Abstract
The paper deals with a class of parameterized equilibrium problems, where the objectives of the players do possess nonsmooth terms. The respective Nash equilibria can be characterized via a parameter-dependent variational inequality of the second kind, whose Lipschitzian stability, under appropriate conditions, is established. This theory is then applied to evolution of an oligopolistic market in which the firms adapt their production strategies to changing input costs, while each change of the production is associated with some “costs of change”. We examine both the Cournot-Nash equilibria as well as the two-level case, when one firm decides to take over the role of the Leader (Stackelberg equilibrium). The impact of costs of change is illustrated by academic examples.
Similar content being viewed by others
References
Allgower EL, Georg K (1997) Numerical path following. In: Ciarlet PG, Lions JL (eds) Techniques of scientific computing, Part 2, Handbook of Numerical Analysis, vol 5. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 3–207
Aubin J-P (1998) Optima and Equilibria. Springer, Berlin
Basilico N, Coniglio S, Gatti N, Marchesi A (2020) Bilevel programming methods for computing single-leader-multi-follower equilibria in normal-form and polymatrix games. EURO J Comput Optim 8:3–31
Brent RP (1973) Algorithms for minimization without derivatives. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs
Dempe S. Bilevel optimization: theory, algorithms and applications. Preprint 2018-11, Fakultät für Mathematik und Informatik, TU Bergakademie Freiberg
Dontchev AL, Rockafellar RT (2014) Implicit functions and solution mappings. Springer, Heidelberg
Facchinei F, Pang J-S (2003) Finite-dimensional variational inequalities and complementarity problems. Springer, Berlin
Flåm SD (2020) Games and cost of change. Ann Oper Res. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-020-03585-w
Frost M, Kružík M, Valdman J (2019) Interfacial polyconvex energy-enhanced evolutionary model for shape memory alloys. Math Mech Solids 24:2619–2635
Gfrerer H, Outrata JV (2016) On Lipschitzian properties of implicit multifunctions. SIAM J Optim 26:2160–2189
Gfrerer H, Outrata JV (2019) On a semismooth\(^{*}\) Newton method for solving generalized equations. arXiv:1904.09167
Kanzow Ch, Schwartz A (2018) Spieltheorie. Springer, Cham
Kinderlehrer D, Stampacchia G (1980) An introduction to variational inequalities and their applications. Academic Press, New York
Mielke A, Roubíček T (2015) Rate-Independent systems - theory and applications. Springer, New York
Murphy MH, Sherali AD, Soyster AL (1982) A mathematical programming approach for determining oligopolistic market equilibria. Math Prog 24:92–106
Outrata JV, Kočvara M, Zowe J (1998) Nonsmooth approach to optimization problems with equilibrium constraints. Kluwer, Dordrecht
Poliquin RA, Rockafellar RT (1998) Tilt stability of a local minimum. SIAM J Optim 8:287–299
Robinson SM (1976) An implicit function theorem for generalized variational inequalities. Technical Summary Report 1672, Mathematics Research Center, University of Wisconsin–Madison
Rockafellar RT, Wets RJ-B (1998) Variational Analysis. Springer, Berlin
Zhu DL, Marcotte P (1996) Co-coercivity and its role in the convergence of iterative schemes for solving variational inequalities. SIAM J Optim 6:714–726
Acknowledgements
The authors are deeply indebted to both Reviewers and the Associated Editor for their careful reading and numerous important suggestions. The also benefited from valuable advices of T. Roubíček.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
The research of J. V. Outrata was supported by the Czech Science Foundation (GA ČR), through the Grant 17-08182S and by the Australian Research Council, Project DP160100854F. The research of J. Valdman was supported by the Czech Science Foundation (GA ČR), through the Grant 17-04301S.
APPENDIX
APPENDIX
In some models of practical importance function q is piecewise linear-quadratic. Then the assumption of positive definiteness of \(\nabla _{x}F(\bar{p},\bar{x})\) in Proposition 1 can be somewhat relaxed.
Proposition 2
Assume that \(\tilde{q}\) is convex, piecewise linear-quadratic and the mapping \(\varXi : \mathbb {R}^{s} \rightrightarrows \mathbb {R}^{s}\) defined by
with \(\varphi (k):=\frac{1}{2} d^{2}q (\bar{x}| -F(\bar{p},\bar{x}))(k)\) is single-valued on \(\mathbb {R}^{s}\). Then S has a single-valued and Lipschitzian localization around \((\bar{p},\bar{x})\).
Proof
By virtue of (Dontchev and Rockafellar 2014, Theorem 3G.4) it suffices to show that the single-valuedness of \(\varXi \) implies the existence of a single-valued and Lipschitzian localization of \(\varSigma \) (defined in (6)) around \((0,\bar{x})\). Clearly,
so that \(\varSigma \) is a polyhedral multifunction due to our assumptions imposed on \( \tilde{q}\), cf. (Rockafellar and Wets 1998, Theorem 12.30). It follows from Robinson (1976) (see also (Outrata et al. 1998, Cor.2.5)) that due to the polyhedrality of \(\varSigma \), it suffices to ensure the single-valuedness of \(\varSigma (\cdot ) \cap \mathcal {V}\) on \(\mathcal {U}\), where \(\mathcal {U}\) is a convex neighborhood of \(0 \in \mathbb {R}^{s}\) and \(\mathcal {V}\) is a neighborhood of \(\bar{x}\). Let us select these neighborhoods in such a way that
which is possible due to the polyhedrality of \(\partial \tilde{q}\). Then one has
Under the posed assumptions for any \(k \in \mathbb {R}^{n}\)
cf. (Rockafellar and Wets 1998, Theorem 13.40), so that \(\mathrm {gph}\,\varSigma \cap (\mathcal {U} \times \mathcal {V})=\{(w,\bar{x} +k)\in \mathcal {U} \times \mathcal {V} | (w,k)\in \mathrm {gph}\,\varXi \}\). Since \(D \partial \tilde{q}(\bar{x},- F(\bar{p},\bar{x}))(\cdot )\) is positively homogeneous, \(\partial \varphi (\cdot )\) is positively homogeneous as well and so the single-valuedness of \(\varSigma (\cdot )\cap \mathcal {V}\) on \(\mathcal {U}\) amounts exactly to the single-valuedness of \(\varXi \) on \(\mathbb {R}^{s}\). \(\square \)
On the basis of (Rockafellar and Wets 1998, Proposition 13.9) the single-valuedness of \(\varXi \) can be ensured via the notion of copositivity. Recall that an [\(s \times s\)] matrix H is strictly copositive with respect to a cone \(\mathcal {K} \subset \mathbb {R}^s\) provided
Proposition 3
Assume that \(\tilde{q}\) is convex, piecewise linear-quadratic and \( \tilde{q}^{\prime \prime }(\bar{x};\cdot )\) is convex. Further suppose that \(\nabla _{x}F(\bar{p},\bar{x})\) is strictly copositive with respect to \(K-K\), where
Then S has a single-valued and Lipschitzian localization around \((\bar{p},\bar{x})\).
Proof
By virtue of (Rockafellar and Wets 1998, Proposition 13.9) the second subderivative \(d^{2}\tilde{q}(\bar{x}| -F(\bar{p},\bar{x}))(\cdot )\) is proper convex and piecewise linear-quadratic and one has
It remains to show that mapping (16) is single-valued. Clearly, the GE in (16) can be written down in the form
where the multifunction \(\varPsi (k):= \nabla _x F(\bar{p},\bar{x}) k + \partial \frac{1}{2} \tilde{q}''(\bar{x};k).\) As explained in (Outrata et al. 1998, Theorem 4.6), under the posed assumptions there is a positive real \(\alpha \) such that
It follows that for all \(k_1, k_2 \in K, \xi _1 \in \partial \frac{1}{2} \tilde{q}''(\bar{x};k_1), \xi _2 \in \partial \frac{1}{2} \tilde{q}''(\bar{x};k_2)\) and
one has
We conclude that \(\Phi \) is strongly monotone on K and, consequently, \(\varXi \) is single-valued by virtue of (Rockafellar and Wets 1998, Proposition 12.54). \(\square \)
Example 1
Put \(m=2, s=1\) and consider the GE (4), where
and the reference pair \((\bar{p},\bar{x})=((-1,1),0)\). Since \(\nabla _x F(\bar{p},\bar{x})=1\), Proposition 1 applies and we may conclude that the respective mapping S has indeed the single-valued and Lipschitzian localization around \( (\bar{p},\bar{x})\).
To compute \(DS (\bar{p},\bar{x})\), we may employ formula (7), where \(\partial \varphi \) is computed according to (17). One has \(K(\bar{x},\bar{v})=\mathbb {R}_{+}, \tilde{q}^{\prime \prime } (\bar{x},w)=0\) for any \(w\in \mathbb {R}_{+}\) and so we obtain that
This yields the formula
valid for all \(h\in \mathbb {R}^2\). Both mappings S and \(DS (\bar{p},\bar{x})\) are depicted in Fig.3. \(\triangle \)
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Outrata, J.V., Valdman, J. On computation of optimal strategies in oligopolistic markets respecting the cost of change. Math Meth Oper Res 92, 489–509 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00186-020-00721-x
Received:
Revised:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00186-020-00721-x