Abstract
This paper quantifies the Chinese consumers’ boycott of Japanese cars that immediately followed the anti-Japanese demonstrations in September 2012. We decompose the total boycott effect into two effects: the transfer effect, which refers to consumers switching from Japanese to non-Japanese brands, and the cancellation effect, which captures decline in sales due to consumers exiting the market. We find that the cancellation effect accounts for more than 90% of the total decline in Japanese car sales, implying a small substitution effect in the automobile market, even though brands of all other countries have benefited. This paper provides evidence of both negative and positive impacts of political conflicts for different market participants and includes analysis with welfare implications.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
Proxy boycotts can also occur in domestic politics. For example, Cuadras-Morató and Raya (2016) study the boycotts of Catalan sparkling wine in Spain.
Our data also cover the period of the “Senkaku Event” in 2010 that arisen from disputes over the Senkaku Islands, known as Diaoyu Islands in China. However, we find no evidence of negative impact resulted from the 2010 “Senkaku Event” in the Chinese automobile market.
We computed the size of Japanese imported cars as a percentage of “Made in China” Japanese cars using data from UN Comtrade (HS code 8703) and our data and find that imported cars account for less than 10% of Japanese car sales in China.
Studies of the automobile industry are abundant in the economics literature. See, for example, Bandeen (1957), Sheahan (1960), Hess (1977), Berkovec (1985), Bresnahan (1987), Cooper and Haltiwanger (1993), Ries (1993), Berry et al. (1995) and Park (2003), covering a variety of topics. In addition, Depner and Bathelt (2005), Deng and Ma (2010), Luong (2013) and Hu et al. (2014) provide analyses of various aspects of the Chinese automobile industry.
CAAM also reports the sales of Jiaocha cars, which are designed for both cargo and passenger purposes. This type of car is specially designed for the Chinese market, especially in the rural areas. Since they are not general passenger cars, and there is no foreign-brand cars in this category, we exclude them from our sample.
See Heilmann (2016) for more details of the boycotts of Japanese products.
The basic fixed effect regression with common trend is
$$\begin{aligned}Y_{it}=\alpha _{i}+\lambda _{t}+{\hat{\rho }} D_{it}+\varepsilon _{it},\end{aligned}$$while the regression with unique trends is
$$\begin{aligned} Y_{it}=\alpha _{i}+\bar{\lambda _{t}}+ {\tilde{\lambda }}_t D_{it} + {\tilde{\rho }} D_{it}+\varepsilon _{it}, \end{aligned}$$where \(\alpha _{i}\) and \(\lambda _{t}\) indicate the group fixed effect and the time fixed effect and \(D_{it}\) is a dummy variable that equals 1 for the treatment group after policy and 0 otherwise. In the second regression, \(\bar{\lambda _{t}}\) denotes the collection of trends of the non-treatment groups while \(\lambda _t D_{it}\) is the unique trend of the treatment group. With the common trend regression, \({\hat{\rho }}\) gives the estimate of ATE. However, if the unique trend model is the true model, then \({\hat{\rho }}\) would be overestimated because its value is equal to \({\tilde{\lambda }}_t + {\tilde{\rho }}\) from the regression with unique trend.
Please see “Appendix A” for additional detail.
References
Ashenfelter O, Ciccarella S, Shatz H (2007) French wine and the U.S. boycott of 2003: Does politics really affect commerce? J Wine Econ 2(1):55–74
Autor DH (2003) Outsourcing at will: the contribution of unjust dismissal doctrine to the growth of employment outsourcing. J Labor Econ 21(1):1–42
Bandeen RA (1957) Automobile consumption, 1940–1950. Econometrica 25(2):239–248
Baron DP (2001) Private politics, corporate social responsibility, and integrated strategy. J Econ Manag Strategy 10(1):7–45
Baron DP (2003) Private politics. J Econ Manag Strategy 12(1):31–66
Berkovec J (1985) New car sales and used car stocks: a model of the automobile market. Rand J Econ 16(2):195–214
Berry S, Levinsohn J, Pakes A (1995) Automobile prices in market equilibrium. Econometrica 63(4):841–890
Bown CP, Crowley MA (2007) Trade deflection and trade depression. J Int Econ 72:176–201
Bresnahan TF (1987) Competition and collusion in the American automobile industry: the 1955 price war. J Ind Econ 35(4):457–482
Chavis L, Leslie P (2009) Consumer boycotts: the impact of the Iraq war on French wine sales in the U.S. Quant Market Econ 7(1):37–67
Che Y, Du J, Lu Y, Tao Z (2015) Once an enemy, forever an enemy? The long-run impact of the Japanese invasion of China from 1937 to 1945 on trade and investment. J Int Econ 96(1):182–198
Ciro B, De Mello JMP, Alexandre S (2010) Dry laws and homicides: evidence from the São Paulo metropolitan area. Econ J 120(543):157–182
Clerides S, Davis P, Michis A (2015) National sentiment and consumer choice: the Iraq war and sales of US products in Arab countries. Scand J Econ 117(3):829–851
Cooper R, Haltiwanger J (1993) Automobiles and the National Industrial Recovery Act: evidence on industry complementarities. Q J Econ 108(4):1043–1071
Cuadras-Morató X, Raya JM (2016) Boycott or buycott?: Internal politics and consumer choices. BE J Econ Anal Policy 16(1):185–218
Davis CL, Meunier S (2011) Business as usual? Economic responses to political tensions. Am J Polit Sci 55(3):628–646
Deng H, Ma AC (2010) Market structure and pricing strategy of China’s automobile industry. J Ind Econ 58(4):818–845
Depner H, Bathelt H (2005) Exporting the German model: the establishment of a new automobile industry cluster in Shanghai. Econ Geogr 81(1):53–81
Egorov G, Harstad B (2017) Private politics and public regulation. Rev Econ Stud 84:1652–1682
Fershtman C, Gandal N (1998) The effect of the Arab boycott on Israel: the automobile market. RAND J Econ 29(1):193–214
Fisman R, Hamao Y, Wang Y (2014) Nationalism and economic exchange: evidence from shocks to Sino-Japanese relations. Rev Financ Stud 27:2626–2660
Fuchs A, Klann NH (2013) Paying a visit: the Dalai Lama effect on international trade. J Int Econ 91(1):164–177
Heilmann K (2016) Does political conflict hurt trade? Evidence from consumer boycotts. J Int Econ 99:179–191
Hendel I, Lach S, Spiegel Y (2017) Consumers’ activism: the cottage cheese boycott. RAND J Econ 48(4):972–1003
Hess AC (1977) A comparison of automobile demand equations. Econometrica 45(3):683–702
Hong C, Hu WM, Prieger JE, Zhu D (2011) French automobiles and the Chinese boycotts of 2008: politics really does affect commerce. BE J Econ Anal Policy 11(1):Article 26
Hu WM, Xiao J, Zhou X (2014) Collusion or competition? Interfirm relationships in the Chinese auto industry. J Ind Econ 62(1):1–40
John A, Klein J (2003) The boycott puzzle: consumer motivations for purchase sacrifice. Manag Sci 49(9):1196–1209
Li Q, Sacko D (2002) The (ir)relevance of militarized interstate disputes for international trade. Int Stud Q 46(1):11–43
Luo Z, Tian X (2018) Can China’s meat imports be sustainable? A case study of mad cow disease. Appl Econ 50(9):1022–1042
Luong TA (2013) Does learning by exporting happen? Evidence from the automobile industry in China. Rev Dev Econ 17(3):461–473
Magee CS (2008) New measures of trade creation and trade diversion. J Int Econ 75:349–362
Michaels G, Zhi X (2010) Freedom fried. Am Econ J Appl Econ 2(3):256–281
Pan Y, Zhou Y (2018) War memory: evidence from assistance during Great East Japan earthquake. Defence Peace Econ Forthcoming
Pandya SS, Venkatesan R (2016) French toast: consumer response to international conflict-evidence from supermarket scanner data. Rev Econ Stat 98(1):42–56
Park BG (2003) Politics of scale and the globalization of the South Korean automobile industry. Econ Geogr 79(2):173–194
Peck J (2017) Temporary boycotts as self-fulfilling disruptions of markets. J Econ Theory 169:1–12
Ries JC (1993) Windfall profits and vertical relationships: Who gained in the Japanese auto industry from VERs? J Ind Econ 41(3):259–276
Sheahan J (1960) Government competition and the performance of the French automobile industry. J Ind Econ 8(3):197–215
Waldinger F (2010) Quality matters: the expulsion of professors and the consequences for Ph.D. student outcomes in Nazi Germany. J Polit Econ 118(4):787–831
Acknowledgements
This paper was presented at the Chinese Economists Society 2015 North America Conference, the 2016 CEC Workshop, and seminars at Fudan University and Peking University. We thank conference and seminar participants, especially Le Wang, Zhao Chen, Wei Huang, Lixing Li, Yongqian Li, Pinghan Liang, Tianyang Xi, Yiqing Xu, and Shilin Zheng for their helpful comments.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Zhou acknowledges financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant Number: 71803064) and the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities of Jinan University (Grant Numbers: 12JNYH002, 12JNKY001, and 15JNQM001).
Appendices
Appendices
1.1 Appendix A
To further separate \({\mathsf {CE}}\) and \({\mathsf {TE}}\) and express them as percentages of total changes in sales, we need information on the substitutability between sales of Japanese cars and other cars. Let \(\delta \) denote the marginal rate of substitution (MRS), which is conditional on the information set \(\varLambda _{t}\); we then have
which may be rewritten into a discrete form asFootnote 11
The MRS, as conventionally defined, measures the substitutability between sales of Japanese versus other cars, based on the information set. We envisioned the information set to contain not only observable market conditions, but also unobservable attitudes of the Chinese customers towards foreign countries especially Japan. There are three main assumptions for the set up of \(\delta \) in Eq. (8). First, consumer preferences are stable. It is especially important that consumers’ attitudes towards Japan are stable, which is arguably true because of the long unhappy history between the two countries. This is also why Eq. (8) does not have a time dimension. Second, non-Japanese and Japanese cars, especially those of similar sizes, are close substitutes, if not perfect substitutes, in the sense that a family may purchase only one car at a time. As a result, the utility function of consumers is a linear combination of consumptions of all cars with a consumer buying the car that gives the highest utility. Last, although price information is unavailable in our data, the prices of new cars in China are stable and can be anticipated almost perfectly. This can be the case because the used car market in China is underdeveloped and most consumers choose to buy new cars from dealership or flagship stores.
1.2 Appendix B
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Luo, Z., Zhou, Y. Decomposing the effects of consumer boycotts: evidence from the anti-Japanese demonstration in China. Empir Econ 58, 2615–2634 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-019-01650-3
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-019-01650-3