Skip to main content

Public policies for household recycling when reputation matters

Abstract

An important strand in the economic literature focuses on how to provide the right incentives for households to recycle their waste. A growing number of studies, inspired by psychology, seek to explain waste sorting and pro-environmental behavior, and highlight the importance of social approval and the peer effect. The present theoretical work explores these issues. We propose a model that considers heterogeneous households that choose to recycle, based on three main household characteristics: their environmental preferences, the opportunity costs of their tax expenditures, and their reputations. The model is original in depicting the interactions among households, which enable them to form beliefs about social recycling norms, allowing them to assess their reputation. These interactions are explored through Agent-based simulations. We highlight how individual recycling decisions depend on these interactions and how the effectiveness of public policies related to recycling are affected by a crowding-out effect. The model simulations consider three complementary policies: provision of incentives to recycle through taxation; provision of information on the importance of selective sorting; and an ‘individualized’ approach that takes the form of a ‘nudge’ using social comparison. Interestingly, the results regarding these policies emerging from households interactions at the aggregate level cannot be fully predicted from “isolated” individual recycling decisions.

This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Notes

  1. Households’ behaviors impact on the environment and the importance of household choices are also stressed in OECD (2014).

  2. For instance, in the study by Brekke et al. (2003), individuals are able to state their ideal pro-social behavior.

  3. ABM is particularly appropriate to study complexity, heterogeneity, evolving norms (or institutional environment), etc. In the evolutionary literature, ABM allows new perspectives on financial (Leal et al. 2016; Veryzhenko et al. 2017) and macroeconomic issues (Dosi et al. 2015; Haldane and Turrell 2018).

  4. See the discussion in the introduction.

  5. In the model simulation presented in Section 4, we suppose that \({v_{i}^{a}}\), \({v_{i}^{t}}\), and ci are normally distributed.

  6. Note that introducing this externality in our model would not change qualitatively our analytical results (Section 3), nor our simulations results (Section 4).

  7. As in Fullerton and Kinnaman (1995), for example.

  8. This functional form implies that the environmental value is increasing at a decreasing rate in the information η and reaches its maximum level “1” when η = 1.

  9. See Croson and Treich (2014) for a presentation of this kind of nudges in the field of environmental preservation. Another important type of “green nudges” consists in providing green default option. See Sunstein and Reisch (2013).

  10. This allows us to explore the idea of Thaler and Sunstein (2008) according to which “If choice architects want to shift behavior and to do so with a nudge, they might simply inform people about what other people are doing”.

  11. Schultz (1999) shows that this type of nudge resulted in an increase in the volume of recycled waste that persisted over time, even after the experiment stopped.

  12. This nudge might deliver biased information since only the best household recycling rates observed are communicated (the top 50% of the observed recycling rates). This nudge might cause the household to overestimate the mean of others’ recycling rates. Therefore, the risk of failing to comply with “consumer sovereignty”, the nudges’ major drawback, is a serious issue for this kind of nudge.

  13. As in Bénabou and Tirole (2006).

  14. This duration ensures that the socialization process and the recycling decisions are stable.

  15. In the model simulation, a tolerance threshold of ± 3% is introduced.

  16. The values used for the means and standard deviations of each parameter are presented in Table (2) in Appendix B.

  17. Simulation results for the configuration corresponding to \(\bar {v}^{t}(=0.3)<\bar {v}^{a}(=0.7)\) are presented in online supplementary materials.

  18. This result is confirmed in the other situation where \(\bar {v}^{t}<\bar {v}^{a}\) depicted in figures provided in online supplementary materials.

  19. These results are confirmed in the other configuration (where \(\bar {v}^{a} >\bar {v}^{t}\)) in online supplementary materials

  20. We have \(\partial r(a_{i}^{*}(t))/\partial t = -(\gamma _{i} x_{i} (1 + {v_{i}^{t}}))/(c_{i} + \gamma _{i} x_{i})\).

  21. 75% may appear a quite high threshold; however, this value ensures that the nudge reinforces tax and information delivery policies, reactivating an almost stable socialization process.

References

  • Abbott A, Nandeibam S, O’Shea L (2013) Recycling: Social norms and warm-glow revisited. Ecol Econ 90:10–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Ajzen I, Fishbein M (1980) Understanding attitudes and predicting socia behaviour. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs

    Google Scholar 

  • Alpízar F, Gsottbauer E (2015) Reputation and household recycling practices: Field experiments in costa rica. Ecol Econ 120:366–375

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersson M, von Borgstede C (2010) Differentiation of determinants of low-cost and high-cost recycling. J Environ Psychol 30(4):402–408

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni J (1988) Privately provided public goods in a large economy: the limits of altruism. J Public Econ 35(1):57–73

    Google Scholar 

  • Bénabou R, Tirole J (2006) Incentives and prosocial behavior. Am Econ Rev 96(5):1652–1678

    Google Scholar 

  • Beretti A, Figuieres C, Grolleau G (2013) Using money to motivate both ’saints’ and ’sinners’: a field experiment on motivational crowding-out. Kyklos 66 (1):63–77

    Google Scholar 

  • Bovens L (2009) The ethics of nudge, pp 207–219. Theory and decision library series a: philosophy and methodology of the social sciences, vol 42. Springer, Dordrecht and New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Brekke KA, Kipperberg G, Nyborg K (2010) Social interaction in responsibility ascription: the case of household recycling. Land Economics 86(4):766 –784

    Google Scholar 

  • Brekke KA, Kverndokk S, Nyborg K (2003) An economic model of moral motivation. J Public Econ 87(9-10):1967–1983

    Google Scholar 

  • Brouillat E (2009) Recycling and extending product-life: an evolutionary modelling. J Evol Econ 19(3):437–461

    Google Scholar 

  • Cialdini RB, Reno RR, Kallgren CA (1990) A focus theory of normative conduct: Recycling the concept of norms to reduce littering in public places. J Pers Soc Psychol 58(6):1015–1026

    Google Scholar 

  • Croson R, Treich N (2014) Behavioral environmental economics: Promises and challenges. Environ Resour Econ 58(3):335–351

    Google Scholar 

  • Czajkowski M, Hanley N, Nyborg K (2015) Social norms, morals and self-interest as determinants of pro-environment behaviours: the case of household recycling. Environ Resour Econ 1–24

  • Dijk M, Kemp R, Valkering P (2013) Incorporating social context and co-evolution in an innovation diffusion model–with an application to cleaner vehicles. J Evol Econ 23(2):295–329

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G, Fagiolo G, Napoletano M, Roventini A, Treibich T (2015) Fiscal and monetary policies in complex evolving economies. J Econ Dyn Control 52:166–189

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2011) Roadmap to a resource efficient Europe. Communication from the commission to the european parliament, the council, the European economic and social committee and the committee of the regions, COM(2011) 571 final

  • Eurostat (2015) 477 kg of municipal waste generated per person in the EU. Technical report, https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/products-eurostat-news/-/DDN-20170130-1

  • Eurostat (2017) Municipal waste statistics. Technical report, https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php/Municipal_waste_statistics

  • Ferrara I, Missios P (2005) Recycling and waste diversion effectiveness: Evidence from canada. Environ Resour Econ 30(2):221–238

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferrara I, Missios P (2012) Does waste management policy crowd out social and moral motives for recycling? Technical report, Working Paper 031, Department of Economics, Ryerson University, Mimeo

  • Frey BS (1997) Not just for the money: an economic theory of personal motivation. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton D, Kinnaman TC (1995) Garbage, recycling, and illicit burning or dumping. J Environ Econ Manag 29(1):78–91

    Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton D, Kinnaman TC (1996) Household responses to pricing garbage by the bag. Am Econ Rev 86(4):971–984

    Google Scholar 

  • Gsottbauer E, Van den Bergh JCJM (2011) Environmental policy theory given bounded rationality and other-regarding preferences. Environ Resour Econ 49(2):263–304

    Google Scholar 

  • Haldane AG, Turrell AE (2018) Drawing on different disciplines: macroeconomic agent-based models. J Evol Econ 1–28

  • Hopper JR, Nielsen JM (1991) Recycling as altruistic behavior normative and behavioral strategies to expand participation in a community recycling program. Environment and Behavior 23(2):195–220

    Google Scholar 

  • Hornik J, Cherian J, Madansky M, Narayana C (1995) Determinants of recycling behavior: a synthesis of research results. J Socio-Econ 24(1):105–127

    Google Scholar 

  • Iyer ES, Kashyap RK (2007) Consumer recycling: Role of incentives, information, and social class. J Consum Behav 6(1):32–47

    Google Scholar 

  • Janssen MA, Jager W (2002) Stimulating diffusion of green products: Co-evolution between firms and consumers. J Evol Econ 12(3):283 –306

    Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins RR (1993) The economics of solid waste reduction: the impact of user fees. New Horizons in Environmentla Economic Series. Edward Elgar, Aldershot

    Google Scholar 

  • Leal SJ, Napoletano M, Roventini A, Fagiolo G (2016) Rock around the clock: an agent-based model of low-and high-frequency trading. J Evol Econ 26 (1):49–76

    Google Scholar 

  • Nyborg K (2011) I don’t want to hear about it: Rational ignorance among duty-oriented consumers. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 79(3):263–274

    Google Scholar 

  • Nyborg K, Howarth RB, Brekke KA (2006) Green consumers and public policy: on socially contingent moral motivation. Resour Energy Econ 28(4):351–366

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2014) Greening Household Behaviour: Overview from the 2011 Survey - Revised edition. OECD Publishing, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Oskamp S, Harrington MJ, Edwards TC, Sherwood DL, Okuda SM, Swanson DC (1991) Factors influencing household recycling behavior. Environment and Behavior 23(4):494–519

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz PW (1999) Changing behavior with normative feedback interventions: a field experiment on curbside recycling. Basic Appl Soc Psychol 21(1):25–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein CR, Reisch LA (2013) Green by default. Kyklos 66(3):398–402

    Google Scholar 

  • Tedeschi G, Vitali S, Gallegati M (2014) The dynamic of innovation networks: a switching model on technological change. J Evol Econ 24(4):817–834

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler RH, Sunstein CR (2008) Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. Yale University Press, New Haven and London

    Google Scholar 

  • Van den Bergh JCJM (2008) Environmental regulation of households: an empirical review of economic and psychological factors. Ecological Economics 66(4):559–574

    Google Scholar 

  • Veryzhenko I, Harb E, Louhichi W, Oriol N (2017) The impact of the french financial transaction tax on hft activities and market quality. Econ Model 67:307–315

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi WK, Huber J, Bell J (2011) Promoting recycling: Private values, social norms, and economic incentives. Am Econ Rev 101(3):65–70

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christophe Charlier.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interests

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A: Proofs of the Propositions and Corollary

1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

We consider the case where the condition \(c_{i}>\frac {1}{2}\left ({{v_{i}^{a}}}^{\left (1-\eta \right )^{2}} + t\left ({v_{i}^{t}}+1\right ) + 2 x_{i} \gamma _{i} \left (\bar {a}_{i}-1\right )\right )\), ensuring that both \(a_{i}^{*}\) and \(\hat {a}_{i}\) are less than 1, is satisfied. Social influence is defined by \(a_{i}^{*}-\hat {a}_{i}\) with \(\hat {a}_{i}\) and \(a_{i}^{*}\) defined respectively in Eqs. 6 and 10. Developing \(a_{i}^{*}-\hat {a}_{i}>0\) gives \(\frac {{{v_{i}^{a}}}^{(1-\eta )^{2}} + t\left (1+{v_{i}^{t}}\right )}{2c_{i}}<\bar {a}_{i}\) (or \(\hat {a}_{i}<\bar {a}_{i}\)).

1.2 Proof of Proposition 2

With \(\hat {a}_{i}\) and \(a_{i}^{*}\) defined in Eqs. 6 and 10, \(\partial \left (a_{i}^{*}-\hat {a}_{i}\right )/\partial t = -\frac {x_{i}\gamma _{i}(1+{v_{i}^{t}})}{2c_{i}(c_{i}+x_{i}\gamma _{i})}\). This derivative is always negative. The same holds true for \(\partial \left (a_{i}^{*}-\hat {a}_{i}\right )/\partial \eta \).

1.3 Proof of Proposition 3

  1. 1.

    The impact of xi on \(a_{i}^{*}\) (and on social influence) is given by \(\partial a_{i}^{*}/\partial x_{i} = \gamma _{i}\frac {2c_{i}\bar {a}_{i}-{{v_{i}^{a}}}^{(1-\eta )^{2}}-t(1+{v_{i}^{t}})}{2(c_{i}+x_{i}\gamma _{i})^{2}}\). It is positive when \(2c_{i}\bar {a}_{i}-{v_{i}^{a}}-t(1+{v_{i}^{t}})>0\), or when \(\bar {a}_{i}>\hat {a}_{i}\). It is negative otherwise.

  2. 2.

    The impact of the tax on social influence is given by \(\partial (a_{i}^{*}-\hat {a}_{i})/\partial t = -\frac {x_{i}\gamma _{i}(1+{v_{i}^{t}})}{2c_{i}(c_{i}+x_{i}\gamma _{i}}\). The effect of xi on it is given by \(\partial ^{2} (a_{i}^{*}-\hat {a}_{i})/\partial t \partial x = -\frac {2\gamma _{i}(1+{v_{i}^{t}})}{(2c_{i}+2x_{i} \gamma _{i})^{2}}\). This effect is always negative. As \(\partial ^{3} (a_{i}^{*}-\hat {a}_{i})/\partial t \partial x^{2} = \frac {{\gamma _{i}}^{2}(1+{v_{i}^{t}})}{(c_{i}+x_{i} \gamma _{i})^{3}}\), this effect is decreasing in absolute value.

  3. 3.

    Calculated in \(a_{i}^{*}\), \(\partial r(a_{i}^{*}(t))/\partial t\) is equal to \(-\frac {x_{i}\gamma _{i}\left (1+{v_{i}^{t}}\right )}{c_{i}+x_{i}\gamma _{i}}\). The impacts of xi on \(\partial r(a_{i}^{*}(t))/\partial t\) is measured by \(\partial ^{2} r(a_{i}^{*}(t))/\partial t \partial x= -\frac {c_{i}\gamma _{i}\left (1+{v_{i}^{t}}\right )}{\left (c_{i}+x_{i}\gamma _{i}\right )^{2}}\), and is negative. It is easy to check that \(\partial ^{3} r(a_{i}^{*}(t))/\partial t \partial x^{2}= \frac {2c_{i}{\gamma _{i}^{2}}\left (1+{v_{i}^{t}}\right )}{\left (c_{i}+x_{i}\gamma _{i}\right )^{3}}\) is positive. So that the effect of xi on the absolute value of the crowding-out effect is always positive at a decreasing rate.

Appendix B: Parameter values used in the model simulations

Table 2 Parameter values used in the model simulations

Appendix C: Robustness check

In the two configurations presented in this article, the mean values \(\bar {v}^{a}\), \(\bar {v}^{t}\), and \(\bar {\gamma }\) used in the normal distributions of these individual parameters are fixed at, respectively, 0.7, 0.3, 0.5, and 0.3, 0.7, 0.5. However, we also tested the separate impact of a variation in the individual parameters (keeping the other parameters fixed) on the results (optimal decision to recycle, social influence and crowding-out effect). We performed extensive Monte Carlo simulations to exclude simulation variability. The results presented below refer to averages over several replications. All the simulation results refer to 1000 independent Monte Carlo simulations, each involving 300 time steps (households’ moves in the model). The simulations are run for four different cases. The first case considers a ‘low’ policy mix (t = 2 and η = 0.2), the second a ‘medium’ policy mix (t = 4 and η = 0.4), and the last two cases, a ‘high’ policy mix (t = 6 and η = 0.6) and a ‘very high’ policy mix (t = 8 and η = 0.8).

Regarding the impact of \(\bar {v}^{a}\) and \(\bar {v}^{t}\) on the optimal recycling decision, Figs. 9 and 10 indicate, as expected, an increasing relation between the intrinsic value of the population mean and the optimal recycling decision, regardless of the policy level. The confidence intervals observed for the different values of the optimal recycling decisions show that the variations in \(\bar {v}^{a}\) do not significantly affect the optimal recycling (since the confidence intervals overlap). By contrast, the variation in \(\bar {v}^{t}\) significantly affects the optimal recycling decision. Similarly, the policy mix level has a significant effect on the optimal recycling decisions, in the expected direction.

Fig. 9
figure 9

The impact of \(\bar {v}^a\)’s variations on \(a_{i}^{*}\)

Fig. 10
figure 10

The impact of \(\bar {v}^t\)’s variations on \(a_{i}^{*}\)

The confidence intervals observed in Figs. 11 and 12 depict the same results for social influence. In fact, the different values of social influence show that the variations in \(\bar {v^{a}}\) and \(\bar {v^{t}}\) have no significant effect on social influence. However, it appears that the different policy mix levels have a significant effect on social influence.

Fig. 11
figure 11

The impact of \(\bar {v}^a\)’s variations on \(a_{i}^{*}-\hat {a}_i\)

Fig. 12
figure 12

The impact of \(\bar {v}^t\)’s variations on \(a_{i}^{*}-\hat {a}_i\)

Figures 13 and 14 refer to the crowding-out effect. The different values for the crowding-out effect show that the variation in \(\bar {v^{a}}\) (see Fig. 13) has no effect on the crowding-out effect. Similarly, the policy mix level has no effect on the crowding-out effect. Figure 14 indicates, as expected a decreasing relation between the extrinsic value of the population mean, and the crowding-out effect, regardless of the policy level. The confidence intervals observed for the different values of the crowding-out effect show that the variations in \(\bar {v}^{t}\) do not significantly affect the crowding-out effect.

Fig. 13
figure 13

The impact of \(\bar {v}^a\)’s variations on \(\partial r(a_{i}^{*}(t))/\partial t\)

Fig. 14
figure 14

The impact of \(\bar {v}^t\)’s variations on \(\partial r(a_{i}^{*}(t))/\partial t\)

The impacts of \(\bar {\gamma }\) on the optimal recycling decision and the social influence and crowding-out effect are presented in Figs. (1516171819). Note that the policy level has a significant effect on the optimal recycling decision. However, the variations in \(\bar {\gamma }\) do not affect the optimal recycling decision significantly (Fig. 15). We observe that both the policy level and the variations in \(\bar {\gamma }\) have a significant effect on social influence (Figure 17). In relation to the crowding-out effect (Fig. 19), the variations in \(\bar {\gamma }\) have a significant effect. By contrast, variations in the policy level have no significant effect on the crowding-out effect.

Fig. 15
figure 15

The impact of \(\bar {\gamma }\)’s variations on \(a_{i}^{*}\)

Fig. 16
figure 16

The impact of \(\bar {C}\)’ variations on ai

Fig. 17
figure 17

The impact of \(\bar {\gamma }\)’s variations on \(a_{i}^{*}-\hat {a}_i\)

Fig. 18
figure 18

The impact of \(\bar {C}\)’ variations on \(a_{i}^{*}-\hat {a}_i\)

Fig. 19
figure 19

The impact of \(\bar {\gamma }\)’s variations on \(\partial r(a_{i}^{*}(t))/\partial t\)

In relation to the cost parameter c, we observe that it has no significant impact on the optimal recycling decision, social influence and the crowding-out effect (Figs. 161820). We observe a relation only between policy level and crowding-out effect.

Fig. 20
figure 20

The impact of \(\bar {C}\)’ variations on \(\partial r(a_{i}^{*}(t))/\partial t\)

Finally, we observe that the variations in visibility do not significantly affect optimal recycling (Figs. 21 and 22). These results are observed without a nudge (Fig. 21) and with the BV nudge (Fig. 22), which latter increases the number of contacts to four. In the case of social influence (Figs. 23 and 24), the low variations in visibility (between 0 and 2) have a significant effect on social influence. For both optimal recycling and social influence, the policy level differences significantly affect the impact of visibility. In relation to the crowding-out effect (Figs. 25 and 26), the policy level variations do not have a significant effect on the impact of visibility (the curves cannot be distinguished). With the exception of ow values (between 0 and 2), the variations in visibility do not significantly affect the crowding-out.

Fig. 21
figure 21

The impact of xi variations on \(a_{i}^{*}\) without nudge

Fig. 22
figure 22

The impact of xi variations on \(a_{i}^{*}\) with the BV nudge

Fig. 23
figure 23

The impact of xi variations on \(a_{i}^{*}-\hat {a}_i\) without nudge

Fig. 24
figure 24

The impact of xi variations on \(a_{i}^{*}-\hat {a}_i\) with the BV nudge

Fig. 25
figure 25

The impact of xi variations on \(\partial r(a_{i}^{*}(t))/\partial t\) without nudge

Fig. 26
figure 26

The impact of xi variations on \(\partial r(a_{i}^{*}(t))/\partial t\) with the BV nudge

Appendix D: The evolution of the recycling rate over time of the simulation

Fig. 27
figure 27

Optimal recycling decision without and with nudge over time

Appendix E: Mean of beliefs on the recycling norm vs. the mean of optimal recycling decisions under the BV nudge

Fig. 28
figure 28

Evolutions of the mean of beliefs on the norm and of the mean of optimal recycling decisions under the BV nudge

Appendix F: Micro level results vs. aggregate level results

Table 3

Rights and permissions

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Charlier, C., Kirakozian, A. Public policies for household recycling when reputation matters. J Evol Econ 30, 523–557 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-019-00648-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-019-00648-5

Keywords

  • Household recycling
  • Waste
  • Environmental regulation
  • Behavioral economics
  • ABM
  • Social interaction

JEL Classification

  • D100
  • D030
  • Q530
  • Q580