Skip to main content
Log in

Decoding unemployment persistence: an econometric framework for identifying and comparing the sources of persistence with an application to UK macrodata

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Most econometric analyses of persistence focus on the existence of non-stationary unemployment but not the origin of this. The present research contains a multivariate econometric framework for identifying and comparing different sources of unemployment persistence (e.g., slow adjustment versus a slowly moving equilibrium rate). The framework contains readily applicable formulas for testing different hypotheses of persistence and is used to identify the causes of this in the UK macroeconomy. The evidence suggests that persistence has been due to a slowly moving equilibrium, driven by the price of crude oil, and not to slow adjustment, for example as related to the process of wage formation, as has often been emphasized.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. As Røed (1997) notes, before Blanchard and Summers (1986) the idea of hysteresis already existed in economics. In fact Phelps (1972) used the term hysteresis. However, it was with their seminal paper that this concept came to the fore of labor market economics. In their (widely used) terminology “hysteresis” describes a very high (but not complete) dependence on the past, i.e., when the sum of auto-regressive coefficients is close but not necessarily equal to 1 (Blanchard and Summers 1986, Footnote 1). As has later been argued a better term for this is persistence (see, e.g., Franz 1990). However, in an empirical analytical context this often implies a failure to reject an exact unit root in the unemployment rate (i.e., the hypothesis that the sum is exactly equal to one). Therefore, this is often referred to as unit root hysteresis (see, e.g., Arestis and Sawyer 2009; Papell et al. 2000; Meng et al. 2017). This is to be distinguished from what has become known as genuine hysteresis (see, e.g., Amable et al. 1994; Göcke 2002). In this terminology, the present research relates only to (multivariate) unit root hysteresis and does not concern genuine hysteresis. I will clarify further on the use of concepts below.

  2. The persistence or “unit root hysteresis” (see Footnote 1 and further below) of the UK unemployment rate has been studied extensively (see, e.g., the references in the surveys in Røed 1997; Gustavsson and Österholm 2009; Arestis and Sawyer 2009 and more recently Furuoka 2017a; Meng et al. 2017). It appears that overall the evidence in favor of “unit root hysteresis” remains mixed. Both the choice of methods and sample seem to influence on the conclusions.

  3. Additional important differences relative to Jacobson et al. (1997) are that their analysis is based on a partial VAR and a so-called Common-Trends approach. Moreover, in their model, equilibrium unemployment depends on unobserved variables, whereas here all variables are observable.

  4. Note that, this “cointegration approximation” in general also provides a means of robustifying the statistical inference (see Johansen 2006; Hoover et al. 2008).

  5. See, e.g., Blanchard (2006).

  6. See, e.g., the surveys in Røed (1997), Gustavsson and Österholm (2009), Arestis and Sawyer (2009) and more recently Furuoka (2017a) and Meng et al. (2017).

  7. See the survey in Røed’s paper from 1997 and for more recent examples, García-Cintado et al. (2015) and Caporale et al. (2016).

  8. In addition, the matter is even further complicated in a multivariate context, since when a unit root is rejected, this need not be inconsistent with hypotheses of slow adjustment: For example, in open economies, other stabilizing mechanisms, such as real wage resistance, may be present and may dominate the destabilization caused by persistence generating mechanisms (see, e.g., Carlin and Soskice 2006).

  9. All results generalize straightforwardly with more lags.

  10. An example, for which this approximation is also derived explicitly, forms a theoretical model (as below), see Møller and Sharp (2013) or Klemp and Møller (2015).

  11. Recalling that the remaining roots obey \(\left| z\right| >1.\)

  12. For example, often I(2) seems to be a useful statistical approximation for time series of nominal prices and wages whose time plots are very smooth or slowly changing.

  13. In these remaining cases it is thus the roots of \(P_{1}(z)\) that are approximated by \(z=1\) and parameter restrictions ensure that \(x_{1t}^{c}\) obeys I(1) or I(2), for the second and third column of the table, respectively, etc. (see Møller 2013).

  14. For this period the assumption of constant long-run parameters was supported by the recursively estimated log-likelihood maximum in the R-form (see, e.g., Juselius 2006). Both forward recursive estimation (to assess constancy from the middle to the end of the sample) and backward recursive estimation (to assess constancy from the beginning to the middle of the sample) were performed. The recursive estimation results can be obtained upon request. Finally, only two dummy variables were needed: an unrestricted impulse dummy (being equal to 1 in 1999:01 and zero otherwise) and a transitory dummy variable being 1 in 2001:01 and − 1 in 2001:02 and zero otherwise. Note that an unrestricted impulse takes account of a break/level shift in the variables that nevertheless cancels in the cointegration relations.

  15. Note that, as already pointed out in Blanchard and Summers (1986) persistence is not only associated with recessions and depressions, but also seems to characterize “normal times.” Hence, it still seems reasonable to analyze the persistence phenomena based on a sample that excludes the crisis.

  16. For this type of model, the latter is not unique and is often referred to as a medium-run and not a long-run equilibrium. A “true” unique long-run equilibrium (steady state) would additionally entail a constant net-foreign asset-to-income ratio to ensure external balance (see Carlin and Soskice 1990; Layard et al. 2005; Carlin and Soskice 2006; Groth 2009). However, to keep this analysis simple this is disregarded here.

  17. See for example Blanchard (2000).

  18. An alternative approach to modeling the wage-unemployment dynamics could be to assume the presence of a threshold for (absolute) unemployment changes below which wages do not react at all. Only when unemployment changes exceed this threshold, sufficient wage pressure will occur and wages begin to react. In the present context such an extension could built on threshold cointegration (see, e.g., Balke and Fomby 1997), with non-stationarity implied by, \(\omega _{3}+\omega _{4}=0\), but only within a band (below the threshold). However, such an analysis is beyond the scope of this study and is thus better left as a separate analysis for future research. Nevertheless, I am still grateful to an anonymous referee for pointing this out.

  19. All estimation is based on PcGive, OxMetrics 6.10 and CATS in RATS (see Doornik and Hendry 1998; Doornik 2010; Dennis et al. 2006, respectively).

  20. This particular condition is analyzed in detail in Møller (2013).

  21. See Johansen (1996), on normalization in general. Here, the normalization of the cointegrating matrix has simply been chosen for computational ease.

  22. See the discussion in Juselius (2006).

  23. This is standard practice in the reduced rank regression method (see Johansen 1996).

  24. This is generally not the case (see Johansen 2005; Lütkepohl 2005).

  25. The zero restrictions, which were exclusively motivated by insignificance, contributed to simplifying the estimated \(\beta _{c}\) matrix considerably.

  26. See, e.g., Røed (1997), Andersen (2010), O’Shaughnessy (2011), Delong and Summers (2012), Blanchard et al. (2015) and Meng et al. (2017).

  27. See the discussion and references in Footnote 16.

References

  • Akdoğan K (2015) Unemployment hysteresis and structural change in europe. Empir Econ 53(4):1–26

  • Amable B, Henry J, Lordon F, Topol R (1994) Strong hysteresis versus zero-root dynamics. Econ Lett 44(1–2):43–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amable B, Mayhew K (2011) Unemployment in the OECD. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 27(2):207–220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersen T (2010, 04) Unemployment persistence. CESifo Forum 11(1): 23–28

  • Arestis P, Sawyer M (eds) (2009) Path dependency and macroeconomics. Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke

    Google Scholar 

  • Bakas D, Papapetrou E (2014) Unemployment in Greece: evidence from greek regions using panel unit root tests. Q Rev Econ Finance 54(4):551–562

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balke NS, Fomby TB (1997) Threshold cointegration. Int Econ Rev 38(3):627–645

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ball LM (2009) Hysteresis in unemployment: old and new evidence. NBER Working Papers 14818, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., Cambridge

  • Blanchard O (2000) Macroeconomics. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O (2006) European unemployment: the evolution of facts and ideas. Econ Policy 21(45):5–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Cerutti, E, Summers LH (2015, November) Inflation and activity: two explorations and their monetary policy implications. Working Paper Series WP15-19, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington

  • Blanchard OJ, Gali J (2007) The macroeconomic effects of oil price shocks: why are the 2000s so different from the 1970s? In: Galí J, Gertler M (eds) International dimensions of monetary policy. National Bureau of Economic Research Inc., Cambridge, pp 373–421

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ, Summers LH (1986) Hysteresis and the European unemployment problem. NBER Macroecon Annu 1:15–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolat S, Tiwari AK, Erdayi AU (2014) Unemployment hysteresis in the Eurozone area: evidences from nonlinear heterogeneous panel unit root test. Appl Econ Lett 21(8):536–540

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caporale GM, Gil-Alana LA, Lovcha Y (2016) Testing unemployment theories: a multivariate long memory approach. J Appl Econ 19(1):95–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlin W, Soskice D (1990) Macroeconomics and the wage bargain: a modern approach to employment, inflation, and the exchange rate. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlin W, Soskice D (2006) Macroeconomics: imperfections, institutions and policies. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Cevik EI, Dibooglu S (2013) Persistence and non-linearity in US unemployment: a regime-switching approach. Econ Syst 37(1):61–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheng S-C, Wu T-P, Lee K-C, Chang T (2014) Flexible fourier unit root test of unemployment for PIIGS countries. Econ Model 36:142–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Danziger D (2008) Adjustment costs, inventories and output. Scand J Econ 110(3):519–542

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davidson JEH, Hall SG (1991) Cointegration in recursive systems. Econ J 101(405):239–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Lee J, Lee C-C, Chang CP (2009) Hysteresis in unemployment revisited: evidence from panel LM unit root tests with heterogeneous structural breaks. Bull Econ Res 61(4):325–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delong JB, Summers LH (2012) Fiscal policy in a depressed economy. Brook Pap Econ Act 43(1):233–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dennis JG, Hansen H, Juselius K (2006) CATS in RATS. Cointegration analysis of time series, version 2. Estima, Evanston

    Google Scholar 

  • Dolado JJ, Jimeno JF (1997) The causes of Spanish unemployment: a structural VAR approach. Eur Econ Rev 41(7):1281–1307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doornik J, Hendry D (2013) PcGive 14, Volume II. OxMetrics 7. Timberlake Consultants

  • Doornik JA (2010) OxMetrics version 6.10

  • Doornik JA, Hendry DF (1998) Givewin. An interface to empirical modelling. Timberlake Consultants Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Franz W (1990) Hysteresis in economic relationships an overview. Physica-Verlag HD, Heidelberg, pp 1–17

    Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg D, Tirole J (1983) Capital as a commitment: strategic investment to deter mobility. J Econ Theory 31(2):227–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furuoka F (2017a) A new approach to testing unemployment hysteresis. Empir Econ 53(3):1253–1280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furuoka F (2017b) A new test for analysing hysteresis in european unemployment. Appl Econ Lett 24(15):1102–1106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gali J (2015, July) Hysteresis and the European unemployment problem revisited. NBER Working Papers 21430, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., Cambridge

  • García-Cintado A, Romero-Ávila D, Usabiaga C (2015) Can the hysteresis hypothesis in Spanish regional unemployment be beaten? New evidence from unit root tests with breaks. Econ Model 47:244–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Göcke M (2002) Various concepts of hysteresis applied in economics. J Econ Surv 16(2):167–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groth C (2009) Macroeconomic analysis. Mimeo, Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen, Copenhagen

    Google Scholar 

  • Gustavsson M, Österholm P (2009) The presence of unemployment hysteresis in the OECD: what can we learn from out-of-sample forecasts? Empir Econ 38:779–792

  • Hansen H, Warne A (2001) The cause of Danish unemployment: demand or supply shocks? Empir Econ 26(3):461–486

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holden S, Nymoen R (2002) Measuring structural unemployment: NAWRU estimates in the nordic countries. Scand J Econ 104(1):87–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoover K, Juselius K, Johansen S (2008) Allowing the data to speak freely: the macroeconometrics of the cointegrated vector autoregression. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 98(2):251–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobson T, Vredin A, Warne A (1997) Common trends and hysteresis in Scandinavian unemployment. Eur Econ Rev 41(9):1781–1816

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen S (1996) Likelihood-based inference in cointegrated vector autoregressive models. Advanced texts in econometrics. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansen S (2005) Interpretation of cointegrating coefficients in the cointegrated vector autoregressive model. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 67(1):93–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen S (2006) Confronting the economic model with the data, chapter 15. In: Colander D (ed) Post Walrasian macroeconomics: beyond the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model, vol 1. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 287–300

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Juselius K (2006) The cointegrated VAR model: econometric methodology and macroeconomics applications. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Klemp M, Møller NF (2015) Post-malthusian dynamics in pre-industrial scandinavia. Scand J Econ 118:841–867

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Layard R, Nickell S (1987) The labour market. In: Dornbusch R, Layard R (eds) The performance of the British economy. Clarendon, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Layard R, Nickell S, Jackman R (2005) Unemployment. Macroeconomic performance and the labour market, 2nd edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lee C-F, Hu T-C, Li P-C, Tsong C-C (2013) Asymmetric behavior of unemployment rates: evidence from the quantile covariate unit root test. Jpn World Econ 28:72–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A, Snower DJ (1986) Wage setting, unemployment, and insider-outsider relations. Am Econ Rev 76(2):235–39

    Google Scholar 

  • Lütkepohl H (2005) New introduction to multiple time series analysis. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Meng M, Strazicich MC, Lee J (2017) Hysteresis in unemployment? Evidence from linear and nonlinear unit root tests and tests with non-normal errors. Empir Econ 53(4):1399–1414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell W, Muysken J (2008) Full employment abandoned: shifting sands and policy failures. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Møller NF (2013) Understanding unemployment hysteresis: a system-based econometric approach to changing equilibria and slow adjustment. Discussion Papers 13-06, University of Copenhagen, Department of Economics

  • Møller NF, Sharp P (2013) Malthus in cointegration space: evidence of a post-malthusian pre-industrial England. J Econ Growth. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-013-9094-0

  • Mosconi R, Giannini C (1992) Non-causality in cointegrated systems: representation estimation and testing. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 54(3):399–417

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Shaughnessy T (2011) Hysteresis in unemployment. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 27(2):312–337

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Papell D, Murray C, Ghiblawi H (2000) The structure of unemployment. Rev Econ Stat 82(2):309–315

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps ES (ed) (1972) Inflation policy and unemployment theory; the cost-benefit approach to monetary planning, 1st edn. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Røed K (1997) Hysteresis in unemployment. J Econ Surv 11(4):389–418

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandberg R (2016) Testing for unit roots in nonlinear heterogeneous panels with smoothly changing trends: an application to Scandinavian unemployment rates. Empir Econ 51(3):1053–1083

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Srinivasan N, Mitra P (2014) The european unemployment problem: its cause and cure. Empir Econ 47(1):57–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vosseler A (2016) Bayesian model selection for unit root testing with multiple structural breaks. Comput Stat Data Anal 100:616–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Niels Framroze Møller.

Additional information

I would like to thank two anonymous referees, Christian Groth, Marc Klemp and Søren Johansen for their valuable comments and suggestions for improvements. Funding from Independent Research Fund Denmark is gratefully acknowledged.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (zip 19 KB)

A Appendices

A Appendices

1.1 The partitioned structural ECM and its reduced ECM form

The point of departure is the SECM for the full process, \( x_{t}\equiv (x_{1t}^{\prime },x_{2t}^{\prime })^{\prime },\) i.e.,

$$\begin{aligned} A\Delta x_{t}=m_{t}+Fx_{t-1}-C\Delta x_{t-1}+\varepsilon _{t}. \end{aligned}$$
(17)

This has the following block representation,

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \begin{array}{c@{\quad }l} A_{11} &{} A_{12} \\ 0 &{} A_{22} \end{array} \right) \left( \begin{array}{l} \Delta x_{1t} \\ \Delta x_{2t} \end{array} \right)= & {} \left( \begin{array}{l} m_{1t} \\ m_{2t} \end{array} \right) +\left( \begin{array}{c@{\quad }l} F_{11} &{} F_{12} \\ 0 &{} F_{22} \end{array} \right) \left( \begin{array}{l} x_{1t-1} \\ x_{2t-1} \end{array} \right) \nonumber \\&-\left( \begin{array}{c@{\quad }l} C_{11} &{} C_{12} \\ 0 &{} C_{22} \end{array} \right) \left( \begin{array}{l} \Delta x_{1t-1} \\ \Delta x_{2t-1} \end{array} \right) +\left( \begin{array}{l} \varepsilon _{1t} \\ \varepsilon _{2t} \end{array} \right) , \end{aligned}$$
(18)

corresponding to (2).

The corresponding reduced form ECM becomes,

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \begin{array}{l} \Delta x_{1t} \\ \Delta x_{2t} \end{array} \right)= & {} \left( \begin{array}{l} \mu _{1t} \\ \mu _{2t} \end{array} \right) +\left( \begin{array}{c@{\quad }l} \Pi _{11} &{} \Pi _{12} \\ 0 &{} \Pi _{22} \end{array}\right) \left( \begin{array}{l} x_{1t-1} \\ x_{2t-1} \end{array} \right) \nonumber \\&+\left( \begin{array}{c@{\quad }l} \Gamma _{11} &{} \Gamma _{12} \\ 0 &{} \Gamma _{22} \end{array} \right) \left( \begin{array}{l} \Delta x_{1t-1} \\ \Delta x_{2t-1} \end{array} \right) +\left( \begin{array}{l} \upsilon _{1t} \\ \upsilon _{2t} \end{array}\right) , \end{aligned}$$
(19)

with,

$$\begin{aligned} \mu _{t}\equiv & {} \left( \begin{array}{l} \mu _{1t} \\ \mu _{2t} \end{array} \right) =\left( \begin{array}{l} A_{11}^{-1}\left( m_{1}-A_{12}A_{22}^{-1}m_{2t}\right) \\ A_{22}^{-1}m_{2t} \end{array} \right) , \\ \Pi\equiv & {} \left( \begin{array}{c@{\quad }l} \Pi _{11} &{} \Pi _{12} \\ 0 &{} \Pi _{22} \end{array} \right) =\left( \begin{array}{c@{\quad }l} A_{11}^{-1}F_{11} &{} A_{11}^{-1}\left( F_{12}-A_{12}A_{22}^{-1}F_{22}\right) \\ 0 &{} A_{22}^{-1}F_{22} \end{array} \right) , \\ \Gamma _{1}\equiv & {} \left( \begin{array}{c@{\quad }l} \Gamma _{11} &{} \Gamma _{12} \\ 0 &{} \Gamma _{22} \end{array} \right) =\left( \begin{array}{c@{\quad }l} -A_{11}^{-1}C_{11} &{} -A_{11}^{-1}\left( C_{12}-A_{12}A_{22}^{-1}C_{22}\right) \\ 0 &{} -A_{22}^{-1}C_{22} \end{array}\right) , \end{aligned}$$

and \(\Gamma \) which is defined as \(I-\Gamma _{1}\) is thus,

$$\begin{aligned} \Gamma \equiv \left( \begin{array}{c@{\quad }l} I-\Gamma _{11} &{} -\Gamma _{12} \\ 0 &{} I-\Gamma _{22} \end{array} \right) =\left( \begin{array}{c@{\quad }c} I+A_{11}^{-1}C_{11} &{} A_{11}^{-1}\left( C_{12}-A_{12}A_{22}^{-1}C_{22}\right) \\ 0 &{} I+A_{22}^{-1}C_{22} \end{array} \right) . \end{aligned}$$

1.2 The UK application

1.2.1 The matrices

$$\begin{aligned} F= & {} \left( \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l@{\quad }l@{\quad }l@{\quad }l} \kappa _{1}+\kappa _{2}-1 &{} \rho _{1} &{} \rho _{21}+\rho _{22} &{} \rho _{5}+\rho _{6} &{} \rho _{3}+\rho _{4} \\ \phi _{2}+\phi _{3}+\phi _{4} &{} \kappa _{3}+\kappa _{4}-1 &{}\qquad 0 &{}\qquad 0 &{}\qquad 0 \\ \qquad 0 &{} \lambda _{1}+\lambda _{2}+\lambda _{3} &{} \kappa _{5}+\kappa _{6}-1 &{}\qquad 0 &{} \qquad 0 \\ \omega _{5}+\omega _{6} &{}\qquad 0 &{} \omega _{3}+\omega _{4} &{} \omega _{1}+\omega _{2}-1 &{}\qquad 0 \\ \qquad 0 &{}\qquad 0 &{}\qquad 0 &{}\qquad 0 &{} \pi _{2}+\pi _{3}-1 \end{array}\right) ,\\ A= & {} \left( \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l@{\quad }l@{\quad }l@{\quad }l} 1 &{} 0 &{} 0 &{} 0 &{} 0 \\ -\phi _{2} &{} 1 &{} 0 &{} 0 &{} 0 \\ 0 &{} -\lambda _{1} &{} 1 &{} 0 &{} 0 \\ 0 &{} 0 &{} -\omega _{3} &{} 1 &{} 0 \\ 0 &{} 0 &{} 0 &{} 0 &{} 1 \end{array} \right) ,C=\left( \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l@{\quad }l@{\quad }l@{\quad }l} \kappa _{2} &{} 0 &{} \rho _{22} &{} \rho _{6} &{} \rho _{4} \\ \phi _{4} &{} \kappa _{4} &{} 0 &{} 0 &{} 0 \\ 0 &{} \lambda _{3} &{} \kappa _{6} &{} 0 &{} 0 \\ \omega _{6} &{} 0 &{} 0 &{} \omega _{2} &{} 0 \\ 0 &{} 0 &{} 0 &{} 0 &{} \pi _{3} \end{array} \right) ,\\ m_{t}= & {} \left( \begin{array}{l} \rho _{0}-g_{A}t+z_{t}^{p} \\ \phi _{1}+z_{t}^{d} \\ \lambda _{0}+z_{t}^{u} \\ \omega _{0}+z_{t}^{w} \\ \pi _{1}+z_{t}^{o} \end{array} \right) . \end{aligned}$$

1.2.2 Accumulated multiplier notation

See Table 5.

Table 5 Accumulated multipliers corresponding to the UK application

1.2.3 Description of the data

See Table 6.

Table 6 Description of the UK data

1.2.4 Misspecification tests

See Table 7.

Table 7 Misspecification vector tests

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Møller, N.F. Decoding unemployment persistence: an econometric framework for identifying and comparing the sources of persistence with an application to UK macrodata. Empir Econ 56, 1489–1514 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1400-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1400-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation