960s. Additionally, recent work by Davidson et al. (2014) provides a strong evidence that globalization improves the efficiency of the matching process in the labor market.

  4. Note that traditional models with homogeneous labor (one or two skill groups) are very limited to study the complex labor market changes—e.g., simultaneous sorting up and down of workers on the skill ladder. See, e.g., Cortes (2016); testing rigorously Jung and Mercenier’s (2014) theoretical model using US panel data, he provides clear evidence of a two-way task/occupational switching pattern of workers—i.e., workers of relatively high (low) skill within a task/occupation are more likely to switch to higher (lower) technology tasks/occupations.

  5. Though focusing on employment effect, Ottaviano et al. (2013) provide an evidence of positive productive effect of offshoring. In this paper, we highlight the positive productivity effect of offshoring induced by technology-upgrading mechanism.

  6. These pro-growth effects of openness become less confirmative in recent more sophisticated model setups. Peretto (2003) develops an endogenous growth model with global oligopolists performing in-house R&D, and analyzes the effects of economic integration among identical countries. He finds an ambiguous growth effects of an incremental tariff reduction due to a trade-off between homogenization effect—global number of firms falls so that the diversity of innovation paths falls—and rationalization effect—the surviving firms become larger and raise R&D spendings under tougher competition. Also, Baldwin and Robert-Nicoud (2008) incorporates heterogeneous firms à la Melitz in a series of endogenous growth models in the literature. He finds an ambiguous growth effects of trade due to a trade-off between \(\overline{\kappa }\)-channel effect—freer trade raises the expected knowledge sunk cost to operate driven by a selection effect à la Melitz—and \(p_{K}\)-channel effect—freer trade lowers the price of new knowledge (marginal cost of innovating). The balance of these two effects depends on the model specifications they consider. In this paper, we study the trade-off between two anti-growth effects (redistribution and displacement) and two pro-growth effects (technology-upgrading and South-employment) in a North–South offshoring context, and show the dominance of the two pro-growth effects.

  7. Though the context is different, Murphy et al. (1991) show also the importance of talent allocation for growth when occupations exhibit increasing returns to ability.

  8. In “Appendix A,” we provide quantitative results of changes in skill distribution (e.g., skill upgrading) which can be compared to the effects of a fall in offshoring costs. Earlier version of this paper studies also analytically the effects of changes in skill distribution.

  9. See e.g., Backus et al. (1992) and Jones (1995).

  10. See Jones (1999) for a review of such models.

  11. To ease notation, we drop the time index when no confusion can arise.

  12. h(i) and m(i) can be viewed as managerial inputs by white-collar (non-production) workers—such as marketing, finance, accounting, etc.—and production of intermediate material inputs by blue-collar (production) workers, respectively, which are not substitutable.

  13. In what follows, we use an asterisk to denote foreign (South) variables.

  14. To avoid explosion of labor productivity, we assume, as usual, convergence of \(\varphi _{j}(z)g(z)\) at the extremes: specifically, \(\lim \nolimits _{z \rightarrow 0}\varphi _{j}(z)g(z)=0\) and \(\lim \nolimits _{z\rightarrow \infty }\varphi _{j}(z)g(z)=0\), \(j\in \left\{ M,L,H\right\} \).

  15. Therefore, the most skilled workers with \(z\in \left( z_{2},\infty \right) \) in Eq. (11) include now MNs’ headquarter service workers in the manufacturing sector and knowledge developing workers in the innovation sector.

  16. For analytical tractability and also to focus on the home county (the North) effects, we abstract from labor market adjustments in the South assuming that there is a large enough cheap labor force in the South—i.e., exogenously given \(C_{M}^{*}\) with \(C_{M}^{*}<C_{M}\) and endogenous \( L^{*}\). Endogenizing \(C_{M}^{*}\) with fixed \(L^{*}\) would only mitigate the variations of skill thresholds \(z_{1}\) and \(z_{2}\) without affecting the main results of the paper as long as conditions (8) and (9) are satisfied (checked also by numerical simulations). \( C_{M}^{*}\) would also be interpreted to include any trade costs.

  17. For a graphical simplicity, here log-linear technologies are adopted. Any more general functional forms consistent with Eq. (10), however, could of course be adopted.

  18. The emergence of both firm types depends on the trade-off between fixed costs and marginal costs. If \(C_{M}^{*}\) and \(f_{O}\) are very low(/high) enough, then all firms will engage in offshoring(/domestic production). Whether both L- and H-tech firms appear in those cases or not would depend again on the relative size between \(C_{L}/C_{H}\) and \(f_{L}/f_{H}\): as an extreme case, e.g., if \(C_{L}=C_{H}\) while \(f_{L}<f_{H}\) (i.e., one technology with different fixed costs) then all firms will of course pay \( f_{L}\) for the same technology. Focusing on the technology-skill links in an offshoring and endogenous growth context, we assume for the remainder of the paper that Eq. (26) holds.

  19. Tobin’s q has been widely used in finance as a proxy for firm performance and for investment opportunities. In our framework where investment is the key to endogenous growth, Tobin’s \(q=1\) condition provides an intuitive and the simplest way to determine the steady-state level of real investment \( L_{I}\). See Baldwin and Forslid (2000) using this approach to analyze the growth effects of trade liberalization between two symmetric countries, and Baldwin and Robert-Nicoud (2008) for an extension incorporating heterogeneous firms.

  20. From Eqs. (13) and (31), Tobin’s q—the ratio of capital’s market value to its replacement cost—equals \(\frac{\pi }{\left( \rho +g\right) C_{H}a_{I}}\). Using Eqs. (14) and (29), we get then \( q=\frac{\lambda \left( E+E^{*}\right) }{\sigma \left( \rho +g\right) C_{H}}\). Finally, replacing E using Eq. (30) and \(E^{*}\) by \( \widetilde{W}^{*}\) from Eq. (22) leads to \(q=\frac{ \lambda \left( \widetilde{W}+\widetilde{W}^{*}-C_{H}L_{I}\right) }{ \left( \sigma -1\right) \left( \rho +g\right) C_{H}}\), which should be equal to one in steady state.

  21. Obviously, the model lacks transitional dynamics (jumps from one steady state to another) with our focus on the steady-state growth effects of policy and/or parameter changes. See Baldwin and Forslid (2000) proving, however, that there is a unique and interior steady-state value of \(L_{I}\) in this type of model, which assures that the model is always in steady state regardless of the transitional dynamics. The steady-state level of \( L_{I}\) is directly associated with steady-state thresholds \(z_{1}\) and \( z_{2} \) in our framework.

  22. Note, however, that South income rises too due to an increased offshoring \( L^{*}\). For brevity, our model abstains from modeling explicitly the labor market in the South. It is, however, straightforward to introduce the same technology-upgrading mechanism in the South by assuming two technologies: e.g., low-tech for primary sector and high-tech for manufacturing. Increased offshoring to the South will then induce the same process as in Fig. 5, leading to a rise in \(C_{M}^{*}\). Though such approach might be more appropriate to mention the South-industrialization effect, endogenizing \(C_{M}^{*}\) would only mitigate the adjustment of \( C_{M}^{{\prime }}\) (thus, the variation of \(z_{2}\)) without affecting the results qualitatively.

  23. At a given \(z_{3}\), a leftward shift of \(z_{2}\)—thus, inducing more domestic firms to adopt high-fixed-cost low-marginal-cost technology —increases capital demand and boosts real investment: a leftward shift of \( z_{3}\). The technology-upgrading effect in real term (represented by the shaded area of panel (b) in Fig. 5) then boosts further real investment.

  24. \(C_{M}^{*}\) can be interpreted to include any trade costs. Explicitly introducing iceberg transportation costs is straightforward but only complicates without adding insight; it only affects income levels in the South. For the same reason and simplicity, the model abstains also from introducing explicit trade costs for the final good shipping between North and South.

  25. A fall in \(C_{M}^{*}\) implies a slightly less direct mechanism. The price ratio \(p_{L}/p_{H}\) rises inducing demand substitutions away from the low-tech varieties. This boosts the size of aggregate multinational activities with identical qualitative effect on \(z_{1}\) and \(z_{2}\).

  26. This implies that the effective production possibility frontier (PPF) expands outwards for given endowments.

  27. The perfect worker mobility case with \(\kappa \rightarrow \infty \) in theirs would be equivalent to the one technology case in this paper where all workers are paid the same efficiency wage rate. By adding here different technologies, this paper has highlighted how offshoring-induced technology-skill reassignment would contribute even further to the positive welfare and growth implications.

  28. Earlier version of this paper analyzes and discusses also changes in skill distribution (skill upgrading and polarization), task-specific technological progress, as well as scale effects of growth in this framework.

  29. Since Gibrat (1931), the most commonly used functional form in applied research to approximate the distribution of income has been the log-normal function: see, e.g., Bourguignon (2003). Any other functional forms, however, could of course be adopted, which leads to the same qualitative results.

  30. It is difficult to get a guidance for offshoring fixed costs. But US Bureau of Economic Analysis reports that the total capital expenditure of foreign affiliates represents about 25% of the whole capital expenditure of US multinational companies. With roughly four affiliates on average, this implies approximately \(f_{H}=1.2\) and \(f_{O}=0.1\) in our model.

  31. In their estimation, Helpman et al. (2004) find that MNs have 15% productivity advantage over non-MN exporters.

  32. We calculate cumulative population share and income share at \(z_{1}\) and \( z_{2}\), respectively. We get then an approximate measure of Gini index by linear interpolations, and distributing capital incomes \(\pi K\) to H -workers. Since our approximate measure obviously underestimates the actual inequality level, we pick the level of OECD average of recent years rather than that of the USA. For the late 2000s, the USA had the fourth highest Gini index among all OECD countries.

  33. With these parameter values, the calibrated log-normal skill distribution exhibits a mean of 0.64, a variance of 0.41 and a skewness of 3.97, with \( z_{1}=0.70\) and \(z_{2}=1.55\).

  34. Our calibrated parameter values satisfy \(\rho -\frac{g}{\sigma -1}>0\) all over the simulations.

  35. The intertemporal real-wage implications for each worker group \(j\in \left\{ M,L,H\right\} \) are computed in the same way.

  36. Exogenous changes in skill distribution can be viewed as resulting from various policy changes (e.g., education, immigration, industry restructuring, trade, etc.).

  37. Without affecting the qualitative results, here we assume that the highest skilled workers are allocated to the innovation sector: \(L_{I}=\int _{ \overline{z}}^{\infty }\varphi _{H}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z\).

  38. Note that the first bracket of Eq. (46) equals to \(\widetilde{W} -C_{H}L_{I}\). In the same way, it can also be shown \(\left( \frac{\widetilde{ W}}{P_{C}}\right) /dz_{2}<0\), implying that a fall in \(f_{O}\) increases average real wage \(\frac{\widetilde{W}}{P_{C}}\) in the economy.

  39. Note that assuming only one technology leads both \(\alpha _{1}^{\prime }\left( z_{1}\right) \) and \(\alpha _{2}^{\prime }\left( z_{2}\right) \) to zero, so that \(\frac{dL_{I}}{dz_{2}}=\frac{\alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) +C_{M}}{\sigma \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}}\left[ \varphi _{M}(z_{1})g(z_{1})\right] \frac{dz_{1}}{dz_{2} }-\frac{\alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}}{\sigma \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}}\left[ \varphi _{H}(z_{2})g(z_{2})\right] \): the second term represents the expansion of high-tech activities, while the first term represents the induced contraction of low-tech activities. Offshoring then increases unambiguously domestic growth rate by exploring Southern labor (Lemma 1). Here, adding different higher technologies increases the growth rate even further due to domestic technology-upgrading effects (Lemma 2).

References

  • Adao, R.: Worker heterogeneity, wage inequality, and international trade: theory and evidence from brazil. Working Paper (2016)

  • Aghion, P., Howitt, P.: A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60, 323–351 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antràs, P., Garicano, L., Rossi-Hansberg, E.: Offshoring in a knowledge economy. Q. J. Econ. 121, 31–77 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antràs, P., Fort, T.C., Tintelnot, F.: The margins of global sourcing: theory and evidence from U.S. firms. Am. Econ. Rev. 107, 2514–2564 (2017)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arkolakis, C., Ramondo, N., Rodríguez-Clare, A., Yeaple, S.: Innovation and production in the global economy. NBER Working Paper 18972 (2017)

  • Backus, D.K., Kehoe, P.J., Kehoe, T.J.: In search of scale effects in trade and growth. J. Econ. Theory 58, 377–409 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R.E., Forslid, R.: Trade liberalisation and endogenous growth: a q-theory approach. J. Int. Econ. 50, 497–517 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R.: Globalisation: the great unbundling(s). Economic Council of Finland 20, 5–47 (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R.E., Robert-Nicoud, F.: Trade and growth with heterogeneous firms. J. Int. Econ. 74, 21–34 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, E., Willmann, G.: Trade, education, and the shrinking middle class. J. Int. Econ. 99, 263–278 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder, A.S.: Offshoring: the next industrial revolution? Foreign Aff. 85, 113–128 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon, F.: The growth elasticity of poverty reduction: explaining heterogeneity across countries and time periods. In: Eicher, T.S., Turnovsky, S.J. (eds.) Inequality and Growth: Theory and Policy Implications. MIT, Cambridge (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Branstetter, L., Saggi, K.: Intellectual property rights, foreign direct investment and industrial development. Econ. J. 121, 1161–1191 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burstein, A., Vogel, J.: International trade, technology, and the skill premium. J. Polit. Econ. 125, 1356–1412 (2017)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bustos, P.: Trade liberalization, exports, and technology upgrading: evidence on the impact of MERCOSUR on Argentinian firms. Am. Econ. Rev. 101, 304–340 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cortes, G.M.: Where have the middle-wage workers gone? A study of polarization using panel data. J. Labor Econ. 34, 63–105 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costinot, A., Vogel, J.: Matching and inequality in the world economy. J. Polit. Econ. 118, 747–786 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, C., Heyman, F., Matusz, S., Sjoholm, F., Zhu, S.C.: Globalization and imperfect labor market sorting. J. Int. Econ. 94, 177–194 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dinopoulos, E., Segerstrom, P.: Intellectual property rights, multinational firms and economic growth. J. Dev. Econ. 92, 13–27 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan, J.: Talent, geography, and offshore R&D. Working Paper (2017)

  • Gibrat, R.: Les Inégalité Economiques. Recueil Sirey, Paris (1931)

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M.: The distribution of talent and the pattern and consequences of international trade. J. Polit. Econ. 112, 209–239 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M., Helpman, E.: Quality ladders in the theory of growth. Rev. Econ. Stud. 58, 43–61 (1991a)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M., Helpman, E.: Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. MIT, Cambridge (1991b)

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M., Helpman, E.: Growth, trade, and inequality. Econometrica 86, 37–83 (2018)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M., Rossi-Hansberg, E.: Trading tasks: a simple theory of offshoring. Am. Econ. Rev. 98, 1978–1997 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M., Maggi, G.: Diversity and trade. Am. Econ. Rev. 90, 1255–1275 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E.: Innovation, imitation, and intellectual property rights. Econometrica 61, 1247–1280 (1993)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E., Melitz, M.J., Yeaple, S.R.: Export versus FDI with heterogeneous firms. Am. Econ. Rev. 94, 300–316 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E., Itskhoki, O., Redding, S.: Inequality and unemployment in a global economy. Econometrica 78, 1239–1283 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh, C.-T., Hurst, E., Jones, C.I., Klenow, P.J.: The allocation of talent and U.S. economic growth. NBER Working Paper 18693 (2013)

  • Jones, C.I.: Time series tests of endogenous growth models. Q. J. Econ. 110, 495–525 (1995)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, C.I.: Growth: With or without scale effects? Am. Econ. Rev. Pap. Proc. 89, 139–144 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jung, J., Mercenier, J.: Routinization-biased technical change and globalization: understanding labor market polarization. Econ. Inq. 52, 1446–1465 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kambourov, G., Manovskii, I.: Rising occupational and industry mobility in the United States: 1968–97. Int. Econ. Rev. 49, 41–79 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P.R.: Trade and wages, reconsidered. Brookings Pap. Econ. Act. 1, 103–137 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, E.: Trade, inequality, and the endogenous sorting of heterogeneous workers. Working Paper (2017)

  • Lucas, R.E.: On the mechanics of economic development. J. Monet. Econ. 22, 3–42 (1988)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, N.G., Swagel, P.: The politics and economics of offshore outsourcing. J. Monet. Econ. 53, 1027–1056 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markusen, J.: Multinational Firms and the Theory of International Trade. MIT, Cambridge (2002)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz, M.: The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71, 1695–1725 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K.M., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W.: The allocation of talent: implications for growth. Q. J. Econ. 106, 503–530 (1991)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naghavi, A., Ottaviano, G.: Offshoring and product innovation. Econ. Theory 38, 517–533 (2009a). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-007-0322-8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naghavi, A., Ottaviano, G.: Firm heterogeneity, contract enforcement, and the industry dynamics of offshoring. Scand. J. Econ. 111, 629–653 (2009b)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano, G.I.P., Peri, G., Wright, G.: Immigration, offshoring, and American jobs. Am. Econ. Rev. 103, 1925–1959 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peretto, P.F.: Endogenous market structure and the growth and welfare effects of economic integration. J. Int. Econ. 60, 177–201 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porzio, T.: Cross-country differences in the optimal allocation of talent and technology. Working Paper (2017)

  • Rivera-Batiz, L.A., Romer, P.M.: Economic integration and endogenous growth. Q. J. Econ. 106, 531–555 (1991a)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rivera-Batiz, L.A., Romer, P.M.: International trade with endogenous technological change. Eur. Econ. Rev. 35, 971–1001 (1991b)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P.M.: Endogenous technological change. J. Polit. Econ. 98, 71–102 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P.M.: Increasing returns and long-run growth. J. Polit. Econ. 94, 1002–1037 (1986)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roy, A.D.: Some thoughts on the distribution of earnings. Oxf. Econ. Pap. 3, 135–146 (1951)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sampson, T.: Dynamic selection: an idea flows theory of entry, trade, and growth. Q. J. Econ. 131, 315–380 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J.: A general equilibrium approach to monetary theory. J. Money Credit Bank 1, 15–29 (1969)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yeaple, S.R.: A simple model of firm heterogeneity, international trade, and wages. J. Int. Econ. 65, 1–20 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young, A.: Learning by doing and the dynamic effects of international trade. Q. J. Econ. 106, 369–405 (1991)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jaewon Jung.

Additional information

I am grateful to Jean Mercenier, Philippe Martin, Cristina Terra, Gerald Willmann, and Maurizio Zanardi for helpful comments and/or encouragements. I also thank Akihiko Yanase and participants at various conferences, workshops, and seminars, including among others the IPN Research Seminar, the APTS 2014 Seoul, the International Workshop on Regions, Firms, and FDI in Ghent, the fifth International Conference on Economics of Global Interactions in Bari, the DEGIT XIX Conference in Nashville, the LACEA-LAMES 2014 São Paulo, the EEA Mannheim 2015, the ASSA 2016 San Francisco, and the KERI seminar, etc., for their helpful comments and discussions on earlier version of this paper. I finally thank Costas Arkolakis, Co-Editor, and two anonymous referees for their insightful and constructive comments and suggestions that helped improve significantly the quality of the paper.

Appendices

Appendix A: Numerical illustration

1.1 A.1 The initial equilibrium

In this section we illustrate our theoretical discussions with numerical simulations. To do this, we first set the stage by characterizing the initial equilibrium roughly calibrated to US data. We assume a log-normal skill distributionFootnote 29 and linear technologies consistent with Eq. (10):

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{l} g(z)=\frac{1}{z\sqrt{2\pi }\varepsilon }\mathrm{e}^{-\frac{(\ln z-\mu )^{2}}{ 2\varepsilon ^{2}}},\ \ \ \ z\in (0,\infty ) \\ \varphi _{j}(z)=1+a_{j}z,\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ j\in \left\{ M,L,H\right\} . \end{array} \end{aligned}$$

Multinational firms do not, of course, offshore outsource all the intermediate components. To reflect more the reality, here we assume that high-tech multinationals use \(\beta \) share of foreign intermediate components and (\(1-\beta \)) share of domestic intermediate components. ILO provides us with unit labor costs (relative to the USA) in manufacturing for a number of cheap labor countries. From which we choose \(C_{M}^{*}=0.63\), approximately a value of Mexico at the end of 1980’ before NAFTA was signed. We set \(\rho =0.05\) for the discount rate and \(\sigma =4\) for the elasticity of substitution between varieties. Empirical evidence on the level of fixed costs is scarce, but it seems reasonable that the ratio of fixed costs for a vertically fragmented firm to those for a domestic firm lies between 1 and 2 (Markusen 2002); we choose the following relative fixed costs: \(f_{L}=1.0,\)\(f_{H}=1.2\) and \(f_{O}=0.1\).Footnote 30

Given these parameter values and functional forms, we calibrate other key parameter values—\(\mu \), \(\varepsilon \), \(a_{M}\), \(a_{L}\), \(a_{H}\), \( \lambda \) and \(\beta \)– by characterizing the initial equilibrium as follows.

(i):

M-workers represent 70% of the population. US Economic Census reports that the ratio of production workers to total employees in manufacturing is about 70%. From the cumulative distribution function (CDF) of log-normal distribution, we set: \(\frac{1}{2}+\frac{1}{2} \)erf\({\left( \frac{\ln z_{1}-\mu }{\sqrt{2}\varepsilon }\right) } =0.7;\)

(ii):

From the same source, we pick the non-production workers’ wage share in total value added from labor as: \(\frac{ C_{L}\int _{z_{1}}^{z_{2}}\varphi _{L}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z+C_{H}\int _{z_{2}}^{\infty }\varphi _{H}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z}{\widetilde{W}}=0.42;\)

(iii):

US Economic Census also reports industry statistics by employment size. We approximate MNs’ total output value share as that of establishments with 2,500 or more employees: \(\frac{p_{H}x_{H}N_{H}}{ p_{L}x_{L}N_{L}+p_{H}x_{H}N_{H}}=0.14;\)

(iv):

For productivity difference between MNs and non-MNs, we set: \(\frac{a_{H}}{a_{L}}=1.15;\)Footnote 31

(v):

For initial income inequality level, we choose: Gini index \(=0.32;\)Footnote 32

(vi):

For the initial growth rate we set \(g=0.03\), the average US real GDP growth rate between 1980 and 2006.

(vii):

Finally, Antràs et al. (2017) reports 14% for the average foreign-input share of US offshoring firms; we set: \(\frac{\beta C_{M}^{*}}{(1-\beta )C_{M}+\beta C_{M}^{*}+C_{H}} =0.14\).

The calibrated parameter values are: \(\mu =-0.80\), \(\varepsilon =0.83\), \( a_{M}=0.35\), \(a_{L}=1.98\), \(a_{H}=2.27\), \(\lambda =0.09\) and \(\beta =0.20\).Footnote 33

1.2 A.2 The effects of offshoring

Table 1 reports the effects of globalization: falls in \(f_{O}\) and \( C_{M}^{*}\), respectively, which confirms our theoretical analyses. Results are percentage change from the initial equilibrium.

Table 1 The effects of falls in \(f_{O}\) and \(C_{M}^{*}\)

Though both shocks provide the same qualitative results, it can be seen that the results are relatively more sensitive to a fall in \(C_{M}^{*}\). As can be seen from Eq. (27), a fall in \(C_{M}^{*}\) induces a direct price advantage of MNs vis-à-vis non-MNs, while a fall in \( f_{O} \) is mitigated from the power term of \(\frac{1}{1-\sigma }\) as is common in this type of monopolistic competition settings. Note also that offshoring increases not only \(L^{*}\) but also \(L^{eff}\) (\( =\int _{0}^{z_{1}}\varphi _{M}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z+\int _{z_{1}}^{z_{2}}\varphi _{L}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z+\int _{z_{2}}^{\infty }\varphi _{H}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z\)), total efficiency units of labor in the North, due to the technology-upgrading mechanisms.

1.3 A.3 Welfare effects

Table 2 reports then the induced percentage changes of welfare for each skill group.

Table 2 Welfare effects of falls in \(f_{O}\) and \(C_{M}^{*}\)

\(Welf_{Agg}\), \(Welf_{M}\), \(Welf_{L}\), and \(Welf_{H}\) measure real incomes \( \frac{E}{P_{C}}\), \(\frac{C_{M}}{P_{C}}\), \(\frac{C_{L}}{P_{C}}\), and \(\frac{ C_{H}}{P_{C}}\), respectively. As discussed in Sect. 4, offshoring leads to different welfare implications for each skill group. M-workers lose in terms of their real income due to an increase of \(P_{C}\), while H-workers would be the main beneficiary.

This welfare conclusion is of course incomplete since it does not take into account the dynamic gains to be reaped from growth. From Eqs. (12) and ( 28), a rise in growth rate implies an increase of total number of firms (varieties) at the same rate. This, in turn, implies from Eq. (5) that \(P_{C}\) falls over time at the rate of \(\frac{g}{\sigma -1}\). To evaluate the intertemporal welfare consequences, we compute the equivalent variation index \(\phi \) from the following utility indifference condition:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( 1+\phi \right) \int _{t=0}^{\infty }\mathrm{e}^{-\rho t}\ln \left( \frac{E\mathrm{e}^{\frac{g_{0}}{\sigma -1}}}{P_{C0}}\right) \mathrm{d}t=\int _{t=0}^{\infty }\mathrm{e}^{-\rho t}\ln \, \left( \frac{E\mathrm{e}^{\frac{g_{1} }{\sigma -1}}}{P_{C1}}\right) \mathrm{d}t, \end{aligned}$$
(44)

where subscripts 0 and 1 indicate before and after shocks, respectively.Footnote 34

\(\int _{t=0}^{\infty }\mathrm{e}^{-\rho t}\ln \left( \frac{E\mathrm{e}^{\frac{g_{0}}{ \sigma -1}}}{P_{C0}}\right) \mathrm{d}t\) represents the present value of total reference real consumption streams before the shock, while \( \int _{t=0}^{\infty }\mathrm{e}^{-\rho t}\ln \left( \frac{E\mathrm{e}^{\frac{g_{1}}{ \sigma -1}}}{P_{C1}}\right) \mathrm{d}t\) represents the corresponding value computed after the shock at \(t=0\). The welfare gain resulting from the shock is equivalent from the perspective of the households to increasing the reference real consumption profile by \(\phi \) percent. This is equivalent to the most frequently used welfare measure \(\left( 1+\phi \right) C_{0}=C_{1}\) in static applied general equilibrium analysis. In Table 2, ItWelfs report these computed values of \(\phi \).Footnote 35 As can be seen, the dynamic welfare gains are large enough to dominate any static losses.

Finally, Table 3 reports the effects of a rise in \(\mu \)—at a given \( \varepsilon \) and at a given mean by adjusting \(\varepsilon \), respectively.

Table 3 The effects of a rise in \(\mu \)

A rise in \(\mu \) at a given \(\varepsilon \) (skill upgrading) increases both \( Welf_{Agg}\) and \(ItWelf_{Agg}\) by increased high-tech activities on the right tail of the distribution. An increase in \(\mu \) raises the dispersion of worker skill heterogeneity and the average skill level rises in a monotonous way: i.e., less least skilled and more highest skilled.Footnote 36 Skill upgrading at a given population should be isomorphic to labor-augmenting technological progress, as in the case of offshoring with access to cheap labor. Both contribute to an aggregate productivity increase, and thus enhance growth.

On the other hand, keeping the mean following a rise in \(\mu \) implies a decrease in \(\varepsilon \), which results in a concentration of density relatively in the middle of the distribution. This favors non-MNs over MNs leading to decrease in aggregate productivity and growth rate; both \( Welf_{Agg}\) and \(ItWelf_{Agg}\) fall by decreased high-tech activities.

Appendix B: Proofs

1.1 B.1 Proof of Proposition 1

Totally differentiating Eqs. (16) and (27), and using Eq. (24), we get:

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ \begin{array}{cc} j_{11} &{} j_{12} \\ j_{21} &{} j_{22} \end{array} \right] \left[ \begin{array}{c} dz_{1} \\ dz_{2} \end{array} \right] =\left[ \begin{array}{c} 0 \\ 1 \end{array} \right] df_{O}, \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{l} j_{11}=\varphi _{M}(z_{1})g(z_{1})+\varphi _{L}(z_{1})g(z_{1}),\\ j_{12}=-\varphi _{L}(z_{2})g(z_{2}), \\ j_{21}=\left( \sigma -1\right) f_{L}\left( \frac{\alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) +C_{M}}{\alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}}\right) ^{\sigma -2}\frac{\alpha _{1}^{\prime }\left( z_{1}\right) \left[ C_{M}^{*}-\alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) C_{M}\right] }{\left[ \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}\right] ^{2}}, \\ j_{22}=\left( \sigma -1\right) f_{L}\left( \frac{\alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) +C_{M}}{\alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}}\right) ^{\sigma -2}\frac{-\alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}^{\prime }\left( z_{2}\right) \left[ \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) +C_{M}\right] }{\left[ \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}\right] ^{2}}. \end{array} \end{aligned}$$

The Jacobian determinant is:

$$\begin{aligned} \left| J\right|= & {} \left[ \varphi _{M}(z_{1})g(z_{1})+\varphi _{L}(z_{1})g(z_{1})\right] \\&\times \left[ \left( \sigma -1\right) f_{L}\left( \frac{ \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) +C_{M}}{\alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}}\right) ^{\sigma -2}\frac{-\alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}^{\prime }\left( z_{2}\right) \left[ \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) +C_{M}\right] }{\left[ \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}\right] ^{2}} \right] \\&+\,\varphi _{L}(z_{2})g(z_{2})\left[ \left( \sigma -1\right) f_{L}\left( \frac{\alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) +C_{M}}{\alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}} \right) ^{\sigma -2}\frac{\alpha _{1}^{\prime }\left( z_{1}\right) \left[ C_{M}^{*}-\alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) C_{M}\right] }{\left[ \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}\right] ^{2}}\right] . \end{aligned}$$

Note from Eqs. (9), (23), and (24),

$$\begin{aligned} C_{M}^{*}-\alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) C_{M}<0. \end{aligned}$$
(45)

From Eqs. (24) and (45), it follows then that: \( \left| J\right| >0.\)

Using Cramer’s rule, we now obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{l} \dfrac{dz_{1}}{df_{O}}=\frac{1}{\left| J\right| }\left[ \varphi _{L}(z_{2})g(z_{2})\right]>0,\\ \dfrac{dz_{2}}{df_{O}}=\frac{1}{\left| J\right| }\left[ \varphi _{M}(z_{1})g(z_{1})+\varphi _{L}(z_{1})g(z_{1})\right] >0. \end{array} \end{aligned}$$

1.2 B.2 Proof of Proposition 3

From (16), (17), (20), and (30) we have:Footnote 37

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\sigma -1}{\sigma }E= & {} \left[ \left( C_{M}+C_{L}\right) \int _{0}^{z_{1}}\varphi _{M}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z+C_{H}\int _{z_{2}}^{\overline{z} }\varphi _{H}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z\right] \nonumber \\&+\frac{C_{M}^{*}}{\sigma }\int _{z_{2}}^{ \overline{z}}\varphi _{H}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z. \end{aligned}$$
(46)

From (39), (41), and (46) we then get:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{l} \left( \frac{E}{P_{C}}\right) ^{\sigma -1} =\left[ \left( C_{M}+C_{L}\right) \int _{0}^{z_{1}}\varphi _{M}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z+\left( C_{H}+\frac{C_{M}^{*}}{\sigma }\right) \int _{z_{2}}^{\overline{z}}\varphi _{H}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z\right] ^{\sigma -1} \\ \quad \cdot \left[ \frac{C_{L}+C_{M}}{\left( \sigma -1\right) \pi f_{L}} \int _{0}^{z_{1}}\varphi _{M}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z\left( C_{L}+C_{M}\right) ^{1-\sigma }+ \frac{C_{H}+C_{M}^{*}}{\left( \sigma -1\right) \pi \left( f_{H}+f_{O}\right) }\int _{z_{2}}^{\overline{z}}\varphi _{H}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z\left( C_{H}+C_{M}^{*}\right) ^{1-\sigma }\right] . \end{array}\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(47)

Differentiating the RHS of this expression with respect to \(z_{2}\) (at a given growth rate), and making use of Eqs. (11), (27), and (37) yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{l} \frac{\mathrm{d}RHS(47)}{\mathrm{d}z_{2}}=\frac{1}{\pi f_{L}}\left( \frac{ \widetilde{E}}{C_{L}+C_{M}}\right) ^{\sigma -2} \\ \cdot \left[ \begin{array}{l} \left[ C_{L}^{^{\prime }}\int _{0}^{z_{1}}\varphi _{M}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z\frac{dz_{1}}{ dz_{2}}+C_{H}^{^{\prime }}\int _{z_{2}}^{\overline{z}}\varphi _{H}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z- \frac{C_{M}^{*}}{\sigma }\varphi _{H}(z_{2})g(z_{2})\right] \cdot \\ \left[ \int _{0}^{z_{1}}\varphi _{M}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z+\left( \frac{f_{L}}{f_{H}+f_{O}} \right) ^{\frac{1}{\sigma -1}}\int _{z_{2}}^{\overline{z}}\varphi _{H}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z\right] \\ +\left( \frac{\widetilde{E}}{C_{L}+C_{M}}\right) \left[ C_{L}^{^{\prime }}\int _{0}^{z_{1}}\varphi _{M}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z\frac{dz_{1}}{dz_{2}}+C_{H}^{^{\prime }}\int _{z_{2}}^{\overline{z}}\varphi _{H}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z-\left( \sigma -1\right) C_{M}^{*}\varphi _{H}(z_{2})g(z_{2})\right] \end{array} \right] \end{array} \end{aligned}$$

where \(\widetilde{E}=\frac{\sigma -1}{\sigma }E\), and \(C_{L}^{^{\prime }}\) and \(C_{H}^{^{\prime }}\) represent derivatives with respect to \(z_{1}\) and \( z_{2}\). From (24) and (37), this expression is unambiguously negative.Footnote 38

1.3 B.3 Proof of Proposition 5

Totally differentiating Eq. (43), we get:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{l} \dfrac{\mathrm{d}L_{I}}{\mathrm{d}z_{2}}=\left[ \begin{array}{l} \dfrac{\alpha _{1}^{\prime }\left( z_{1}\right) \left[ C_{M}^{*}-\sigma \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) C_{M}\right] }{\left[ \sigma \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}\right] ^{2}}\int _{0}^{z_{1}}\varphi _{M}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z+\dfrac{\left( 1-\sigma \right) \alpha _{1}^{\prime }\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) C_{M}^{*}}{\left[ \sigma \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}\right] ^{2}}\int _{z_{2}}^{\infty }\varphi _{H}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z \\ -\dfrac{\rho \left( \sigma -1\right) \alpha _{1}^{\prime }\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) C_{M}^{*}}{\lambda ^{2}\left[ \sigma \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*} \right] ^{2}}+\dfrac{\alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) +C_{M}}{\sigma \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}}\left[ \varphi _{M}(z_{1})g(z_{1})\right] \end{array} \right] \frac{dz_{1}}{dz_{2}}\\ \qquad \qquad +\left[ \begin{array}{l} \dfrac{-\sigma \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}^{\prime }\left( z_{2}\right) \left[ \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) +C_{M}\right] }{\left[ \sigma \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}\right] ^{2}}\int _{0}^{z_{1}}\varphi _{M}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z+\dfrac{ \left( 1-\sigma \right) \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}^{\prime }\left( z_{2}\right) C_{M}^{*}}{\left[ \sigma \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}\right] ^{2}} \int _{z_{2}}^{\infty }\varphi _{H}(z)g(z)\mathrm{d}z \\ -\dfrac{\rho \left( \sigma -1\right) \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}^{\prime }\left( z_{2}\right) C_{M}^{*}}{\lambda ^{2}\left[ \sigma \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*} \right] ^{2}}-\dfrac{\alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}}{\sigma \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}}\left[ \varphi _{H}(z_{2})g(z_{2}) \right] \end{array} \right] . \end{array}\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(48)

Given that all the other terms are based on second-order price adjustments \( \alpha _{1}^{\prime }\left( z_{1}\right) \) and \(\alpha _{2}^{\prime }\left( z_{2}\right) \), we compare the only two sizable terms: i.e., the last terms in each bracket. From Eqs. (23), (24) and (37 ), we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) +C_{M}}{\sigma \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}}\left[ \varphi _{M}(z_{1})g(z_{1})\right] \frac{\varphi _{L}(z_{2})g(z_{2})}{\varphi _{M}(z_{1})g(z_{1})+\varphi _{L}(z_{1})g(z_{1})} \\&\quad -\frac{\alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}}{\sigma \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}}\left[ \varphi _{H}(z_{2})g(z_{2})\right] =-\frac{C_{M}^{*}\varphi _{H}(z_{2})g(z_{2})}{\sigma \alpha _{1}\left( z_{1}\right) \alpha _{2}\left( z_{2}\right) +C_{M}^{*}}<0. \end{aligned}$$

It can be thus believed that \(\frac{dL_{I}}{dz_{2}}<0\), implying \(\frac{ dL_{I}}{df_{O}}<0\) from Proposition 1.Footnote 39

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Jung, J. Technology, skill, and growth in a global economy. Econ Theory 68, 609–641 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-018-1136-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-018-1136-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation