Abstract
We propose a financial market model with optimistic and pessimistic fundamentalists who, respectively, overestimate and underestimate the true fundamental value due to ambiguity in the stock market. We assume that agents form their beliefs about the fundamental value through an imitative process, considering the relative ability shown by optimists and pessimists in guessing the realized stock price. We also introduce an endogenous switching mechanism, allowing agents to switch to the other group of speculators if they performed better in terms of relative profits. Moreover, the stock price is determined by a nonlinear mechanism. We study, via analytical and numerical tools, the stability of the unique steady state, its bifurcations and the emergence of complex behaviors, with possible multistability phenomena. To quantify the global propensity to optimism/pessimism of the market, we introduce an index, depending on pessimists’ and optimists’ beliefs and shares, thanks to which we are able to show that the occurrence of the waves of optimism and pessimism are due to the joint effect of imitation and switching mechanism. Finally, we perform a statistical analysis of a stochastically perturbed version of the model, which high lights fat tails and excess volatility in the returns distributions, as well as bubbles and crashes for stock prices, in agreement with the empirical literature.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
1 We stress that such a notion of ambiguity differs from the one employed in general equilibrium theory, where agents, in making their choices in stochastic frameworks, are assumed to take into account different probability laws describing the distribution of relevant random variables. See e.g. Dow and Werlang (1992) and Ellsberg (1961).
2 Starting with the crucial paper by De Bondt and Thaler (1985), a well-grounded empirical literature has arisen to show the presence of overreaction phenomena in financial markets. We recall that, as said in France et al. (1994), page 19, overreaction is “defined as a movement in price that overshoots the equilibrium value and then subsequently returns to its true value”. Subsequently, some authors have given further foundations to overreaction events through the formulation and analysis of mathematical models. See, for instance, the works by Barberis et al. (1998), by Hong and Stein (1999) and by Veronesi (1999).
We only provide sufficient conditions for the occurrence of each scenario. We remark thatwe may indeed obtain the same scenario for other parameter configurations. Moreover, wenotice that some of the stability intervals we shall derive below may in principle be empty forany parameter configuration. We will provide numerical examples in Section 4 to show thatthere exist parameter settings for which such intervals are nonempty and the correspondingscenarios do actually occur.
Actually, if \(\mu _{1}=\mu _{2}\in (\max \left \{\mu _{\ell },0\right \},\mu _{r})\) we find two disjoint adjacent stability intervals. Such limit case can however be encompassed in the mixed scenario.
References
Anderson S, de Palma A, Thisse J (1992) Discrete choice theory of product differentiation. The MIT Press, Cambridge
Akerlof GA, Shiller RJ (2009) Animal spirits: how human psychology drives the economy and why it matters for global capitalism. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Barberis N, Shleifer A, Vishny R (1998) A model of investor sentiment. J Financ Econ 49:307–343
Barberis N, Thaler R (2003) A survey of behavioral finance. In: Constantinides G M, Harris M, Stulz R (eds) Handbook of the economics of finance, 1st edn. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1053–1128
Brock WA, Hommes CH (1997) A rational route to randomness. Econometrica 65:1059–1095
Brock WA, Hommes CH (1998) Heterogeneous beliefs and routes to chaos in a simple asset pricing model. J Econ Dyn Control 22:1235–1274
Chiarella C, Dieci R, He X-Z (2009) Heterogeneity, market mechanisms, and asset price dynamics. In: Hens T, Schenk-Hoppé K R (eds) Handbook of financial markets: dynamics and evolution. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 277–344
Chiarella C, He X-Z, Hommes CH (2006) A dynamic analysis of moving average rules. J Econ Dyn Control 30:1729–1753
De Bondt W, Thaler R (1985) Does the stock market overreact? J Financ 40:793–805
De Grauwe P (2012) Lectures on behavioral macroeconomics. Princeton University Press, Princeton
De Grauwe P, Macchiarelli C (2015) Animal spirits and credit cycles. J Econ Dyn Control 59:95–117
De Grauwe P, Rovira Kaltwasser P (2012) Animal spirits in the foreign exchange market. J Econ Dyn Control 36:1176–1192
Dieci R, He X-Z, Hommes C (eds) (2014) Nonlinear economic dynamics and financial modelling. Essays in honour of Carl Chiarella. Springer, Berlin
Dow J, Werlang S (1992) Uncertainty aversion, risk aversion, and the optimal choice of portfolio. Econometrica 60:197–204
Ellsberg D (1961) Risk, ambiguity, and the savage axioms. Q J Econ 75:643–669
Epstein S (2003) Cognitive-experiential self-theory of personality. In: Millon T, Lerner M J (eds) Comprehensive handbook of psychology, vol 5. Wiley, Hoboken, New Jersey, pp 159–184
Farebrother RW (1973) Simplified Samuelson conditions for cubic and quartic equations. Manch Sch 41:396–400
France V, Kodres L, Moser J (1994) A review of regulatory mechanisms to control the volatility of prices. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. Econ Perspect 18:15–26
Gilbert D (2002) Inferential correction. In: Gilovich T, Griffin D, Kahneman D (eds) Heuristics and biases: the psychology of intuitive thought. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 167–184
Harris L (1998) Circuit breakers and program trading limits: what have we learned? In: Litan R, Santomero A (eds) Brookings-wharton papers on financial services. Brookings Institutions Press, Washington, pp 17–63
Hommes CH (1991) Adaptive learning and roads to chaos: the case of the cobweb. Econ Lett 36:127–132
Hommes CH (1994) Dynamics of the cobweb model with adaptive expectations and nonlinear supply and demand. J Econ Behav Organ 24:315–335
Hommes CH (2006) Heterogeneous agent models in economics and finance. In: Tesfatsion L, Judd KL (eds) Hand-book of computational economics, vol. 2: agent-based computational economics. Elsevier Science B.V., Amsterdam, pp 1109–1186
Hommes CH (2013) Behavioral rationality and heterogeneous expectations in complex economic systems. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Hong H, Stein JC (1999) A unified theory of underreaction, momentum trading and overreaction in asset markets. J Financ 54:2143–2184
Keynes JM (1936) The general theory of employment interest and money. Macmillan, London
Kindleberger CP, Aliber RZ (2005) Manias, panics, and crashes: a history of financial crises. Wiley, Hoboken, New Jersey
Kyle A (1988) Trading halts and price limits. Rev Futures Mark 7:426–434
Naimzada A, Pireddu M (2015a) Real and financial interacting markets: a behavioral macro-model. Chaos Solit Fract 77:111–131
Naimzada A, Pireddu M (2015b) A financial market model with endogenous fundamental values through imitative behavior. Chaos 25:073110. doi:10.1063/1.4926326
Naimzada A, Pireddu M (2015c) Introducing a price variation limiter mechanism into a behavioral financial market model. Chaos 25:083112. doi:10.1063/1.4927831
Naimzada A, Ricchiuti G (2008) Heterogeneous fundamentalists and imitative processes. Appl Math Comput 199:171–180
Naimzada A, Ricchiuti G (2009) The dynamic effect of increasing heterogeneity in financial markets. Chaos Solit Fract 41:1764–1772
Naimzada A, Ricchiuti G (2014) Complexity with heterogeneous fundamentalists and a multiplicative price mechanism. Econ Notes 43:233–247
Schlag K (1998) Why imitate, and if so, how?: a boundedly rational approach to multi-armed bandits. J Econ Theory 78:130–156
Schmitt N, Westerhoff F (2014) Speculative behavior and the dynamics of interacting stock markets. J Econ Dyn Control 45:262–288
Tuinstra J (2002) Nonlinear dynamics and the stability of competitive equilibria. In: Hommes C H, Ramer R, Withagen C H (eds) Equilibrium, markets and dynamics. Essays in honour of claus weddepohl. Springer, Berlin, pp 329–343
Tversky A, Kahneman D (1974) Judgement under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. Science 185:1124–1131
Veronesi P (1999) Stock market overreactions to bad news in good times: a rational expectations equilibrium model. Rev Financ Stud 12:975–1007
Weddepohl C (1995) A cautious price adjustment mechanism: chaotic behavior. J Econ Behav Organ 27:293–300
Westerhoff F (2009) Exchange rate dynamics: a nonlinear survey. In: Rosser Jr J B (ed) Handbook of research on complexity. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 287–325
Wilson T (2002) Strangers to ourselves: discovering the adaptive unconscious. Harvard University Press, Cambridge
Zhu M, Chiarella C, He X-Z, Wang D (2009) Does the market maker stabilize the market? Physica A 388:3164–3180
Acknowledgments
The authors thank Professor He and Professor Hommes for their valuable comments about the interpretation of the model and the consistency with real data, and all the participants to NED 2015 for helpful discussions.
The authors wish also to thank the anonymous Reviewers and Professor Dieci, Guest Editor of the Special Issue on “Nonlinear Economic Dynamics”, for the useful suggestions.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Ethics declarations
Conflict of interests
The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.
Appendix
Appendix
Proof of Proposition 1
The expression of the steady state for the population shares follows by noticing that, in equilibrium, P(t + 1) = P(t) and thus, by Eq. 3, we have π X = π Y = 0 at the steady state, so that \(\omega ^{\ast }=\frac {1}{2}\). Moreover, from the stock price equation we find \(P^{\ast }=\omega ^{\ast } X^{\ast }+(1-\omega ^{\ast })Y^{\ast }=\frac {X^{\ast }+Y^{\ast }}{2}\), so that \(X^{\ast }=F-\frac {\Delta }{2}\) and \(Y^{\ast }=F+\frac {\Delta }{2}\). Inserting such expressions in P ∗, we get P ∗ = F, as desired. □
Proof of Proposition 2
Since from Eq. 7 it follows that
then we find
as desired. □
Proof of Proposition 3
To prove (i′) − (iii′), we use the conditions in Farebrother (1973).
To such aim, we need to compute the Jacobian matrix for G in correspondence to (X ∗, P ∗, ω ∗),which reads as
The Farebrother conditions are the following:
-
(i)
1 − C 1 + C 2 − C 3 > 0;
-
(ii)
1 − C 2 + C 1 C 3 − (C 3)2 > 0;
-
(iii)
3 − C 2 > 0;
-
(iv)
1 + C 1 + C 2 + C 3 > 0,
where C i , i ∈ {1, 2, 3}, are the coefficients of the characteristic polynomial
In our framework, we have:
and thus simple computations allow to notice that conditions (i) − (i i i) above read,respectively, as (i′) − (iii′), while (i v) reduces to \(\widetilde {\gamma }>0\), which is indeed true. □
Proof of Corollary 1
Firstly, we keep Δ ≠ 0, μ and \(\widetilde {\gamma }\) fixed and we solve conditions \((i^{\prime })-(iii^{\prime })\) with respect to β.
If 2 − μΔ2 ≤ 0, we have that condition (i′) is not satisfied by any β > 0, which means that we are in the unconditionally unstable scenario.
Let us now consider 2 − μΔ2 > 0.Condition (i′) is then equivalent to
From (iii′) we have
Finally, we notice that we can rearrange condition (ii′) as k 1 β 2 + k 2 β + k 3 > 0 with \(k_{1}=- {\Delta }^{8}\widetilde {\gamma }^{2}\mu ^{2} - 2{\Delta }^{6}\widetilde {\gamma }^{2}\mu ,\, k_{2}=4{\Delta }^{6} \widetilde {\gamma } \mu ^{2} + 8{\Delta }^{4}\widetilde {\gamma }^{2}\mu - 16{\Delta }^{2}\widetilde {\gamma }\) and \(k_{3}=32\mu {\Delta }^{2} + 64\).
If μ > 0, then k 1 < 0 < k 3, and thus condition (ii′) is fulfilled by
with \(\beta _{r_{0}}<0<\beta _{r_{1}}\) given by
where
Combining Eqs. 14–16 and recalling that β > 0,we find that system (i′) − (iii′) is equivalent to
In particular, if β ℓ ≤ 0,i.e., if \(\widetilde {\gamma }\le 2-\mu {\Delta }^{2}\), and\(\min \{\beta _{r_{1}},\beta _{r_{2}}\}>0\), we have the destabilizing scenario, while when \(0<\beta _{\ell }<\min \{\beta _{r_{1}},\beta _{r_{2}}\}\)the mixed scenario occurs; in all other cases we have the unconditionally unstable scenario.
If, instead, μ = 0, then k 1 = 0 and it is easy tosee that conditions (i′) − (iii′) are equivalent to \(\max \{\beta _{\ell },0\}<\beta <\beta _{r_{1}}\),with \(\beta _{\ell }=\frac {4}{\widetilde {\gamma }{\Delta }^{2}} \left (\frac {\widetilde {\gamma }}{2}-1\right )\)and\(\beta _{r_{1}}=\frac {4}{\widetilde {\gamma }{\Delta }^{2}}\). Then, in this case we havea destabilizing scenario (\(\beta _{\ell }\le 0<\beta _{r_{1}}\))if and only if \(\widetilde {\gamma }\in (0,2]\), while a mixed scenario (\(0<\beta _{\ell }<\beta _{r_{1}}\))occurs if and only if \(\widetilde {\gamma }\in (2,4)\).
Now we keep Δ ≠ 0, β and \(\widetilde {\gamma }\) fixed and we solve conditions (i′) − (iii′) with respect to μ. Solving (i′) we find
while (iii′) provides
Condition (ii′) can be rewritten as
where \(q_{1}={\Delta }^{6}\beta \widetilde {\gamma }(4-\beta \widetilde {\gamma }{\Delta }^{2}), \, q_{2}=-2{\Delta }^{2}({\Delta }^{4}\beta ^{2}\widetilde {\gamma }^{2} - 4{\Delta }^{2}\beta \widetilde {\gamma }^{2} - 16)\)and \(q_{3}= 16(4-\beta \widetilde {\gamma }{\Delta }^{2})\).
First we notice that, if q 1 = 0, i.e., if \(\beta =4/(\widetilde {\gamma }{\Delta }^{2})\), then also q 3 = 0and thus (20) is satisfied for all μ > 0 if and only if \({\Delta }^{4}\beta ^{2}\widetilde {\gamma }^{2}={\Delta }^{4} \left (4/(\widetilde {\gamma } {\Delta }^{2})\right )^{2}\widetilde {\gamma }^{2}=16< 4{\Delta }^{2}\beta \widetilde {\gamma }^{2}+ 16=32\), which is indeed true. We stress that if μ = 0 = q 1, then condition (ii′) is again never fulfilled and thus we do not have stability for μ = 0 if q 1 = 0. Hence, when q 1 = 0 conditions (i′) − (iii′) simply reduce to\(\mu \in (\mu _{\ell },\mu _{r})\cap (0,+\infty )\), and this provides the destabilizing scenario for μ ℓ < 0 < μ r , the mixed scenariofor 0 < μ ℓ < μ r , and the unconditionally unstable scenario for \(\mu _{r}\le \max \{\mu _{\ell },0\}\).
Let us now assume that q 1 ≠ 0. If \(\chi ={q_{2}^{2}}-4q_{1}q_{3}>0\), we can introduce the real numbers
and
where
We then have that Eq. 20 is solved by \(\mu <\mu _{1}\,\cup \,\mu >\mu _{2}\) if q 1 > 0 and by μ 1 < μ < μ 2if q 1 < 0. Let us examine theformer case. Since we have q 1 > 0 and q 3 > 0, the sign of μ 1/2 is the same of − q 2. Since from q 1 > 0 we have \(\beta <4/(\widetilde {\gamma }{\Delta }^{2})\), we obtain
so that, in such case, we have q 2 > 0 and thus μ 1 < μ 2 < 0and Eq. 20 is fulfilled by any μ ≥ 0. Combining this with Eqs. 18 and 19 we obtain \(\mu \in (\mu _{\ell },\mu _{r})\cap [0,+\infty )\), which provides the destabilizing scenario if μ ℓ < 0 < μ r , the mixed scenario if 0 < μ ℓ < μ r and the unconditionally unstable scenario if \(\mu _{r}\le \max \{\mu _{\ell },0\}\).
Conversely, if q 1 < 0, combining μ 1 < μ < μ 2 with Eqs. 18 and 19 we have \(\mu \in (\max \left \{\mu _{1},\mu _{\ell }\right \},\min \left \{\mu _{2},\mu _{r}\right \})\cap [0,+\infty )\), which can again give rise to either a destabilizing, a mixed or an unconditionally unstable scenario.
If \({q_{2}^{2}}-4q_{1}q_{3}<0\), we have that Eq. 20 is always fulfilled if \(4-\beta \widetilde {\gamma }{\Delta }^{2}>0\) and never fulfilled when \(4-\beta \widetilde {\gamma }{\Delta }^{2}<0\). In the former case, recalling Eqs. 18 and 19, we obtain \(\mu \in (\mu _{\ell },\mu _{r})\cap [0,+\infty )\), and thus we can have destabilizing, mixed and unconditionally unstable scenarios. If instead \(4-\beta \widetilde {\gamma }{\Delta }^{2}<0\), conditions (i′) − (iii′) can not be satisfied and we just find the unconditionally unstable scenario.
It can be easily seen that the remaining situation \({q_{2}^{2}}-4q_{1}q_{3}=0\) can only provide the previous scenarios.Footnote 4
Finally, the stability conditions with respect to Δ when μ = 0 and β ≠ 0 read as
when \(\widetilde {\gamma }\ge 2\), and simply as \(0\le {\Delta }<\frac {2}{\sqrt {\widetilde {\gamma }\beta }}\,\), when \(\widetilde {\gamma }< 2\). For \(\widetilde {\gamma }\ge 2\) we then find the mixed scenario and for \(\widetilde {\gamma }<2\) the destabilizing scenario. The proof is complete. □
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Cavalli, F., Naimzada, A. & Pireddu, M. An evolutive financial market model with animal spirits: imitation and endogenous beliefs. J Evol Econ 27, 1007–1040 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-017-0506-8
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-017-0506-8