Abstract
A great number of theories have been offered as to the root of the difference between modern and premodern mentalities. One neglected account comes from Georg Simmel’s The Philosophy of Money, which argues that the rise of the mass money economy in the early modern era encouraged calculative modes of thought, and took over the coordinating functions of a number of previously important institutions such as kin and religious networks, thus “freeing” the latter to evolve without strong material feedback. This paper considers monetary exchange and kin/religious networks as alternative strategies for coordinating the division of labor, and shows how the widespread availability of the former can alter the cultural-evolutionary constraints on the latter. This dynamic explains a number of salient differences between modern and premodern moral life such as money’s profaning character, as well as the sociological significance of modern moral phenomena like individualism, rationalism, and fundamentalism.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.
Data availability
Data sharing not applicable to this article as no datasets were generated or analyzed during the current study.
Notes
The personalistic societies of the following section, for example, do not necessarily correspond to paleolithic societies, which likely varied widely in scale, complexity (Singh & Glowacki 2022), and the potential for ad hoc large-scale cooperation (Boyd & Richerson 2022). Nevertheless, any stage of supra-personalistic social complexity presumably follows a period of lower complexity at some point in the past, implying a solution of the problems raised in this paper. Regress, of course, is also possible following the loss of a coordinating technology (e.g., Harwick 2018).
Examples of rational reconstructions of social phenomena that self-consciously do not follow historical development include Menger (1892), Buchanan and Tullock (1962), Rawls (1971). There is of course the opposite danger of historical overfitting; a “just-so story”. Rooting the elements of our story as firmly as possible in orthodox economic theory will be important to guard against this danger.
The division of labor between cells within a multicellular body is also governed by phenotypic divisions between cell types, with considerably more complexity than between organism types of a species: Kaufmann (1993: 461) estimates the human body has up to 300 distinct cell types, with more types requiring exponentially longer genomes.
For more on why parables of goods-exchange emerging out of anarchy do not work, see Harwick (2023a).
Harwick (2020) defines the Incentive Gap as “the impossibility in broad classes of social dilemmas of eliminating the incentive to defect among some subset of agents, whose defection would eventually lead to the total unraveling of cooperation.”
Evolutionary stability is a closely related refinement of Nash equilibrium where strategies are selected at the population level through differential reproduction, rather than by individuals through rational choice. While evolutionary stability is usually thought of as a narrower concept than Nash equilibrium (e.g., it will exclude “knife-edge” equilibria that are not robust to random noise), selection between groups can generate evolutionarily stable strategies which are not Nash equilibria for the individuals in those groups. See Okasha (2006) for a detailed defense of the meaningfulness of “"selection between groups” and the conditions under which it would apply.
Because at this point we are interested in the evolution of basic cultural capacity rather than the evolution of specific cultural forms, several of Henrich & Muthukrishna’s proposed avenues of intergroup competition – prestige-based copying and differential migration – are not applicable, and may even hinder the evolution of basic cultural capacity to the extent they reduce genetic assortativity. Differential survival and differential reproduction of groups, however – even without direct conflict – will suffice.
The importance of metering benefits in the heuristics used to build up social exchange strategies is emphasized by Cosmides et al. (2010) in both dyadic and n-person exchange.
This can operationalize the complementarity between social ties and production in Kerr and Mandorff’s (2021) model of ethnic specialization.
Greif (2006) notes that as it becomes more difficult for groups to exclude nonmembers from the use of their visible markers, the effectiveness of inter-group trade and specialization declines, which can either lead to a breakdown of exchange, or the development of centralized enforcement institutions and territorial law.
Interestingly, a reorganization of sartorial laws was a key piece of Sultan Mahmud II’s attempted rebalancing of Ottoman interest groups in 1829, particularly the establishment of distinctive dress for the administrative class (Quataert 1997).
Why the Reformation succeeded where previous aniconic movements had failed, will be suggested in the following sections.
Simmel (1907: 249) does discuss disordered attitudes to money as an end in itself, namely the miser (who values the holding of money for its own sake) and the spendthrift (who values the spending of money for its own sake), but these are marginal cases.
Interestingly, the prior use of money by mercantile classes does seem to have taken place mostly in settings where overarching inter-group enforcement mechanisms had evolved. See e.g., Milgrom et al (1990) on the medieval Law Merchant.
This cannot, of course, be taken for granted, as the previous section shows. Nevertheless, the origin of this kind of enforcement (on which see Harwick and Root 2020) is outside the scope of this paper: here we are more interested in its effects than its causes.
Particularly severe information asymmetries may still make a division of labor along group lines efficient even today, especially where state enforcement is unwieldy, unreliable, or unwanted (e.g., Richman 2006). It should be noted however that one vital function of money is to eliminate information asymmetries on at least one side of the transaction (Alchian 1977).
Though not on everyone, particularly in the enforcing group, which must still organize collective action for enforcement of property claims upon subsidiary groups.
To the extent that moralizing religions (as opposed to the pure costly signal rituals of Section 1) are an expression of rationalization in the Simmel/Weber sense, Baumard et al. (2015) suggests that economic affluence (corresponding to monetization) is the direct causal factor as opposed to political complexity or state capacity. The present paper fills in “the proximate mechanisms by which affluence leads to the emergence of new kinds of religions.”
References
Aktor Mikael (2018) Impurity and purification. In: Olivelle Patrick, Davis Donald (eds) Hindu Law: A New History of Dharmaśāstra. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Alchian Armen (1977) Why money? J Money Credit Bank 9(1):133–140
Alger Ingela, Weibull Jörgen (2013) Homo moralis: preference evolution under incomplete information and assortative matching. Econometrica 81(6):2269–2302
Armstrong WE (1924) Rossel Island money. Econ J 34(135):423–429
Bandy MS (2004) Fissioning scalar stress and social evolution in early village societies. Am Anthropol 106(2):322–333. https://doi.org/10.1525/aa.2004.106.2.322
Baumard Nicolas, Hyafil Alexandre, Morris Ian, Boyer Pascal (2015) Increased affluence explains the emergence of ascetic wisdoms and moralizing religions. Curr Biol 25(1):10–15
Baumard Nicolas, Huillery Elise, Hyafil Alexandre, Safra Lou (2022) The cultural evolution of love in literary history. Nat Human Behav 6:506–522
Bloch Maurice (1989) The Symbolism of Money in Imerina. In: Bloch M, Parry J (eds) Money and the Morality of Exchange. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Bó, E, Hernández P, Mazzuca, S (2021) The Paradox of Civilization: Pre-Institutional sources of security and prosperity. Am Polit Sci Rev 116(1):213–230.
Bohannan Paul (1955) Some principles of exchange and investment among the tiv. Am Anthropol 57(1):60–70
Bowles Samuel, Gintis Herbert (2011) A Cooperative Species: Human Reciprocity and its Evolution. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Boyd Robert, Richerson Peter J (2022) Large-scale cooperation in small-scale foraging societies. Evol Anthropol 31:175–198
Buchanan James, Tullock Gordon (1962) The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor
Caton J (2023) Usury in late medieval and early modern England: Distinguishing between cultural and regulatory arbitrage. Working paper
Choi Jung-Kyoo, Bowles Samuel (2007) The coevolution of parochial altruism and war. Science 318(5850):636–640
Cosmides Leda, Barrett H Clark, Tooby J (2010) Adaptive specializations, social exchange, and the evolution of human intelligence. Proc Natl Acad Sci 107(Suppl. 2):9007–9014
Falk A, Hermle J (2018) “Relationship of gender differences in preferences to economic development and gender equality. Science, 362(6412)
Fehr Ernst, Gächter Simon (2000) Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. Am Econ Rev 90(4):980–994
François Anexandre (2009) The languages of vanikoro: three lexicons and one grammar. In: Evans Bethwyn (ed) Discovering History Through Language: Papers in Honour of Malcolm Ross. Australian National University, Canberra, pp 103–126
Gilmore David (1991) Manhood in the Making: Cultural Concepts of Masculinity. Yale University Press, New Haven
Greif Avner (1993) Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade. Am Econ Rev 83(3):525–48
Greif Avner (2000) The fundamental problem of exchange: a research agenda in historical institutional analysis. Eur Rev Econ Hist 4:251–284
Greif Avner (2006) The birth of impersonal exchange: The community responsibility system and impartial justice. J Econ Perspect 20(2):221–236
Gullbekk Svein (2019) Money and its Interpretation: Attitudes to Money in the Societas Chriastiana. In: Naismith Rory (ed) A Cultural History of Money in the Medieval Age. Bloomsbury, London
Harwick Cameron (2018) Money and its institutional substitutes. J Inst Econ 14(4):689–714
Harwick Cameron (2020) Inside and outside perspectives on institutions: an economic theory of the Noble lie. J Contextual Econ 140(1):3–29
Harwick Cameron (2022) Signals and Incentives in Blockchain Applications. In: Caton James (ed) Edward Elgar Handbook of Blockchains and Cryptocurrencies. Edward Elgar, Northampton, MA
Harwick Cameron, Root Hilton (2020) The feudal origins of the Western legal tradition. Jahrbuch für die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft (Ordo) 70(1):3–20
Harwick C, Kelly M (2023) The Inevitability of Incompleteness. Working paper
Harwick C (2023a). “Why I Am Not A Contractarian. Working Paper
Harwick C (2023b) Cities in the Rise and Decline of Civilizations. Working paper
Henrich Joseph (2020) The WEIRDest People in the World: How the West Became Psychologically Peculiar and Particularly Prosperous. Farrar, Straus, & Giroux, New York
Henrich Joseph, Muthukrishna Michael (2021) The origins and psychology of human cooperation. Ann Rev Psychol 72:207–240
Henrich Joseph, Heine Steven, Norenzayan Ara (2010) The weirdest people in the world? Behav Brain Sci 33:61–135
Hooper PL, Demps K, Gurven M, Gerkey D, Kaplan HS (2015) Skills, division of labour and economies of scale among amazonian hunters and south indian honey collectors. Philos Trans R Soc Lond B Biol Sci 370(1683):20150008. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2015.0008
Iannaccone Laurence R (1992) Sacrifice and stigma: reducing free-riding in cults, communes, and other collectives. J Polit Econ 100(2):271–291
Johnson Noel D, Koyama Mark (2019) Persecution and Toleration: The Long Road to Religious Freedom. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Kauffman SA (1993) The Origins of Order: Self-Organization and Selection in Evolution. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Keane Webb (2002) Sincerity, ‘modernity’, and the protestants. Cult Anthropol 17(1):65–92
Kerr W, Mandorff M (2021) Social networks, ethnicity, and entrepreneurship. J Human Resources forthcoming
Kocherlakota Narayana (1998) Money is memory. J Econ Theory 81:232–251
Lukaszewski AW, Gurven M, von Rueden CR, Schmitt DP (2017) What explains personality covariation? a test of the socioecological complexity hypothesis. Soc Psychol Personal Sci 8(8):943–952
Luria AR (1979) The Making of Mind: A Personal Account of Soviet Psychology. Harvard University Press, Cambridge
Mann M (1984) The autonomous power of the state: its origins mechanisms and results. Eur J Sociol 25(2):185–213. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003975600004239
Marwick Ben (2003) Pleistocene exchange networks as evidence for the evolution of language. Camb Archaeol J 13(1):67–81
Maurer B (2006) The anthropology of money. Annu Rev Anthropol 35:15–36
McElreath Richard, Boyd Robert, Richerson Peter (2003) Shared norms and the evolution of ethnic markers. Curr Anthropol 44(1):122–129
Mendenhall George E (1955) Law and Covenant in Israel and the Ancient Near East”. Biblical Archaeol 17(2):26–44 and 17(3): 49–76
Menger C (1892) On the Origins of Money. Econ J 2:239–255
Milgrom Paul R, North Douglass Cecil, Weingast Barry R (1990) The role of institutions in the revival of trade. Econ Polit 2(1):1–23
Munro John H (2003) The medieval origins of the financial revolution: usury, rentes, and negotiability. Int Hist Rev 25(3):505–562
Muthukrishna Michael, Henrich Joseph (2021) Psychology as a historical science. Annu Rev Psychol 72:717–749
Muthukrishna M, Bell AV, Henrich J, Curtin CM, Gedranovich A, McInerney J, Thue B (2020) Beyond Western, Educated, Industrial, Rich, and Democratic (WEIRD) Psychology: measuring and mapping scales of cultural and psychological distance. Psychol Sci 31(6):678–701
Norgaard J, Harwick Cameron (2022) The bumblebee effect: Monopolization and illicit drug markets. Working paper
North Douglass, Wallis John Joseph, Weingast Barry R (2009) Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Okasha Samir (2006) Evolution and the Levels of Selection. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Putnam R. (2000) Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. Simon & Schuster: New York
Quataert Donald (1997) Clothing Laws, state, and Society in the Ottoman Empire, 1720–1829. Int J Middle East Stud 29(3):403–425
Rappaport Roy A (1971) The sacred in human evolution. Annu Rev Ecol Syst 2:23–44
Rawls John (1971) A Theory of Justice. Harvard University Press, Cambridge
Richman Barak (2006) How community institutions create economic advantage: jewish diamond merchants in New York. Law Soc Inq 31(2):383–420
Simmel Georg (1907) The Philosophy of Money. Routledge, New York
Singh Manvir, Glowacki Luke (2022) Human social organization during the Late Pleistocene. Evol Human Behav 43(5):418–431
Skarbek David (2014) The Social Order of the Underworld: How Prison Gangs Govern the American Penal System. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Smith Adam (1776) An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. W. Strahan & T. Cadell, London
Sober E, Wilson DS (1998) Unto Others: The Evolution and Psychology of Unselfish Behavior. Harvard University Press, Cambridge
Sperber Dan (1975) (Alice Morton, trans.) Rethinking Symbolism. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Weber Max (1956) Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology. University of California Press, Berkeley
Whitehouse Harvey, François Pieter, Savage Patrick E, Hoyer Daniel, Feeney Kevin C, Cioni Enrico, Purcell Rosalind et al (2022) Testing the big gods hypothesis with global historical data: a review and ‘retake.’ Relig Brain Behav 13(2):124–166
Yamagishi Toshio (1986) The provision of a sanctioning system as a public good. J Personal Soc Psychol 51(1):110–116
Funding
No funding was received to assist with the preparation of this manuscript.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Ethics declarations
Competing interests
The author has no relevant financial or non-financial interests to disclose.
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Rights and permissions
Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.
About this article
Cite this article
Harwick, C. Money’s mutation of the modern moral mind: The Simmel hypothesis and the cultural evolution of WEIRDness. J Evol Econ (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-023-00844-4
Accepted:
Published:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-023-00844-4