Advertisement

Journal of Evolutionary Economics

, Volume 16, Issue 1–2, pp 109–135 | Cite as

Innovation strategy and the patenting behavior of firms

  • Carine PeetersEmail author
  • Bruno van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie
Regular Article

Abstract

This paper investigates whether firms’ innovation strategies affect their patenting behavior, as measured by both the probability of having a patent portfolio and the number of active patents held. Three main dimensions of an innovation strategy are taken into account: the relative importance of basic research, applied research and development work in total R&D activities, the product or process orientation of innovation efforts, and the extent to which firms enter into collaborative R&D with other institutions. The major findings can be summarized as follows: (1) taking into account the various dimensions of an innovation strategy turns out to approximate the patenting behavior of firms better than the traditional Schumpeterian hypotheses related to firm size and market power; (2) there is a positive relationship between the patent portfolio of firms and an outward-oriented innovation strategy characterized by R&D partnerships with external organizations - scientific institutions and competitors in particular; (3) process-oriented innovators patent less than product-oriented innovators; (4) a stronger focus on basic and applied research is associated with a more active patenting behavior; (5) firms that perceive high barriers to innovation (internal, risk-related or external barriers) have smaller patent portfolios; (6) the perceived limitations of the patent system do not significantly influence the patenting behavior, suggesting that firms patent for other strategic reasons than merely protecting innovation rents.

Keywords

Product innovation Innovation strategy Collaborative R&D Patent portfolio Patent system 

JEL Classification

O31 O32 O34 L25 

References

  1. Arora A (1997) Patents, licensing, and market structure in chemicals. Res Policy 26(4–5):391–403CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Arrow K (1962) Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In: Nelson RR (ed) The rate and direction of inventive activity. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
  3. Arundel A (2001) The relative effectiveness of patents and secrecy for appropriation. Res Policy 30(4):611–624CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Arundel A, Kabla I (1998) What percentage of innovations is patented? Res Policy 27(2):127–141CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Baldwin JR, Hanel P, Sabourin D (2002) Determinants of innovative activity in Canadian manufacturing firms. In: Kleinknecht A, Mohnen P (eds) Innovation and firm performance: econometric explorations of survey data. Palgrave, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  6. Baumol WJ (2002) The free market innovation machine. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
  7. Brouwer E, Kleinknecht A (1999) Innovative output and a firm propensity to patent. An exploration of CIS Micro data. Res Policy 28(6):615–624CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Cassiman B, Pérez-Castrillo D, Veugelers R (2001) Endogenizing know-how flows through the nature of R&D investments. Int J Ind Organ 20(6):775–799CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Cohen WM, Levin RC (1989) Empirical studies of innovation and market structure. In: Schmalensee R, Willig RD (eds) Handbook of industrial organization, North-Holland, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
  10. Cohen WM, Nelson RR, Walsh JP (2000) Protecting their intellectual assets: appropriability conditions and why US manufacturing firms patent (or not), NBER Working Paper, No. 7552Google Scholar
  11. Crépon B, Duguet E, Kabla I (1996) Schumpeterian conjectures: a moderate support from various innovation measures. In: Kleinknecht A (ed) Determinants of innovation—the message from new indicators, Palgrave, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  12. Crépon B, Duguet E, Mairesse J (1998) Research, innovation, and productivity: an econometric analysis at the firm level. Econ Innov New Technol 7(2):115–158CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Duguet E, Kabla I (1998) Appropriation strategy and the motivations to use the patent system: an econometric analysis at the firm level in French manufacturing. Ann Écon Stat 49/50:289–327Google Scholar
  14. Gilbert R, Newberry D (1982) Preemptive patenting and the persistence of monopoly. Am Econ Rev 72(3):514–526Google Scholar
  15. Glazier SC (2000) Patent strategies for business, L B I Law & Business InstituteGoogle Scholar
  16. Griliches Z (1990) Patent statistics as economic indicators: a survey. J Econ Lit 28(4):1661–1707Google Scholar
  17. Hall BH, Griliches Z, Hausman JA (1986) Patents and R and D: is there a lag? Int Econ Rev 27(2):265–283CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Hausman JA, Hall BH, Griliches Z (1984) Econometric models for count data with an application to the patents-R&D relationship. Econometrica 52(4):909–938CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Levin RC, Klerovick AK, Nelson RR, Winter SG (1987) Appropriating the returns from industrial research and development. Brookings Pap Econ Act 1987(3):783–831CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Lööf H, Heshmati A (2002) Knowledge capital and performance heterogeneity: an innovation study at firm level. Int J Prod Econ 76(1):61–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Mansfield E (1986) Patents and innovation: an empirical study. Manag Sci 32(2):173–181CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Mansfield E, Schwartz M, Wagner S (1981) Imitation costs and patents: an empirical study. Econ J 91(364):907–918CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Nelson RR (1959) The simple economics of basic scientific research. J Polit Econ 67(3):297–306CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Nielsen AO (2001) Patenting, R&D and market structure: manufacturing firms in Denmark. Technol Forecast Soc Change 66(1):47–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Parr RL, Sullivan PH (1996) Technology licensing, Wiley, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  26. Peeters C, van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie B (2003a) Measuring innovation competencies and performances—a survey of large firms in Belgium, IIR Working Paper No. 03–16Google Scholar
  27. Peeters C, van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie B (2003b) Organizational competencies and innovation performances—the case of large firms in Belgium, IIR Working Paper No. 03–19Google Scholar
  28. Reitzig M (2004) Strategic management of intellectual property. Sloan Manage Rev 45(3):35–40Google Scholar
  29. Rivette KG, Kline D (2000) Discovering new value in intellectual property. Harvard Bus Rev 78:54–66Google Scholar
  30. Scherer FM (1965) Firm size, market structure, opportunity, and the output of patented inventions. Am Econ Rev 55(5):1097–1125Google Scholar
  31. Scherer FM (1983) The propensity to patent. Int J Ind Org 1(1):107–128CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Schmookler J (1957) Inventors past and present. Rev Econ Stat 39(3):321–333CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Schumpeter JA (1942) Capitalism, socialism and democracy, Harper, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  34. Scotchmer S and Green J (1990) Novelty and disclosure in patent law. RAND J Econ 21(1):131–146CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Sherry EF, Teece DJ (2004) Royalties, evolving patent rights, and the value of innovation. Res Policy 33(2):179–191CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Teece DJ (1998) Capturing value from knowledge assets: the new economy, markets for know-how, and intangibles assets. Calif Manage Rev 40(3):55–79Google Scholar
  37. van Ophem H, Brouwer E, Kleinknecht A, Mohnen P (2001) The mutual relation between patents and R&D. In: Kleinknecht A, Mohnen P (eds) Innovation and firm performance: econometric explorations of survey data, Palgrave, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  38. Veugelers R, Cassiman B (1999) Make and buy in innovation strategies: evidence from Belgian manufacturing firms. Res Policy 28(1):63–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag 2006

Authors and Affiliations

  • Carine Peeters
    • 1
    Email author
  • Bruno van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie
    • 2
  1. 1.The Fuqua School of BusinessDuke UniversityDurhamUSA
  2. 2.Solvay Business SchoolUniversite Libre de Bruxelles (ULB), Centre Emile Bernheim, DULBEA and CEPRBrusselsBelgium

Personalised recommendations