Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Financial liberalization, political institutions, and income inequality

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Rising income inequality coinciding with financial liberalization has stimulated extensive studies on the possible links between income inequality and different forms of financial liberalization, both inputs and outputs, since the 1990s. Nonetheless, empirical investigations remain inconclusive. To provide new and robust evidence, this study investigates the distributional repercussions of financial liberalization and the role played by democratization in this process. Focusing on the outcome measures of financial liberalization, we find, in a panel of developing and developed countries for 1989–2011, that (1) financial openness alleviates income inequality, particularly for less democratic countries; (2) stock market development mitigates income inequality, whereas its volatility exacerbates it, with both effects decreasing with democratization; (3) banking development strengthens income inequality, whereas its volatility alleviates it, with both effects again moderating with democratization; and (4) these effects are mediated by human capital accumulation and entrepreneurship development. The data thus suggest that financial reforms toward capital account openness and more liquid, stable stock markets are beneficial to income distribution, as such reforms allow more previously excluded households and firms to access financial funds and services, thereby increasing human capital and entrepreneurship, especially in less democratic countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For instance, Das and Mohapatra (2003), Beck et al. (2010), Agnello et al. (2012), Delis et al. (2014), Bumann and Lensink (2016), Christopoulos and McAdam (2017), Haan and Sturm (2017), Furceri and Loungani (2018), and Manish and O’Reilly (2018) consider the input/policy measure of financial liberalization such as bank regulation and capital market liberalization policy. Others including Jalilian and Kirkpatrick (2005), Clarke et al. (2006), Beck et al. (2007), Kim and Lin (2011), Law et al. (2014), Jauch and Watzka (2016), D’Onofrio et al. (2017), Haan and Sturm (2017), and Blau (2018) focus on outcome measures such as capital (e.g., foreign direct investment, FDI) flows and the size and stability of the financial sector.

  2. For instance, Law et al. (2014), Cepparulo et al. (2017), and De Hann and Strum (2017) also explore the role of political institutions. Cepparulo et al. (2017), in a sample of developing countries from 1984 to 2012, find that the pro-poor impact of banking development decreases as the quality of institutions rises. Law et al. (2014), using a sample of 81 countries averaged over 1985–2010, show that banking development tends to reduce income inequality only after a certain threshold level of institutional quality has been achieved. Using a panel fixed effects model for a sample of 121 countries covering 1975–2005, De Hann and Strum (2017) demonstrate that banking development raises income inequality irrespective of the quality of political institutions. We differ from these studies by considering not only banking development but also stock market development. We also consider actual financial openness and financial volatility as well as the mechanisms of how these financial variables affect income inequality.

  3. Indeed, Boix (2003) and Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) show that income inequality affects democratization. The causality running from inequality to finance is also recognized by Claessens and Perotti (2007).

  4. We also check whether the diminishing effects of financial liberalization on inequality with increasing democratization are simply because of too much finance, as suggested by Arcand et al. (2015). Including the squares of the financial liberalization indicators, we continue to find that the financial variables and their interaction with democratization retain their signs and significance. This means that democratization captures more than the financial curse of Arcand et al. (2015). Further, we replace GDP growth with log real GDP per capita and its quadratic term; the financial variables and their interaction with democratization retain their signs and significance. These results are not reported to save space but are available on request.

  5. The only exception is for the Column (3) regression perhaps because of using too many endogenous variables. We find a similar case for the following two tables.

  6. Liu et al. (2017) also find that a rise in turnover in the stock market augments income inequality in China.

  7. This might also explain the larger number of instruments than countries.

  8. The quantile regression approach, introduced by Koenker and Bassett (1978), has gained increasing popularity in applied economics and has recently been extended to panel data with additive fixed effects and combined instrumental variable techniques in a quantile setting (e.g., Koenker 2004; Galvao 2011; Harding and Lamarche 2014). However, all these estimators are consistent in large-T samples. More recently, Powell (2016) and Powell and Wagner (2014) exploit the ideas of Chernozhukov and Hansen (2008) and propose a different estimator, based on instrumental variables. The estimator is consistent for small T. This is the most suitable method for our study given the small T and endogeneity of the regressors. Please see Powell (2016) for more details.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S (2005) Unbundling institutions. J Polit Econ 113:949–995

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson JA (2000) Democratization or repression? Eur Econ Rev 44:683–693

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson JA (2005) Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson J (2006) Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Naidu S, Restrepo P, Robinson JA (2015) Democracy, redistribution, and inequality. In: Atkinson AB, Bourguignon F (eds) Handbook of income distribution, vol 2. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1885–1966

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Bolton P (1992) An incomplete contracts approach to financial contracting. Rev Econ Stud 59:473–494

    Google Scholar 

  • Agnello L, Sousa RM (2012) How do banking crises impact on income inequality? Appl Econ Lett 19:1425–1429

    Google Scholar 

  • Agnello L, Mallick SK, Sousa RM (2012) Financial reforms and income inequality. Econ Lett 116:583–587

    Google Scholar 

  • Aizenman J, Pinto B (eds) (2005) Managing economic volatility and crises: a practitioner’s guide. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Alessandria G, Qian J (2005) Endogenous financial intermediation and real effects of capital account liberalization. J Int Econ 67:97–128

    Google Scholar 

  • Ansell BW, Samuels DJ (2014) Inequality and democratization: an elite-competition approach. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Arcand JL, Berkes E, Panizza U (2015) Too much finance? J Econ Growth 20:105–148

    Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58:277–297

    Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bover O (1995) Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. J Econom 68:29–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee AV, Newman AF (1993) Occupational choice and the process of development. J Polit Econ 101:274–298

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Lee JW (2013) A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950-2010. J Dev Econ 104:184–198

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck T, Demirgüç-Kunt A, Levine R (2007) Finance, inequality and the poor. J Econ Growth 12:27–49

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck T, Levine R, Levkov A (2010) Big bad banks? The winners and losers from bank deregulation in the United States. J Finance 65:1637–1667

    Google Scholar 

  • Bencivenga VR, Smith BD, Starr RM (1995) Transaction costs, technological choice, and endogenous growth. J Econ Theory 67:53–117

    Google Scholar 

  • Blau BM (2018) Income inequality, poverty, and the liquidity of stock markets. J Dev Econ 130:113–126

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Bond S (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J Econom 87:115–143

    Google Scholar 

  • Boix C (2003) Democracy and redistribution. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Bollerslev T (1986) Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity. J Econ 31:307–327

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonica A, McCarty N, Poole KT, Rosenthal H (2013) Why hasn’t democracy slowed rising inequality? J Econ Perspect 27:103–124

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd JH, Smith BD (1998) The evolution of debt and equity markets in economic development. Econ Theory 12:519–560

    Google Scholar 

  • Breen R, García-Peñalosa C (2005) Income inequality and macroeconomic volatility: an empirical investigation. Rev Dev Econ 9:380–398

    Google Scholar 

  • Bumann S, Lensink R (2016) Capital account liberalization and income inequality. J Int Money Finance 61:143–162

    Google Scholar 

  • Byrne JP, Davis EP (2005a) Investment and uncertainty in the G7. Rev World Econ 141:1–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Byrne JP, Davis EP (2005b) The impact of short- and long-run exchange rate uncertainty on investment: a panel study of industrial countries. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 67:307–329

    Google Scholar 

  • Cepparulo A, Cuestas JC, Intartaglia M (2017) Financial development, institutions, and poverty alleviation: an empirical analysis. Appl Econ 49:3611–3622

    Google Scholar 

  • Chernozhukov V, Hansen C (2008) Instrumental variable quantile regression: a robust inference approach. J Econom 142:379–398

    Google Scholar 

  • Christopoulos D, McAdam P (2017) Do financial reforms help stabilize inequality? J Int Money Finance 70:45–61

    Google Scholar 

  • Claessens S, Perotti E (2007) Finance and inequality: channels and evidence. J Comp Econ 35:748–773

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarke GRG, Xu LC, Zou H-F (2006) Finance and income inequality: What do the data tell us? South Econ J 72:578–596

    Google Scholar 

  • Crotty J (2003) The neoliberal paradox: the impact of destructive product market competition and impatient finance on nonfinancial corporations in the neoliberal era. Rev Rad Polit Econ 35:271–279

    Google Scholar 

  • D’Onofrio A, Minetti R, Murro P (2017) Banking development, socioeconomic structure and income inequality. J Econ Behav Organ forthcoming

  • Das M, Mohapatra S (2003) Income inequality: the aftermath of stock market liberalization in emerging markets. J Empir Finance 10:217–248

    Google Scholar 

  • De Haan J, Sturm J-E (2017) Finance and income inequality: a review and new evidence. Eur J Polit Econ 50:171–195

    Google Scholar 

  • Delis MD, Hasan I, Kazakis P (2014) Bank regulations and income inequality: empirical evidence. Rev Finance 18:1811–1846

    Google Scholar 

  • Demirgüç-Kunt A, Levine R (2009) Finance and inequality: theory and evidence. Ann Rev Financ Econ 1:287–318

    Google Scholar 

  • Demirgüç-Kunt A, Feyen E, Levine R (2013) The evolving importance of banks and securities markets. World Bank Econ Rev 27:476–490

    Google Scholar 

  • Furceri D, Loungani P (2018) The distributional effects of capital account liberalization. J Dev Econ 130:127–144

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Zeira J (1993) Income distribution and macroeconomics. Rev Econ Stud 60:35–52

    Google Scholar 

  • Galvao AF Jr (2011) Quantile regression for dynamic panel data with fixed effects. J Econom 164:142–157

    Google Scholar 

  • Gimet C, Lagoarde-Segot T (2011) A closer look at financial development and income distribution. J Bank Finance 35:1698–1713

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood J, Jovanovic B (1990) Financial development, growth, and the distribution of income. J Polit Econ 98:1076–1107

    Google Scholar 

  • Haber S, North DC, Weingast BR (eds) (2007) Political institutions and financial development. Stanford University Press, Stanford

    Google Scholar 

  • Harding M, Lamarche C (2014) Estimating and testing a quantile regression model with interactive effects. J Econom 178:101–113

    Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh J, Chen TC, Lin SC (2019) Financial structure, bank competition and income inequality. North Am J Econ Finance 48:450–466

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang Y (2010) Political institutions and financial development: an empirical study. World Dev 38:1667–1677

    Google Scholar 

  • Jalilian H, Kirkpatrick C (2005) Does financial development contribute to poverty reduction? J Dev Stud 41:636–656

    Google Scholar 

  • Jauch S, Watzka S (2016) Financial development and income inequality: a panel data approach. Empir Econ 51:291–314

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen NM (2003) Democratic governance and multinational corporations: political regimes and inflows of foreign direct investment. Int Organ 57:587–616

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim D-H, Lin S-C (2011) Nonlinearity in the financial development-income inequality nexus. J Comp Econ 39:310–325

    Google Scholar 

  • Koenker R (2004) Quantile regression for longitudinal data. J Multivar Anal 91:74–89

    Google Scholar 

  • Koenker R, Bassett G (1978) Regression quantiles. Econometrica 46:33–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohler K, Guschanski A, Stockhammer E (2016) How does financialization affect functional income distribution? A theoretical clarification and empirical assessment. Soc-Econ Rev 20:1–26

    Google Scholar 

  • La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A, Vishny RW (1998) Law and finance. J Polit Econ 106:1113–1155

    Google Scholar 

  • Lane PR, Milesi-Ferretti GM (2007) The external wealth of nations mark II: revised and extended estimates of foreign assets and liabilities, 1970–2004. J Int Econ 73:223–250

    Google Scholar 

  • Laursen T, Mahajan S (2005) Volatility, income distribution, and poverty. In: Aizenman J, Pinto B (eds) Managing economic volatility and crises: a practitioner’s guide. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Law SH, Tan HB, Azman-Saini WNW (2014) Financial development and income inequality at different levels of institutional quality. Emerg Markets Finance Trade 50:21–33

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine R (1991) Stock markets, growth and tax policy. J Finance 46:1445–1465

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine R (2005) Finance and growth: theory and evidence. In: Aghion P, Durlauf S (eds) Handbook of economic growth. Elsevier, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Li Q (2006) Political violence and foreign direct investment. In: Fratianni M, Rugman AM (eds) Research in global strategic management, vol 12. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 231–255

    Google Scholar 

  • Li Q, Resnick A (2003) Reversal of fortunes: democratic institutions and FDI inflows to developing countries. Int Organ 57:175–211

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin K-H, Tomaskovic-Devey D (2013) Financialization and U.S. income inequality, 1970–2008. Am J Sociol 118:1284–1329

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu G, Liu Y, Zhang C (2017) Financial development, financial structure and income inequality in China. World Econ 40:1890–1917

    Google Scholar 

  • Mahler VA (2004) Economic globalization, domestic politics, and income inequality in the developed countries: a cross-national study. Comp Polit Stud 37:1025–1053

    Google Scholar 

  • Manish GP, O’Reilly C (2018) Banking regulation, regulatory capture and inequality. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0501-0

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall MG, Gurr TR, Jaggers K (2017) Polity IV Project: political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2016. Center for Systemic Peace

  • Mehlum H, MoeneKO TR (2012) Mineral rents and social development in Norway. In: Hujo K (ed) Mineral rents and the financing of social policy. Palgrave Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Mishkin FS (2007) Is financial globalization beneficial? J Money Credit Bank 39:259–294

    Google Scholar 

  • Mishkin FS (2009) Globalization and financial development. J Dev Econ 89:164–169

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F, Perotti E (2000) Security markets versus bank finance. Legal enforcement and investor protection. Int Rev Finance 1:81–96

    Google Scholar 

  • Perotti EC, Volpin P (2007) Politics, investor protection and competition. University of Amsterdam, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell D (2016) Quantile regression with nonadditive fixed effects. Available at: http://works.bepress.com/david_powell/1/

  • Powell D, Wagner J (2014) The exporter productivity premium along the productivity distribution: evidence from quantile regression with nonadditive firm fixed effects. Rev World Econ 150:763–785

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajan RG (1992) Insiders and outsiders: the choice between informed and arm’s length debt. J Finance 47:1367–1400

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajan RG, Ramcharan R (2011) Land and credit: a study of the political economy of banking in the United States in the early 20th century. J Finance 66:1895–1931

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajan RG, Zingales L (1998) Which capitalism? Lessons from the East Asian crisis. J Appl Corpor Finance 11:40–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajan RG, Zingales L (2003) The great reversals: the politics of financial development in the twentieth century. J Financ Econ 69:5–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramey G, Ramey VA (1995) Cross-country evidence on the link between volatility and growth. Am Econ Rev 85:1138–1151

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D (1998) Why do more open economies have bigger governments? J Polit Econ 106:997–1032

    Google Scholar 

  • Roine J, Vlachos J, Waldenström D (2009) The long-run determinants of inequality: what can we learn from top income data? J Public Econ 93:974–988

    Google Scholar 

  • Roodman D (2009) A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 71:135–158

    Google Scholar 

  • Solt F (2009) Standardizing the world income inequality database. Soc Sci Q 90:231–242

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE (2000) Capital market liberalization, economic growth, and instability. World Dev 28:1075–1086

    Google Scholar 

  • van Treeck T (2009) The political economy debate on ‘Financialization’—A macroeconomic perspective. Rev Int Polit Econ 16:907–944

    Google Scholar 

  • Windmeijer F (2005) A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. J Econom 126:25–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Yang B (2011) Does democracy foster financial development? An empirical analysis. Econ Lett 112:262–265

    Google Scholar 

  • Zalewski DA, Whalen CJ (2010) Financialization and income inequality: a post Keynesian institutionalist analysis. J Econ Issues 44:757–777

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to the anonymous referee for valuable suggestions and comments that improve the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shu-Chin Lin.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Ethical approval

This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Shu-Chin Lin: The usual disclaimer applies.

Appendices

Appendix 1: measuring volatility

1.1 Measuring volatility

We follow Byrne and Davis (2005a, b) by proxying for financial volatility using conditional standard deviations obtained from the GARCH (1, 1) model. A standard GARCH model consists of mean and variance equations. For each country \( i \), we fit an ARMA (\( p, q \)) (autoregressive moving average) model to the mean equation of financial development \( \left( {finvol_{t} } \right): \)

$$ finvol_{t} = b_{0} + \mathop \sum \limits_{j = 1}^{p} b_{j} finvol_{t - j} + \mathop \sum \limits_{j}^{q} c_{j} \varepsilon_{t - j} $$
(4)

where \( \varepsilon_{t} \) is the white noise at time \( t \). We choose a model for \( p \) and \( q \) using the Schwarz Bayesian criterion. For conditional heteroskedasticity, we assume that.

$$ \varepsilon_{t} |\varOmega_{t - 1} = h_{t}^{1/2} \eta_{t} $$

where \( \varOmega_{t - 1} \) denotes the information set to time \( t - 1 \), \( h_{t} \) represents conditional variance at time \( t \), and \( \eta_{t} \sim NID\left( {0,1} \right). \) We then use the GARCH(1,1) specification proposed by Bollerslev (1986) as follows:

$$ h_{t} = \alpha_{1} + \alpha_{2} \varepsilon_{t - 1}^{2} + \beta h_{t - 1} $$
(5)

Appendix 2: descriptive statistics and list of Countries

See Tables 8 and 9.

Table 8 Descriptive statistics
Table 9 List of sample countries

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kim, DH., Hsieh, J. & Lin, SC. Financial liberalization, political institutions, and income inequality. Empir Econ 60, 1245–1281 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-019-01808-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-019-01808-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation