Skip to main content
Log in

Receiver’s sensitivity and strategic information transmission in multi-sender cheap talk

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Journal of Game Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study examines how a CEO’s sensitivity affects information transmission from multiple unit managers when they communicate strategically during decision-making for technology investment. We develop a simple cheap talk model comprising one CEO and K unit managers, wherein the CEO makes a decision to maximize the units’ profit after the managers reveal their preference for the decision through cheap talk. We demonstrate that the expected total profit improves when sensitivity to the opinion of a manager whose expected preference is moderate among all managers increases. The driving force of the results is termed as alignment effect; increasing sensitivity to a moderate opinion decreases the difference between the expected CEO’s decision and the managers’ ideals. Furthermore, some implications on the decision-making process in technology investment within firms are discussed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Resource allocation within a firm and strategic behavior of unit managers have been important issues in the internal capital market literature. Gertner and Scharfstein (2013) provide a useful survey.

  2. Indeed, early empirical studies (e.g., Montgomery and Hariharan (1991)) have demonstrated that related diversification is a common practice.

  3. An exception is Dessein et al. (2010). They investigated decision-making for synergy creation in the win-lose situation where standardization increases the profit of one unit but decreases that of another.

  4. Rumelt (1982) and Nesta and Saviotti (2005) demonstrate that related diversification is positively associated with higher financial performance. Additionally, Montgomery (1994) conducts a survey on this issue.

  5. Li et al. (2016) study a situation wherein one uninformed DM choses either of two projects after consulting two responsible senders who observe the quality of only their project.

  6. Melumad and Shibano (1991) study one-to-one communication under this assumption.

  7. One exception is McGee and Yang (2013). They study strategic information transmission between one receiver and two senders with independent private information when the receiver’s ideal decision is multiplicative in the senders’ information. They demonstrate that strategic complementarity exists in senders’ strategies.

  8. If this assumption holds, the equilibrium analysis and the following comparative statics become tractable. See Sects. 4.2 and 4.3 for details.

  9. This assumption is plausible because specific information on each business is required to expect the impact of a new technology, for example, specific technical characteristics of the product, potential needs of consumers, and number of potential competitors.

  10. All the missing proofs and derivations hereafter are presented in the Appendix.

  11. The form of equation (2) is similar to that of Alonso et al. (2008). An important difference between their model and ours is that in their model, \(q_i (\alpha )\) is assumed to be zero because they assume the mean of the senders’ information to be zero.

  12. Generically, this condition is not sufficient for the existence of an infinite-portioned equilibrium; for an example of this, see Alonso (2008).

  13. Several studies have suggested that CEOs’ characteristics or preferences significantly affect corporate decisions. For example, a CEO who is assigned to grow a certain product division may favor increasing the division’s performance in terms of their career concern (Gibbons and Murphy (1992)). Similarly, CEOs overinvest in businesses related to their background and experience, thereby making it difficult to oust them when they perform poorly (Shleifer and Vishny (1989)). Bertrand and Schoar (2003) empirically show that the difference between the characteristics of top managers significantly affects a wide range of corporate practices such as investment policy, financial policy, organizational strategy, and performance.

    Some theoretical studies on organizational economics have demonstrated that managers’ (irrational) characteristics and biased preferences aid in better decision-making because they work as a commitment device when state-contingent contracts are not feasible. For example, scholars have investigated CEOs’ visions (Rotemberg and Saloner (2000)), leaders’ resoluteness (Bolton et al. (2012)), and supervisors’ favoritism (Prendergast and Topel (1996)).

  14. The deviation is straightforward from Eq.  (5) and its first derivative with respect to e.

  15. The marginal effect of e on the DM’s expected payoff is represented by

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{ 2 }{ (e+2)^2 (3e+11)^2 (4e+11)^2 } \left( - 40 e (e+2)^2 (7e+22) s^2 + (3e+11)^2 (8e^2 + 24e +13) c^2 \right) . \end{aligned}$$

    At \(e=0\), the first term in the bracket is equal to zero, whereas the second term is strictly positive as long as \(c>0\).

  16. Christensen (1997) states, “As firms gain experience within a given network, they are likely to develop capabilities, organizational structures, and cultures tailored to their value network’s distinctive requirements. (...) organizational consensus identifying the customers and the customer’s needs may differ substantially from one value network to the next.”

References

  • Alonso R “Shared control and strategic communication”, Mimeo (2008)

  • Alonso R, Dessein W, Matouschek N (2008) When does coordination require centralization? Am Econ Rev 98(1):145–179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ambrus A, Takahashi S (2008) Multi-sender cheap talk with restricted state spaces. Theoretical Econ 3(1):1–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith D (1993) Interested experts and policy advice: multiple referrals under open rule. Games Econ Behav 5(1):3–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battaglini M (2002) Multiple referrals and multidimensional cheap talk. Econometrica 70(4):1379–1401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand M, Schoar A (2003) Managing with style: the effect of managers on firm policies. Q J Econ 118(4):1169–1208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton P, Brunnermeier MK, Veldkamp L (2012) Leadership, coordination, and corporate culture. Rev Econ Stud 80(2):512–537

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christensen CM (1997) The innovator’s dilemma: when new technologies cause great firms to fail. Harvard Business Review Press,

  • Crawford VP, Sobel J (1982) Strategic information transmission. Econometrica 1982:1431–1451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dessein W, Garicano L, Gertner R (2010) Organizing for synergies. Am Econ J 2:77–114

    Google Scholar 

  • Galeotti A, Ghiglino C, Squintani F (2013) Strategic information transmission networks. J Econ Theory 148(5):1751–1769

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gertner R, Scharfstein D (2013) “Internal capital market”, in Gibbons and Roberts (Eds.) The handbook of organizational economics, Princeton University Press, 655-679

  • Gilligan TW, Krehbiel K (1987) Collective decisionmaking and standing committees: an informational rationale for restrictive amendment procedures. J Law Econ Org 3(2):287–335

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons R, Murphy KJ (1992) Optimal incentive contracts in the presence of career concerns: Theory and evidence. J Political Econ 100(3):468–505

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishna V, Morgan J (2001A) A model of expertise. Q J Econ 116(2):747–775

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishna V, Morgan J (2001B) Asymmetric information and legislative rules: some amendments. Am Political Sci Rev 95(2):435–452

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li Z, Rantakari H, Yang H (2016) Competitive cheap talk. Games Econ Behav 96:65–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melumad ND, Shibano T (1991) Communication in settings with no transfers. The RAND Journal of Economics 173–198

  • Montgomery CA (1994) Corporate Diversificaton. J Econ Perspectives 8(3):163–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montgomery CA, Hariharan S (1991) Diversified expansion by large established firms. J Econ Behav Org 15(1):71–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morgan J, Stocken PC (2008) Information aggregation in polls. Am Econ Rev 98(3):864–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGee A, Yang H (2013) Cheap talk with two senders and complementary information. Games Econ Behav 79:181–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nesta L, Saviotti PP (2005) Coherence of the knowledge base and the firm’s innovative performance: Evidence from the US pharmaceutical industry. J Ind Econ 53(1):123–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prendergast C, Topel RH (1996) Favoritism in organizations. J Political Econ 104(5):958–978

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan R, Servaes H, Zingales L (2000) The cost of diversity: the diversification discount and inefficient investment. J Finance 55(1):35–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rantakari H (2008) Governing adaptation. Rev Econ Stud 75(4):1257–1285

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rotemberg JJ, Saloner G (2000) Visionaries, managers, and strategic direction. RAND Journal of Economics 693–716

  • Rumelt RP (1982) Diversification strategy and profitability. Strategic Manag J 3(4):359–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer A, Vishny RW (1989) Management entrenchment: the case of manager-specific investments. J Financial Econ 25(1):123–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang H, Zhang L (2018) Communication and the optimality of hierarchy in organizations. J Law Econ Org 35(1):154–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hiromasa Ogawa.

Ethics declarations

Disclosure of potential conflicts of interest

The author has received research grants from Japan Society for the Promotion of Science Grant-in-Aid for Young Scientists (B:16K17083).

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The author appreciates financial support from Japan Society for the Promotion of Science Grant-in-Aid for Young Scientists (B:16K17083). The author thanks the editor, the associate editor, and two anonymous referees for providing constructive suggestions that greatly improved the article. All remaining errors are the author’s responsibility.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Derivation of experts’ strategy and (2)

We first show that the equilibrium communication strategy in any perfect Bayesian equilibrium is of the interval form. Let two different posterior expectation of \(\theta _i\) induced in an equilibrium be \(m', m''\) and suppose \(m' < m''\). Given that \(d = d^*\), \(\frac{ \partial ^2 E [\pi _i | \theta _i, m_i ] }{ \partial \theta _i^2 } = - 1 < 0\) and \(\frac{ \partial ^2 E [\pi _i | \theta _i, m_i ] }{ \partial m_i \partial \theta _i } = \frac{ 2\alpha _i}{\sum _l \alpha _l} > 0\). Then, for \(m'\) and \(m''\), there exists, at most, one type of expert who is indifferent between both. Suppose that \( \theta _i' < \theta _i''\) and \( E [ \pi _i | \theta _i', m'' ] \ge E [ \pi _i | \theta _i', m' ] \) and \( E [ \pi _i | \theta _i'', m' ] > E [ \pi _i | \theta _i'', m'' ] \). Then, \( E [ \pi _i | \theta _i', m'' ] - E [ \pi _i | \theta _i', m' ] > E [ \pi _i | \theta _i'', m'' ] - E [ \pi _i | \theta _i'', m' ] \), which is contradiction.

When the expert induces \(m'\), the expected DM’s decision from expert i’s perspective is given by \(E[ d | m_i = m' ] = \frac{ \alpha _i }{ \sum _{l} \alpha _l } (m' + c_i) + \sum _{k \ne i} \frac{ \alpha _k }{ \sum _{l} \alpha _l } (E[m_k] + c_k)\). Substituting this into the indifferent condition, we obtain equation (2) as follows;

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{ \alpha _i }{ \sum _{k} \alpha _k } ( ( m_{i,j+1} + c_i )^2 - ( m_{i,j} + c_i )^2 ) + 2 (m_{i,j+1} - m_{i,j}) \sum _{k \ne i} ( E [ m_k ] + c_k ) \\&\qquad - 2 (m_{i,j+1} - m_{i,j}) (a_{i,j} + c_i) = 0 \\&\rightarrow m_{i,j+1} + m_{i,j} + 2 c_i + 2 \frac{ \sum _l \alpha _l }{ \alpha _i } \sum _{k \ne i} ( E [ m_k ] + c_k ) - 2 \frac{ \sum _l \alpha _l }{ \alpha _i } ( a_{i,j} + c_i )= 0 \\&\rightarrow a_{i,j+1} - a_{i,j} = a_{i,j} - a_{i,j-1} + 4 \frac{ \sum _{k \ne i} \alpha _k (a_{i,j} + c_i) - \sum _{k \ne i} \alpha _k ( E [ m_k ] + c_k ) }{ \alpha _i }. \end{aligned}$$

Together with the boundary conditions \(a_{i,0} = -s_i\) and \(a_{i,N_i} = s_i\), the second-order difference Eq. (2) has the following solution in explicit form;

$$\begin{aligned} a_{i,j} = \frac{ \displaystyle x (\alpha _i)^{j} - y (\alpha _i)^{j} }{ \displaystyle x (\alpha _i)^{N_i} - y (\alpha _i)^{N_i} } (s_i - q_i (\alpha ) ) + \frac{ \displaystyle x (\alpha _i)^{N_i-j} - y (\alpha _i)^{N_i-j} }{ \displaystyle x (\alpha _i)^{N_i} - y (\alpha _i)^{N_i} } (- s_i - q_i (\alpha ) ) + q_i (\alpha )\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where \(x (\alpha _i) = - \left( 1 - \frac{2 \sum _l \alpha _l }{\alpha _i} \right) + \sqrt{ \left( 1 - \frac{2 \sum _l \alpha _l }{\alpha _i} \right) ^2 - 1} \) and \(y (\alpha _i) = - \left( 1 - \frac{2 \sum _l \alpha _l}{\alpha _i} \right) - \sqrt{ \left( 1 - \frac{2 \sum _l \alpha _l}{\alpha _i} \right) ^2 - 1}\). Note that \(x (\alpha _i) \cdot y (\alpha _i) = 1\).

1.2 The properties regarding to communication strategy and the proofs

Property 1

For \(i=1,2,...,K\), the upper bound of \(N_i\) does not exist if \( q_i ( \alpha ) \in [ - s_i, s_i ]\).

Proof

It is straightforward to check that \( \{ a_{i,j} \}_{j = 0,1,...N_i} \) satisfy boundary constraints that \(a_{i,0} = - s_i \) and \(a_{i,N_i} = s_i\) for any \(N_i\). Then, we show that \( \{ a_{i,j} \}_{j = 0,1,...N_i} \) satisfy the order constraints. Since \(x (\alpha _i) > y (\alpha _i)\), \(\displaystyle x (\alpha _i)^{j} - y (\alpha _i)^{j}\) is strictly increased and \(\displaystyle x (\alpha _i)^{N_i-j} - y (\alpha _i)^{N_i-j}\) is strictly decreased as j increases. Then, for any \(N_i\), the first term of (10) is not decreasing in j if \( s_i \ge q_i (\alpha )\) and strictly increasing in j if \( s_i > q_i (\alpha ) \), and the second term of (10) is not decreasing in j if \( - s_i \le q_i (\alpha )\) and strictly increasing in j if \( - s_i < q_i (\alpha )\). Then, if \( - s_i \le q_i (\alpha ) \le s_i\), \(a_{i,j}\) is strictly increasing in j. \(\square \)

Property 2

\(E[ m_i^2]\) is increasing in \(N_i\).

Proof

After lengthy calculations, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} E[m_i^2]= & {} \sum _{j=0}^{N_i-1} \int _{a_{i,j}}^{a_{i,j+1}} \left( \frac{a_{i,j+1} + a_{i,j}}{2} \right) ^2 \frac{1}{2 s_i } d \theta _i \nonumber \\= & {} \frac{1}{8 s_i} \sum _{j=0}^{N_i-1} ( a_{i,j+1}^3 + a_{i,j+1}^2 a_{i,j} - a_{i,j+1} a_{i,j}^2 - a_{i,j}^3 ) \nonumber \\= & {} \frac{1}{4} \frac{x(\alpha _i)^2 + 2 x(\alpha _i) + 1}{x(\alpha _i)^2 + x(\alpha _i) + 1} s_i^2 - \frac{1}{4} \frac{x(\alpha _i)^2 - 2 x(\alpha _i) + 1}{x(\alpha _i)^2 + x(\alpha _i) + 1} q_i(\alpha )^2 \nonumber \\&- \frac{1}{4} \frac{ (x(\alpha _i)^2-1)^2}{ x(\alpha _i) (x(\alpha _i)^2 + x(\alpha _i) + 1) } \left( \frac{ x(\alpha _i)^{N_i} }{ (x(\alpha _i)^{N_i}+1)^2 } (s_i^2 - q_i (\alpha )^2) \nonumber \right. \\&\left. + \frac{ 4 x(\alpha _i)^{2N_i} }{ (x(\alpha _i)^{2N_i}-1)^2 } s_i^2 \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(11)

The first and second term in (11) is independent of \(N_i\). Since \(x (\alpha _i) > 1\) and \(s_i> q_i(\alpha ) > -s_i\), the third term in (11) is positive.

To check whether the third term in (11) is decreasing in \(N_i\), we define

$$\begin{aligned} f(X) = \frac{1}{4} \frac{ (x(\alpha _i)^2-1)^2}{ x(\alpha _i) (x(\alpha _i)^2 + x(\alpha _i) + 1) } \left( \frac{ X }{ (X+1)^2 } (s_i^2 - q_i(\alpha )^2) + \frac{ 4 X^2 }{ (X^2-1)^2 } s_i^2 \right) , \end{aligned}$$

and note that

$$\begin{aligned} f'(X) = \dfrac{1}{4} \dfrac{ (x(\alpha _i)^2-1)^2}{ x(\alpha _i) (x(\alpha _i)^2 + x(\alpha _i) + 1) } \left( \dfrac{ -X^2 + 1 }{ (X+1)^4 } (s_i^2 - q_i(\alpha )^2) + \dfrac{ -2 X^5 - 2X }{ (X^2-1)^4 } s_i^2 \right) . \end{aligned}$$

Since \(f'(X)>0\) for \(X>1\), the third term in (11) is strictly decreasing in \(N_i\), then \(E[m_i^2]\) strictly increases in \(N_i\). Equation (5) can be derived by substituting \(x (\alpha _i) = - \left( 1 - \frac{2 \sum _l \alpha _l }{\alpha _i} \right) + \sqrt{ (1 - \frac{2 \sum _l \alpha _l}{\alpha _i} )^2 - 1} \) into (11), and taking the limit of \(N_i\) (then, the third term in (11) become zero). \(\square \)

Property 3

\(E[ \pi ]\) and \(E[ \pi _i ]\) are increasing in \(E[ m_i^2]\).

Proof

First, we show that \(E[ \pi _i ]\) is increasing in \(E[ m_i^2]\). Substituting \( d^* = \sum _{k} \frac{ \alpha _k }{ \sum _{l} \alpha _l } (m_k + c_k) \) into \( E[ \pi _i ] \), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} E[ \pi _i ]= & {} - E \left[ \left( \sum _{k} \frac{ \alpha _k }{ \sum _{l} \alpha _l } (m_k + c_k) - \theta _i - c_i \right) ^2 \right] \nonumber \\= & {} \frac{ \alpha _i }{ \sum _{l} \alpha _l } \left( 2 - \frac{ \alpha _i }{ \sum _{l} \alpha _l } \right) E [ m_i^2 ] - E [ \theta _i^2 ] - \left( \frac{ \alpha _i }{ \sum _{l} \alpha _l } - 1 \right) ^2 c_i^2 \nonumber \\&- \sum _{k \ne i} \left( \frac{ \alpha _k }{ \sum _{l} \alpha _l } \right) ^2 ( E[m_k^2] + c_k^2 ) \nonumber \\&- 2 \left( \frac{ \alpha _i }{ \sum _{l} \alpha _l } - 1 \right) \sum _{k \ne i} \frac{ \alpha _k }{ \sum _{l} \alpha _l } c_i c_k - \sum _{j \ne i} \sum _{k \ne i, j} \frac{ \alpha _j \alpha _k }{ (\sum _{l} \alpha _l)^2 } c_j c_k. \end{aligned}$$
(12)

The second equality follows from the facts \( E[ m_i ] = 0\), \( E[ \theta _i m_i ] = E [ E[ \theta _i m_i | r_i ] ] = E [ m_i E[ \theta _i | r_i ] ] = E[ m_i^2 ]\), and \(E[ \theta _i m_j ] = E[ \theta _i] E[ m_j ] = 0\) for \(j \ne i\). Immediately, \(E[ \pi _i ]\) is increasing in \(E [ m_i^2 ]\).

Finally, we show that \(E[ \pi ]\) is increasing in \(E[ m_1^2],...,E[ m_K^2]\). Summing (12) with i, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} E[ \pi ] = \sum _i \alpha _i \left( - E[ \theta _i^2] + \frac{ \alpha _i }{ \sum _{l} \alpha _l } E[ m_i^2] - \frac{1}{2} \sum _{k \ne i} \frac{ \alpha _k }{ \sum _{l} \alpha _l } (c_i - c_k)^2 \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(13)

Then, \(E[ \pi ]\) is increasing in \(E[ m_1^2],...,E[ m_K^2]\). \(\square \)

1.3 Proof of Proposition 2

The first term in (6) is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \frac{\partial M_i}{\partial \alpha _i}(\alpha , q) \right| _{ \displaystyle q = q_i (\alpha ) }= & {} \frac{ \sum _{k \ne i} \alpha _k }{ (4 \sum _{k \ne i} \alpha _k + 3\alpha _i)^2 } s_i^2 \nonumber \\&+ \frac{ 3 \sum _{k \ne i}\alpha _k }{ (4 \sum _{k \ne i} \alpha _k + 3\alpha _i)^2 } \left( \frac{ \sum _{k \ne i} \alpha _k (c_k - c_i) }{ \sum _{k \ne i} \alpha _k } \right) ^2 \end{aligned}$$
(14)

and is always positive. Since \(q_i (\alpha )\) is independent of \(\alpha _i\), \(\frac{ \partial q_i }{ \partial \alpha _i } (\alpha ) = 0\). Then, the second term in (6) becomes zero. Thus, the marginal effect of \(\alpha _i\) on \({{\hat{M}}}_i ( \alpha ) \) is always positive. \(\square \)

1.4 Proof of Proposition 3

The first term in (7) is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \frac{\partial M_j}{\partial \alpha _i}(\alpha , q) \right| _{ \displaystyle q = q_j (\alpha ) }= & {} - \frac{ \alpha _j }{ (4 \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k + 3\alpha _j)^2 } s_j^2 \nonumber \\&- \frac{ 3 \alpha _j }{ (4 \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k + 3\alpha _j)^2 } \left( \frac{ \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k (c_k - c_j) }{ \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k } \right) ^2 \end{aligned}$$
(15)

and is always negative. The second term in (7) is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial M_j }{ \partial q_j } ( \alpha , q_j (\alpha ) ) \cdot \frac{ \partial q_j }{ \partial \alpha _{i} } (\alpha ) = \frac{ 2 (\sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k (c_k - c_j) ) ( \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k (c_k - c_i) ) }{ ( 4 \sum _{ k \ne j} \alpha _k + 3 \alpha _j ) (\sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k)^2}. \end{aligned}$$
(16)

Summing (15) and (16) and rearranging it, we obtain \(\frac{ \partial {{\hat{M}}}_j }{ \partial \alpha _i } ( \alpha )\) as follows;

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial {{\hat{M}}}_j }{ \partial \alpha _i } ( \alpha )= & {} \frac{ 1 }{ \left( 4 \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k + 3 \alpha _j \right) ^2 \left( \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k \right) ^2 } \nonumber \\&\left( \underbrace{ - \alpha _j \left( \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k \right) ^2 s_j^2 - 3 \alpha _j \left( \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k (c_j - c_k) \right) ^2 }_{\text {The sensitivity effect}} \right. \nonumber \\&+ \left. \underbrace{2 \left( 4\sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k + 3 \alpha _j \right) \left( \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k (c_k - c_j) \right) \left( \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k (c_k - c_i) \right) }_{\text {The alignment effect}} \right) . \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(17)

The sign of the alignment effect equals to the sign of \(\sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k (c_k - c_j) \cdot \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k (c_k - c_i)\). Then, it is strictly positive if and only if \(c_i > \frac{\sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k c_k}{ \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k }\) and \(c_j > \frac{\sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k c_k}{ \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k }\) or \(c_i < \frac{\sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k c_k}{ \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k }\) and \(c_j < \frac{\sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k c_k}{ \sum _{k \ne j} \alpha _k }\).

Finally, we provide an example in which the cross effect is positive. Let \(\alpha _i = 1\) for \(i = 1,...,K\) and \(c_i = c_j\). Substituting these into (17) and utilizing \(q_j (\alpha ) = \frac{\sum _{k \ne j} (c_k - c_j)}{ K-1 }\), the parts bracketed in (17) can be represented as

$$\begin{aligned} (K-1)^2 ( - s_j^2 + (8K-5) ( q_j (\alpha ) )^2). \end{aligned}$$
(18)

Since \(s_j^2 > ( q_j (\alpha ) )^2\) under our assumption \(s_i > \max _{ k \in \{ 1,...,K \} } \left\{ 2 |c_k| \right\} \), (18) can be positive if the absolute value of \(q_j (\alpha )\) is sufficiently large (say, \(q_j (\alpha ) = \frac{s_j}{2}\)). \(\square \)

1.5 Proof of Proposition 4

For a given \(\beta _1,...,\beta _K\), the DM’s decision is given by \( \sum _{i} \frac{ \beta _i }{ \sum _{l} \beta _l } (m_i + c_i)\). We denote \(\beta = (\beta _1,...,\beta _K)\). Then, the quality of communication with expert i is given by \(M_i (\beta , q_i( \beta ) )\) and the DM’s expected payoff is given as

$$\begin{aligned} E[\pi ]= & {} - \sum _{i} \left( \alpha _i E[\theta _i^2] + \left( \left( \frac{ \beta _i }{ \sum _{l} \beta _l } \right) ^2 \sum _l \alpha _l - 2 \alpha _i \frac{ \beta _i }{ \sum _{l} \beta _l } \right) M_i (\beta , q_i( \beta ) ) \right. \\&- \left( \alpha _i \left( \frac{ \beta _i }{ \sum _{l} \beta _l } - 1 \right) ^2 + \left( \frac{ \beta _i }{ \sum _{l} \beta _l } \right) ^2 \sum _{k \ne i} \alpha _k \right) c_i^2 \\&\left. - \sum _{k \ne i} \left( \frac{ \beta _i \beta _k }{ (\sum _{l} \beta _l)^2 } \sum _l \alpha _l - \alpha _i \frac{ \beta _k }{ \sum _{l} \beta _l } - \alpha _k \frac{ \beta _i }{ \sum _{l} \beta _l } \right) c_i c_k \right) . \end{aligned}$$

The first derivative of \(E[\pi ]\) with \(\beta _i\) at \(\beta _k = \alpha \) for all k is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \frac{\partial E[\pi ] }{\partial \beta _i} \right| _{ \displaystyle (\beta _1,...,\beta _K) = (\alpha ,...,\alpha ) }= & {} \left. \frac{ \alpha }{ K } \sum _k \frac{ \partial {{\hat{M}}}_k }{ \partial \beta _i }(\beta ) \right| _{ \displaystyle (\beta _1,...,\beta _K) = (\alpha ,...,\alpha ) }. \end{aligned}$$

According to (14), (15), and (16), each marginal effect is as follows;

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \frac{ \partial {{\hat{M}}}_i }{ \partial \beta _i }(\beta ) \right| _{ \displaystyle (\beta _1,...,\beta _K) = (\alpha ,...,\alpha ) } = \frac{ K-1 }{ \alpha (4K-1)^2 } s_i^2 + \frac{ 3 \sum _{k \ne i}(c_k - c_i)^2 }{ \alpha (4K-1)^2 (K-1) } \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \frac{ \partial {{\hat{M}}}_j }{ \partial \beta _i }(\beta ) \right| _{ \displaystyle (\beta _1,...,\beta _K) = (\alpha ,...,\alpha ) }= & {} - \frac{ 1 }{ \alpha (4K-1)^2 } s_j^2 - \frac{ 3 \sum _{k \ne j}(c_k - c_j)^2 }{ \alpha (4K-1)^2 (K-1)^2 } \\&+ \frac{ 2 \sum _{k \ne j}(c_k - c_i) \sum _{k \ne j}(c_k - c_j) }{ \alpha (4K-1) (K-1)^2 }. \end{aligned}$$

Summing them, we derive (9) as follows;

$$\begin{aligned}&\left. \sum _{k} \frac{ \partial {{\hat{M}}}_k }{ \partial \beta _i } ( \beta ) \right| _{ \displaystyle (\beta _1,...,\beta _K) = (\alpha ,...,\alpha ) } \\&\quad = \frac{ 1 }{ \alpha (4K-1)^2 } \left( (K-1) s_i^2 - \sum _{k \ne i} s_k^2 \right) \\&\qquad + \frac{ 3(K-1) ( \sum _{k \ne i }( c_k-c_i) )^2 - \sum _{j \ne i} ( 3 ( \sum _{k \ne j} (c_k-c_j) )^2 - 2(4K-1) ( \sum _{k \ne j} (c_k-c_i) \sum _{k \ne j} ( c_k - c_j ) ) ) }{ \alpha (4K-1)^2 (K-1)^2 } \\&\quad = \frac{ 1 }{ \alpha (4K-1)^2 } \left( (K-1) s_i^2 - \sum _{k \ne i} s_k^2 \right) \\&\qquad + \frac{5K-2}{ \alpha (4K-1)^2 (K-1)^2 } \left( -(K-2)(K-1)c_i^2 + (K-2) \sum _{j \ne i} c_j^2 \right. \\&\left. \qquad + 2 (K-2) c_i \sum _{j \ne i}c_j - 2 \sum _{j \ne i}\sum _{k \ne i, j} c_j c_k \right) \\&\quad = \frac{ 1 }{ \alpha (4K-1)^2 } \left( (K-1) s_i^2 - \sum _{k \ne i} s_k^2 \right) \\&\qquad + \frac{ (5K-2)(K-2) }{ \alpha (K-1)(4K-1)^2 } \left( \frac{ 1 }{ (K-1)(K-2) } \sum _{j \ne i} \sum _{k \ne i,j} (c_j-c_k)^2 - \frac{ 1 }{ (K-1) } \sum _{k \ne i} (c_i-c_k)^2 \right) . \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

1.6 Proof of observation 1

Without loss of generality, we assume \(c_i = 0\) and \(c_j > 0\). Define \(g_i ( c ) = \sum _{j \ne i} \sum _{k \ne i,j} (c_j-c_k)^2 - (K-1) \sum _{k \ne i} (c_i-c_k)^2\) where \(c = (c_1,...,c_K)\). We have \(\frac{ \partial g_i }{ \partial c_k } = -4 \sum _{l \not \in {\mathbb {I}} } c_l + 2 K c_j > -4 \sum _{l \not \in {\mathbb {I}} } c'_l + 2 K c_j\) where \(c'_l\) is defined as \(c'_l = c_l\) if \(c_l > 0\) and \(c'_l = - c_l\) otherwise. If \(c_j \ge c'_l\) for all l, \(\sum _{l \not \in {\mathbb {I}} } c'_l < (K-I) c_j\). Then, \(\frac{ \partial g_i }{ \partial c_k } > (4 I - 2K) c_j\). Thus, \(g_i ( c )\) is increasing in \(c_j\) if \(I > K/2\).

Let \(c'' = (c''_1,...,c''_K)\) where \(c''_l\) is defined as \(c''_l = c_l\) for \(l \in {\mathbb {I}}\) and \(c''_l = \min _{l \not \in {\mathbb {I}} } c'_l\) otherwise. It is immediate that \( g_i (c) > g_i (c'') \). Then, we have

$$\begin{aligned} g_i (c'') = ( 2 (I-1) (K-I) - (K-2) (K-I) ) (\min _{l \not \in {\mathbb {I}} } c'_l)^2 \end{aligned}$$

If \(I > K/2\), \(g_i (c'') > 0\) therefore \( g_i (c) > 0\). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ogawa, H. Receiver’s sensitivity and strategic information transmission in multi-sender cheap talk. Int J Game Theory 50, 215–239 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-020-00747-9

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-020-00747-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation