Advertisement

Journal of Evolutionary Economics

, Volume 24, Issue 3, pp 479–513 | Cite as

“Generalized Darwinism” and the quest for an evolutionary theory of policy-making

  • Christian SchubertEmail author
Regular Article

Abstract

According to the “Generalized Darwinism” movement (GD), the three principles of variation, selection and retention/replication (labeled “Darwinian” in some variants of GD) can and should be used as a meta-theoretical framework for the explanation of evolutionary processes in the sociocultural domain. Despite their biological origins, the various variants of GD aim at redefining these principles in a way that is supposed to abstract from any domain-specific particulars. We argue that in order to qualify as an adequate meta-theoretical framework for evolutionary economics, GD should not only inspire and guide positive theory development in evolutionary economics, but also be able to support viable practical policy implications. Examining its potential to do so, however, leads us to the conclusion that in its specific deductive variant proposed by Hodgson & Knudsen (HKGD), it risks systematically misguiding evolutionary policy advice. Competing variants, such as the one proposed by Pelikan, fare better in this regard.

Keywords

Evolution Selection Darwinism Ontology Continuity hypothesis Evolutionary theory of policy-making 

JEL Classification

A1 B4 B52 D6 O1 

References

  1. Ahuvia A (2008) If money doesn’t make us happy, why do we act as if it does? J Econ Psychol 29:491–507Google Scholar
  2. Aldrich HE, Hodgson GM, Hull DL, Knudsen T, Mokyr J, Vanberg VJ (2008) In defence of generalized Darwinism. J Evol Econ 18:77–596Google Scholar
  3. Andersen ES (2009) Schumpeter’s evolutionary economics. Anthem Press, LondonGoogle Scholar
  4. Andersson C (2011) Splitting the replicator: generalized Darwinism and the place of culture in nature. J Econ Behav Organ 80:657–669Google Scholar
  5. Ayala F (2010) The difference of being human: morality. Proc Natl Acad Sci 107:9015–9022Google Scholar
  6. Breslin D (2011) Reviewing a generalized Darwinist approach to studying socio-economic change. Int J Manag Rev 13:218–235Google Scholar
  7. Browne J (2006) Darwin’s origin of species. A biography. Atlantic, LondonGoogle Scholar
  8. Buenstorf G (2006) How useful is generalized Darwinism as a framework to study competition and industrial evolution? J Evol Econ 16:511–527Google Scholar
  9. Campbell DT (1960) Blind variation and selective retention in creative thought as in other knowledge processes. Psychol Rev 67:380–400Google Scholar
  10. Campbell DT (1965) Variation and selective retention in socio-cultural evolution. In: Barringer HR, Blankstein GI, Mack RW (eds) Social change in developing areas: a re-interpretation of evolutionary theory. Schenkman, Cambridge, pp 19–49Google Scholar
  11. Campbell DT (1987) Evolutionary epistemology. In: Radnitzky G, Bartley III WW (eds) Evolutionary epistemology, rationality and the sociology of knowledge. Open Court, Chicago and La Salle IL, pp 47–89Google Scholar
  12. Carroll SB (2005) Endless forms most beautiful: the new science of evo devo. Norton, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  13. Cochrane T, Maclaurin J (2012) Evolvability and progress in evolutionary economics. J Bioecon 14:101–114Google Scholar
  14. Commons JR (1934) Institutional economics—its place in political economy. Macmillan, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  15. Cordes C (2006) Darwinism in economics: from analogy to continuity. J Evol Econ 16:529–541Google Scholar
  16. Cordes C (2007a) Turning economics into an evolutionary science: Veblen, the selection metaphor, and analogical thinking. J Econ Issues 41:135–154Google Scholar
  17. Cordes C (2007b) Can a generalized Darwinism be criticized? A rejoinder to Geoffrey Hodgson. J Econ Issues 41:277–281Google Scholar
  18. Cordes C (2009) The role of biology and culture in veblenian consumption dynamics. J Econ Issues 43:115–141Google Scholar
  19. Cordes C, Schubert C (2013) Role models that make you unhappy: social learning, light paternalism and welfare. J Inst Econ, forthcomingGoogle Scholar
  20. Cordes C, Richerson PJ, McElreath R, Strimling P (2008) A naturalistic approach to the theory of the firm: the role of cooperation and cultural evolution. J Econ Behav Organ 68:125–139Google Scholar
  21. Dawkins R (1976) The selfish gene. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  22. Dawkins R (1983) Universal Darwinism. In: Bendall DS (ed) Evolution from molecules to man. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 403–425Google Scholar
  23. Dennett DC (1994) Darwin’s dangerous idea. Simon & Schuster, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  24. Dennett DC (1997) The evolution of evaluators. In: Nicita A, Pagano U (eds) The evolution of economic diversity. Routledge, London, pp 66–81Google Scholar
  25. Dolfsma W (2005) Towards a dynamic (Schumpeterian) welfare economics. Res Policy 34:69–82Google Scholar
  26. Dopfer K (1976) Introduction: towards a new paradigm. In: Dopfer K (ed) Economics in the future. Macmillan, London, pp 3–35Google Scholar
  27. Ebner A (2006) Institutions, entrepreneurship, and the rationale of government: an outline of the Schumpeterian theory of the state. J Econ Behav Organ 59:497–515Google Scholar
  28. Ferguson N (2008) The ascent of money. A financial history of the world. Penguin, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  29. Frank RH (2008) Should public policy respond to positional externalities? J Public Econ 92:1777–1786Google Scholar
  30. Frey BS (2008) Happiness: a revolution in economics. MIT Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  31. Geisendorf S (2009) The economic concept of evolution: self-organization or universal Darwinism? J Econ Methodol 16:377–391Google Scholar
  32. Ghiselin MT (1995) Darwin, progress, and economic principles. Evol 49:1029–1037Google Scholar
  33. Gray J (1998) Hayek on Liberty. Routledge, LondonGoogle Scholar
  34. Guha A (1994) The Darwinian view of progress: a comment on sen. Popul Dev Rev 20:861–865Google Scholar
  35. Harford T (2011) Adapt: why success always starts with failure. Little, Brown, LondonGoogle Scholar
  36. Hayek FA (1976) Law, legislation and liberty, vol II. Routledge, LondonGoogle Scholar
  37. Hayek FA (1988) The fatal conceit. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  38. Hodgson GM (1993) Economics and evolution: bringing life back into economics. University of Michigan Press, Ann ArborGoogle Scholar
  39. Hodgson GM (1997) The evolutionary and non-Darwinian economics of Joseph Schumpeter. J Evol Econ 7:131–145Google Scholar
  40. Hodgson GM (1999) Economics and Utopia: why the learning economy is not the end of history. Routledge, LondonGoogle Scholar
  41. Hodgson GM (2002) Darwinism in economics: from analogy to ontology. J Evol Econ 12:259–281Google Scholar
  42. Hodgson GM (2004a) Hayekian evolution reconsidered: a response to Caldwell. Camb J Econ 28:291–300Google Scholar
  43. Hodgson GM (2004b) Social Darwinism in Anglophone Academic Journals: a contribution to the history of the term. J Hist Sociol 17:428–463Google Scholar
  44. Hodgson GM (2005) Generalizing Darwinism to social evolution: some early attempts. J Econ Issues 39:899–914Google Scholar
  45. Hodgson GM (2007) A response to Christian Cordes and Clifford Poirot. J Econ Issues 41:265–276Google Scholar
  46. Hodgson GM (2010) A philosophical perspective on contemporary evolutionary economics. Papers on economics & evolution, # 1001. Max Planck Institute of Economics, Jena, GermanyGoogle Scholar
  47. Hodgson GM, Knudsen T (2004) The firm as an interactor: firms as vehicles for habits and routines. J Evol Econ 14:281–307Google Scholar
  48. Hodgson GM, Knudsen T (2006a) Why we need a generalized Darwinism, and why generalized Darwinism is not enough. J Econ Behav Organ 61:1–19Google Scholar
  49. Hodgson GM, Knudsen T (2006b) Dismantling Lamarckism: why descriptions of socio-economic evolution as Lamarckian are misleading. J Evol Econ 16:343–366Google Scholar
  50. Hodgson GM, Knudsen T (2007) Evolutionary theorizing beyond Lamarckism: a reply to Richard Nelson. J Evol Econ 17:353–359Google Scholar
  51. Hodgson GM, Knudsen T (2008a) Information, complexity and generative replication. Biol Philos 23:47–65Google Scholar
  52. Hodgson GM, Knudsen T (2008b) In search of general evolutionary principles: why Darwinism is too important to be left to the biologists. J Bioecon 10:51–69Google Scholar
  53. Hodgson GM, Knudsen T (2010a) Darwin’s conjecture. The search for general principles of social and economic evolution. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  54. Hodgson GM, Knudsen T (2010b) Generative replication and the evolution of complexity. J Econ Behav Organ 75:12–24Google Scholar
  55. Hodgson GM, Knudsen T (2012a) Agreeing on generalised Darwinism: a response to Pavel Pelikan. J Evol Econ 22:9–18Google Scholar
  56. Hodgson GM, Knudsen T (2012b) Underqualified—maximal generality in Darwinian explanation: a response to Matt Gers. Biol Philos 27:607–614Google Scholar
  57. Hull DL (1988) Science as a process. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  58. Hull DL (1989) The metaphysics of evolution. State University of New York Press, AlbanyGoogle Scholar
  59. Kauffman SA (1993) The origins of order: self-organization and selection in evolution. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  60. Kerstenetzky CL (2000) Hayek: the evolutionary and the evolutionist. Rat Soc 12:163–184Google Scholar
  61. Kerstenetzky CL (2007) Hayek and Popper on ignorance and intervention. J Inst Econ 3:33–53Google Scholar
  62. Keynes JN (1917) The scope and method of political economy. Macmillan, LondonGoogle Scholar
  63. KitcherHossfeld U, Witt U P (2012) The lure of the peak. The New RepublicGoogle Scholar
  64. Knudsen T (2004) Economic evolution without variation, selection and retention. Erwäg Wissen Ethik 15:75–78Google Scholar
  65. Levit GS, Hossfeld U, Witt U (2011) Can Darwinism be ‘generalized’ and of what use would this be? J Evol Econ 21:545–562Google Scholar
  66. Lewontin RC (1985) Adaptation. In: Levins R, Lewontin RC (eds) The dialectical biologist. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, pp 65–84Google Scholar
  67. Marciano A (2009) Why Hayek is a Darwinian (after all)? Hayek and Darwin on social evolution. J Econ Behav Organ 71:52–61Google Scholar
  68. Mayr E (2001) What evolution is? Weidenfeld & Nicolson, LondonGoogle Scholar
  69. Metcalfe JS (1998) Evolutionary economics and creative destruction. Routledge, LondonGoogle Scholar
  70. Metcalfe JS (2001) Institutions and progress. Ind Corp Change 10:561–586Google Scholar
  71. Murmann JP (2003) Knowledge and competitive advantage: the co-evolution of firms, technology and national institutions. Cambridge University Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  72. Nelson RR (1977) The moon and the ghetto. Norton, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  73. Nelson RR (1981) Assessing private enterprise: an exegesis of tangled doctrine. Bell J Econ 12:93–111Google Scholar
  74. Nelson RR (2006) Evolutionary social science and universal Darwinism. J Evol Econ 16:491–510Google Scholar
  75. Nelson RR, Winter SG (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Belknap Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  76. Ng Y-K (2006) Public policy implications of behavioral economics and happiness studies. In: Ng Y-K, Ho L-S (eds) Happiness and public policy: theory, case studies and implications. Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke, pp 237–252Google Scholar
  77. Nooteboom B (2008) Learning, discovery and collaboration. In: Nooteboom B, Stam E (eds) Microfoundations of innovation policy. Amsterdam University Press, Amsterdam, pp 75–102Google Scholar
  78. Pelikan P (1995) Competition of socioeconomic institutions: in search of the winners. In: Gerken L (ed) Competition among institutions. Macmillan, London, pp 15–45Google Scholar
  79. Pelikan P (2003) Why economic policies need comprehensive evolutionary analysis. In: Pelikan P, Wegner G (eds) The evolutionary analysis of economic policy. E. Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 15–45Google Scholar
  80. Pelikan P (2011) Evolutionary developmental economics: how to generalize Darwinism fruitfully to help comprehend economic change. J Evol Econ 21:341–366Google Scholar
  81. Pelikan P (2012) Agreeing on generalized Darwinism: a response to Geoffrey Hodgson and Thorbjørn Knudsen. J Evol Econ 22:1–8Google Scholar
  82. Popper KR (1989) Conjectures and refutations, 5th edn. Routledge, LondonGoogle Scholar
  83. Price GR (1995) The nature of selection. J Theor Biol 175:389–396Google Scholar
  84. Robbins L (1935) An essay on the nature and significance of economic science. Macmillan, LondonGoogle Scholar
  85. Rosenberg A (2000) Does evolutionary theory give comfort or inspiration to economics? In: Rosenberg A (ed) Darwinism in philosophy, social science and policy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 172–194Google Scholar
  86. Rubin PH (2002) Darwinian politics. Rutgers University Press, New BrunswickGoogle Scholar
  87. Ruse M (1996) Monad to man: the concept of progress in evolutionary biology. Harvard University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  88. Ruse M (1999) The Darwinian revolution. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  89. Ruse M (2006) Darwinism and its discontents. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  90. Ruse M (2009) Charles Darwin on human evolution. J Econ Behav Organ 71:10–19Google Scholar
  91. Schubert C (2012) Is novelty always a good thing? Towards an evolutionary welfare economics. J Evol Econ 22:585–619Google Scholar
  92. Schubert C (2013a) How to evaluate creative destruction: Reconstructing Schumpeter’s approach. Camb J Econ. doi: 10.1093/cje/bes055 Google Scholar
  93. Schubert C (2013b) The pitfalls of Darwinian “progress”: a comment on “Evolvability and progress in evolutionary economics” by Tim Cochrane and James Maclaurin. J Bioecon. doi: 10.1007/s10818-012-9146-0 Google Scholar
  94. Sen AK (1993) On the Darwinian view of progress. Pop Dev Rev 19:123–137Google Scholar
  95. Stoelhorst JW (2008a) The explanatory logic and ontological commitments of generalized Darwinism. J Econ Methodol 15:343–363Google Scholar
  96. Stoelhorst JW (2008b) Darwinian foundations for evolutionary economics. J Econ Issues 42:415–423Google Scholar
  97. Stoelhorst JW (2009) The naturalist view of Universal Darwinism: an application to the evolutionary theory of the firm. In: Hodgson GM (ed) Darwinism and economics. Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 361–379Google Scholar
  98. Sugden R (1993) Normative judgments and spontaneous order: the contractarian element in Hayek’s thought. Const Pol Econ 4:393–424Google Scholar
  99. University of Hertfordshire (2010). Businesses could learn lessons from evolution. http://www.sciencedaily.com/releases/2010/06/100629081742.htm. Accessed 10 Feb 2012
  100. Vanberg VJ (1994a) Cultural evolution, collective learning, and constitutional design. In: Reisman D (ed) Economic thought and political theory. Kluwer, Boston, pp 171–204Google Scholar
  101. Vanberg VJ (1994b) Hayek’s legacy and the future of liberal thought: rational liberalism vs. evolutionary agnosticism. J Econ Etud Hum 5:451–481Google Scholar
  102. Vanberg VJ (2006) Human intentionality and design in cultural evolution. In: Schubert C, von Wangenheim G (eds) Evolution and design of institutions. Routledge, London, pp 197–212Google Scholar
  103. Vromen J (1995) Economic evolution. An enquiry into the foundations of the new institutional economics. Routledge, LondonGoogle Scholar
  104. Vromen J (2007) Generalized Darwinism in evolutionary economics: the devil is in the details. Papers on economics and evolution, # 0711. Max Planck Institute of Economics, Jena, GermanyGoogle Scholar
  105. Vromen J (2008) Ontological issues in evolutionary economics: the debate between generalized Darwinism and the continuity hypothesis. Papers on economics & evolution # 0805. Max Planck Institute of Economics, Jena GermanyGoogle Scholar
  106. Vromen J (2010) Heterogeneous economic evolution: a different view on Darwinizing evolutionary economics. Papers on economics and evolution #1015. Max Planck Institute of Economics, Jena, GermanyGoogle Scholar
  107. Whitman DG (1998) Hayek contra Pangloss on evolutionary systems. Const Polit Econ 9:45–66Google Scholar
  108. Wilkinson W (2006) Out of position: against the politics of relative standing. Policy 22:3–9Google Scholar
  109. Wilson EO (1998) Consilience. The unity of knowledge. Knopf, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  110. Wilson DS, Gowdy J (2010) The relevance of evolutionary science for economic theory and policy. White Paper for NSF SBE Program Initiative “Framing Research for 2020 and Beyond”, draft, October 13Google Scholar
  111. Winter S (1964) Economic natural selection and the theory of the firm. Yale Econ Essays 4:225–272Google Scholar
  112. Witt U (1996a) Innovations, externalities, and the problem of economic progress. Public Choice 89:113–130Google Scholar
  113. Witt U (1996b) A “Darwinian revolution” in economics? J Inst Theoret Econ 152:707–715Google Scholar
  114. Witt U (1999) Evolutionary economics and evolutionary biology. In: Koslowski P (ed) Sociobiology and bioeconomics. Springer, Berlin, pp 279–298Google Scholar
  115. Witt U (2001) Learning to consume—a theory of wants and the growth of demand. J Evol Econ 11:23–36Google Scholar
  116. Witt U (2002) How evolutionary is Schumpeter’s theory of economic development? Ind Inn 9:7–22Google Scholar
  117. Witt U (2003a) Generic features of evolution and its continuity: a transdisciplinary perspective. Theoria 18:273–288Google Scholar
  118. Witt U (2003b) Economic policy making in evolutionary perspective. J Evol Econ 13:77–94Google Scholar
  119. Witt U (2004) On the proper interpretation of “evolution” in economics and its implications for the theory of production. J Econ Methodol 11:125–146Google Scholar
  120. Witt U (2008a) Heuristic twists and ontological creeds—road map for evolutionary economics. In: Hanappi H, Elsner W (eds) Advances in evolutionary institutional economics. Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 9–34Google Scholar
  121. Witt U (2008b) What is specific about evolutionary economics? J Evol Econ 18:547–575Google Scholar
  122. Witt U, Cordes C (2007) Selection, learning and Schumpeterian dynamics—a conceptual debate. In: Hanusch H, Pyka A (eds) The Elgar companion to neo-Schumpeterian economics. Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 316–328Google Scholar
  123. Wohlgemuth M (2002) Evolutionary approaches to politics. Kyklos 55:223–246Google Scholar
  124. Wörsdorfer JS (2009) When do social norms replace status-seeking consumption? An application to the consumption of cleanliness. Metroecon 61:35–67Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Brandenburg University of TechnologyCottbusGermany

Personalised recommendations