International Journal of Game Theory

, Volume 46, Issue 4, pp 1015–1036 | Cite as

Natural implementation with semi-responsible agents in pure exchange economies

Original Paper

Abstract

We study Nash implementation by natural price–quantity mechanisms in pure exchange economies when agents have intrinsic preferences for responsibility. An agent has an intrinsic preference for responsibility if she cares about truth-telling that is in line with the goal of the mechanism designer besides her material well-being. A semi-responsible agent is an agent who, given what her opponents do, acts in an irresponsible manner when a responsible behavior poses obstacles to her material well-being. The class of efficient allocation rules that are Nash implementable is identified provided that there is at least one agent who is semi-responsible. The Walrasian rule is shown to belong to that class.

Keywords

Nash equilibrium Exchange economies Intrinsic preferences for responsibility Boundary problem Price–quantity mechanism 

JEL Classification

C72 D71 

References

  1. Corchón L, Herrero C (2004) A decent proposal. Span Econ Rev 6:107–125CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Bochet O (2007) Implementation of the Walrasian correspondence. Int J Game Theory 36:301–316CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Doğan B (2014) Essays on mechanism design and implementation. Ph.D. dissertation, University of RochesterGoogle Scholar
  4. Dutta B, Sen A (2012) Nash implementation with partially honest individuals. Games Econ Behav 74:154–169CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Dutta B, Sen A, Vohra R (1995) Nash implementation through elementary mechanisms in economic environments. Econ Des 1:173–204Google Scholar
  6. Eliaz K (2002) Fault-tolerant implementation. Rev Econ Stud 69:589–610CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Glazer J, Rubinstein A (1998) Motives and implementation: on the design of mechanisms to elicit opinions. J Econ Theory 79:157–173CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Hurwicz L (1978) On the interaction between information and incentives in organizations. In: Krippendorff K (ed) Communication and control in society. Scientific Publishers Inc, New York, pp 123–147Google Scholar
  9. Hurwicz L, Maskin E, Postlewaite A (1995) Feasible Nash implementation of social choice rules when the designer does not know endowments or production sets. In: Ledyard J (ed) The economics of informational decentralization: complexity, efficiency, and stability, essays in honor of Stanley Reiter. Kluwer, Amsterdam, pp 367–433CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Jackson MO (1992) Implementation in undominated strategies: a look at bounded mechanisms. Rev Econ Stud 59:757–775CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Jackson MO (2001) A crash course in implementation theory. Soc Choice Welf 18:655–708CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Jackson MO, Palfrey T, Srivastava S (1994) Undominated Nash implementation in bounded mechanisms. Games Econ Behav 6:474–501CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Kartik N, Tercieux O (2012) Implementation with evidence. Theor Econ 7:323–355CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Kartik N, Tercieux O, Holden R (2014) Simple mechanisms and preferences for honesty. Games Econ Behav 83:284–290CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Lombardi M, Yoshihara N (2013a) A full characterization of Nash implementation with strategy space reduction. Econ Theory 54:131–151CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Lombardi M, Yoshihara N (2013b) Natural implementation with partially honest agents. IER discussion paper series A, No. 561, The Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi UniversityGoogle Scholar
  17. Lombardi M, Yoshihara N (2014) Natural implementation with partially-honest agents in economic environments with free-disposal. IER discussion paper series A, No. 616, The Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi UniversityGoogle Scholar
  18. Maskin E (1999) Nash equilibrium and welfare optimality. Rev Econ Stud 66:23–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Matsushima H (2008a) Role of honesty in full implementation. J Econ Theory 139:353–359CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Matsushima H (2008b) Behavioral aspects of implementation theory. Econ Lett 100:161–164CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Otani Y, Sicilian J (1982) Equilibrium of Walras preference games. J Econ Theory 27:47–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Pazner E, Schmeidler D (1978) Egalitarian equivalent allocations: a new concept of economic equity. Q J Econ 92:671–686CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Postlewaite A, Wettstein D (1989) Feasible and continuous implementation. Rev Econ Stud 56:603–611CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Saijo T, Tatamitani Y, Yamato T (1996) Toward natural implementation. Int Econ Rev 37:949–980CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Saijo T, Tatamitani Y, Yamato T (1999) Characterizing natural implementability: the fair and Walrasian correspondences. Games Econ Behav 28:271–293CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Saporiti A (2014) Securely implementable social choice rules with partially honest agents. J Econ Theory 154:216–228CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Sjöström T (1996) Implementation by demand mechanisms. Econ Des 1:343–354Google Scholar
  28. Tatamitani Y (2001) Implementation by self-relevant mechanisms. J Math Econ 35:427–444CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Thomson W (1984) The manipulability of resource allocation mechanisms. Rev Econ Stud 51:447–460CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Thomson W (1999) Monotonic extensions on economic domains. Rev Econ Des 4:13–33Google Scholar
  31. Tian G (1992) Implementation of the Walrasian correspondence without continuous, convex, and ordered preferences. Soc Choice Welf 9:117–130CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2017

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Adam Smith Business SchoolUniversity of GlasgowGlasgowUK
  2. 2.Department of EconomicsUniversity of Massachusetts AmherstAmherstUSA
  3. 3.The Institute of Economic ResearchHitotsubashi UniversityKunitachiJapan
  4. 4.School of ManagementKochi University of TechnologyKochiJapan

Personalised recommendations