Skip to main content
Log in

Accelerating the transition to employment at benefit exhaustion: still possible after four years of unemployment?

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper provides evidence of how the long-term unemployed react to the threat of running out of unemployment insurance (UI) after receiving it for nearly 4 years. To identify the effect of UI exhaustion, we make use of a 1999 Danish legislative change that progressively reduced potential benefit duration from 5 to 4 years. We find that shortening UI duration hastens the transition to employment throughout the unemployment spell up to benefit exhaustion even if it occurs as long as 4 years later. However, although the proportional effect is large, it is small in absolute value.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source OECD

Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Source DREAM data, men aged 25–44 years starting a fresh UI period in 1998

Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Source DREAM data. Men aged 25–44 years starting a fresh UI period in 1998

Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Source DREAM data, men aged 25–44 years starting a fresh UI period in 1998

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For men in particular, Caliendi et al. (2013) find that jobs accepted close to and after UI exhaustion are associated with lower quality, whilst those accepted when they are still insured tend to have higher quality (i.e. the UI recipients can be more selective).

  2. The UIFs are private associations of employees or self-employed persons organised solely for ensuring economic support in the event of unemployment. However, UI is largely financed by the state.

  3. 1 EUR \(=\) 7.45 DKK.

  4. Employment on the side, refusal of job offers, cheating or lock-out can lead to UI reduction.

  5. As the PBD is reduced in the passive period, individuals did not have different lengths of the activation period. Had such differences existed, they could have affected the effect at the end of entitlement. Nevertheless, Rosholm and Svarer (2008) do not find a threat effect for Danish workers with more than 1 year of unemployment.

  6. Whilst a new reform in 2007 reduced the passive period, the maximum duration of UI benefits remained unchanged. In 2010, a new reform reduced the maximum duration of UI from 4 to 2 years.

  7. As the previous reform dated 1994 was fully implemented first in January 1998, we look only at individuals starting a fresh period in 1998.

  8. Theoretically, individuals starting a fresh spell in 1998 and who were unemployed during the entire PBD experienced a reduction in 9 months at the most.

  9. Den Registerbaserede Evaluering Af Marginaliseringsomfanget (DREAM), Administrative Recorded Evaluation of the Extent of Marginalisation.

  10. Individuals who are not in a legal sense searching for work receive at least one of the following subsidies: unemployment subsidy for the not-labour-market-ready unemployed (includes special courses, workplace internships), social assistance for the not-labour-market-ready unemployed (includes special courses, workplace internships), sabbatical leave, disability pension, early retirement, student subsidy, flexjob (special working conditions) subsidy, rehabilitation and sickness benefits.

  11. These definitions are based on Statistics Denmark’s classification of the population into three groups: native Danes, immigrants, and descendants of immigrants (i.e. the second generation of immigrants). Native Danes are individuals born in Denmark with at least one parent who is not only a Danish citizen but was also born in Denmark. Immigrants (first generation) are defined as foreign-born individuals with foreign-born parents or parents with foreign citizenship. Descendants of immigrants (second generation) are defined as individuals born in Denmark to foreign-born parents or parents with foreign citizenship. In the analysis, we group first- and second-generation immigrants under the ‘immigrant’ category.

  12. Individuals only regain a fresh spell if they worked at least 52 weeks during the preceding 3 years.

  13. The data show that 90% of the 5-week breaks occur in summer, when people are expected to take a holiday.

  14. According to this definition of calendar time, the reform is implemented in the beginning of month 13.

  15. \(\hbox {PBD}_{is} \left( \tau \right) = 60\) for all first fresh UI spells that started in 1998 (\(\tau \le \)12) before the reform was implemented. From Fig. 2, we can further deduce that for fresh UI spells that start after the reform \(PBD_{is} \left( \tau \right) = 51\) for 12 \(< \tau = 22, {\hbox {PBD}}_{is} \left( \tau \right) = 50\) for \(\tau = 23, {\hbox {PBD}}_{is} \left( \tau \right) = 49\) for \(\tau = 24\) and \({\hbox {PBD}}_{is} \left( \tau \right) = 48\) for \(\tau > 24\).

  16. \(d_{ist} \) measures the total sum of months which individual i has spent as unemployed in 1998. That is, \(d_{ist} =t+\sum \nolimits _{j=1}^{j=S-1} T_{ij}\) measured in calendar month December 1998 (or \(\tau +t=12\)), where \(T_{ij}\) denote, the duration of the sth unemployment spell since first entry in 1998. Given that individuals enter the sample with a fresh unemployment spell in 1998, it is not possible to gain the right to a subsequent fresh UI period prior to January 1999.

  17. To incorporate market conditions at entry, we also include local unemployment rates as covariates.

  18. The parameters and error terms are now state-specific.

  19. The three states are staying unemployed, transiting into employment and transiting into other social benefits.

  20. For the duration effect of unemployment on the transition into employment, see Appendix Fig. 8.

  21. This effect is measured in comparison with the reference category ‘15 or more months until UI exhaustion’.

  22. We use the lower bound of the 95% confidence interval.

  23. For the duration effect of UI on the transition to other benefits, see Appendix Fig. 9.

  24. To investigate heterogeneity, we attempted to estimate interaction terms between individual characteristics and UI durations, but these specifications of the model did not converge.

References

  • Addison JT, Portugal P (2004) How does the unemployment insurance system shape the time profile of jobless duration? Econ Lett 85:229–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergström R, Edin P (1992) Time aggregation and the distributional shape of unemployment duration. J Appl Econ 7:5–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boone J, Van Ours JC (2012) Why is there a spike in the job finding rate at benefit exhaustion? De Economist 160:413–438

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burdett K (1979) Unemployment insurance as a search subsidy: a theoretical analysis. Econ Inq 17:333–343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caliendo M, Tatsiramos K, Uhlendorff A (2013) Benefit duration, unemployment duration and job match quality: a regression discontinuity approach. J Appl Econom 28:604–627

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D, Chetty R, Weber A (2007) The spike at benefit exhaustion: leaving the unemployment system or starting a new job? Am Econ Rev 97:113–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D, Levine PB (2000) Extended benefits and the duration of UI spells: evidence from the New Jersey extended benefit program. J Public Econ 78:107–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carling K, Edin PA, Harkman A, Holmlund B (1996) Unemployment duration, unemployment benefits, and labor market programs in Sweden. J Public Econ 59:313–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D’Addio AC, Rosholm M (2005) Exits from temporary jobs in Europe: a competing risks analysis. Labour Econ 12:449–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DØRS (2007) Dansk Økonomi, forår 2007, kapitel III Dansk arbejdsmarkedspolitik efter år 2000 [The Danish economy, Spring 2007, Chapter III The Danish labour market after 2000] Copenhagen: DØRS

  • Filges T, Geerdsen L P, Knudsen A-S D, Jørgensen A-M K, Kowalski K (2013) Unemployment benefit exhaustion: incentive effects on job finding rates: a systematic review. Campbell Syst Rev 4

  • Fortin B, Lacroix G, Drolet S (2004) Welfare benefits and the duration of welfare spells: evidence from a natural experiment in Canada. J Public Econ 88:1495–1520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaure S, Røed K, Westlie L (2012) Job search incentives and job match quality. Labour Econ 19:438–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geerdsen LP (2006) Is there a threat effect of labour market programmes? A study of ALMP in the Danish UI system. Econ J 116:738–750

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geerdsen LP, Holm A (2007) Duration of UI periods and the perceived threat effect from labour market programmes. Labour Econ 14:639–652

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graversen BK, Larsen B (2013) Is there a threat effect of mandatory activation programmes for the long-term unemployed? Empir Econ 44:1031–1051

  • Ham JC, Rea J (1987) Unemployment insurance and male unemployment duration in Canada. J Labor Econ 5:325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J, Singer B (1984) A method for minimizing the impact of distributional assumptions in econometric models for duration data. Econometrica 52:271–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins SP (1995) Easy estimation methods for discrete-time duration models. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 57:129–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins SP, García-Serrano C (2004) The relationship between unemployment benefits and re-employment probabilities: evidence from Spain. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 66:239–260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz LF, Meyer BD (1990) The impact of the potential duration of unemployment benefits on the duration of unemployment. J Public Econ 41:45–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kroft K, Lange F, Notowidigdo MJ (2013) Duration dependence and labor market conditions: evidence from a field experiment. Q J Econ 128:1123–1167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kyyrä T, Parrotta P, Rosholm M (2013) The effect of receiving supplementary UI benefits on unemployment duration. Labour Econ 21:122–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lalive R, Zweimüller J (2004) Benefit entitlement and unemployment duration: the role of policy endogeneity. J Public Econ 88:2587–2616

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyer BD (1990) Unemployment Insurance and unemployment spells. Econometrica 58:757–782

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moffitt R (1985) Unemployment insurance and the distribution of unemployment spells. J Econom 28:85–101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moffitt R, Nicholson W (1982) The effect of unemployment insurance on unemployment: the case of federal supplemental benefits. Rev Econ Stat 64:1–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mortensen DT (1977) Unemployment insurance and job search decisions. Ind Labor Relat Rev 30:505–517

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pellizzari M (2006) Unemployment duration and the interactions between unemployment insurance and social assistance. Labour Econ 13:773–798

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rebollo-Sanz Y (2012) Unemployment insurance and job turnover in Spain. Labour Econ 19:403–426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogers CL (1998) Expectations of unemployment insurance and unemployment duration. J Labor Econ 16:630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosholm M (2001) Cyclical variations in unemployment duration. J Popul Econ 14:173–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosholm M, Svarer M (2008) The threat effect of active labour market programmes. Scand J Econ 110:385–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tatsiramos K, Ours JC (2014) Labor market effects of unemployment insurance design. J Econ Surv 28:284–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tuomala J (2011) The threat effect of mandatory programmes in Finland. Labour 25:508–527

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van den Berg GJ (1990) Nonstationarity in job search theory. Rev Econ Stud 57:255–277

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Klaauw B, Van Ours JC (2013) Carrot and stick: how re-employment bonuses and benefit sanctions affect exit rates from welfare. J Appl Econom 28:275–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Ours JC, Vodopivec M (2006) How shortening the potential duration of unemployment benefits affects the duration of unemployment: evidence from a natural experiment. J Labor Econ 24:351–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Ours JC, Vodopivec M (2008) Does reducing unemployment insurance generosity reduce job match quality? J Public Econ 92:684–695

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weatherall CD (2008) Education at workplaces: long-term unemployment, wages and enrolment. Department of Economics. University of Copenhagen, Denmark

    Google Scholar 

  • Winkelmann L, Winkelmann R (1998) Why are the unemployed so unhappy? Evidence from panel data. Economica 65:1–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Michael Svarer, Jan Høgelund, Steven Jenkins, Brian Krogh Graversen, David Grubb, Anders Holm, Ismir Mulalic, and Bo Honoré for helpful comments and Natalie Reid for thoroughly rereading the paper and providing valuable language usage assistance. We would also like to thank an anonymous editor. Next, we are grateful to Aske Egsgaard-Pedersen for research assistance and to participants at EALE 2013 and the SFI Advisory Research Board for comments and suggestions. We also acknowledge financial support from the Strategic Programme for Welfare Research.

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Cecilie Dohlmann Weatherall.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 3 Extra parameters and standard errors in Table 2 for complementary log–log model and competing risk model taking dynamic sorting into account.
Fig. 8
figure 8

Source DREAM data, men aged 25–44 years who started a ‘fresh’ unemployment spell in 1998

Estimated duration effect of staying unemployed, presented as odds ratio of finding a job (compared to first 3 months as unemployed). Note The number of observations consists of 438,338 UI months. Remaining UI months can be negative if the UI administration gives extensions because of administrative errors or procedural delays.

Fig. 9
figure 9

Source DREAM data. Men aged 25–44 years starting a fresh spell in 1998

Estimated duration effect of staying unemployed, presented as odds ratio of exiting to other income support (compared to first 3 months as unemployed). Note The number of observations consists of 438,338 UI months. Remaining UI months can be negative if the UI administration provides extensions because of administrative errors or procedural delays.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Geerdsen, L.P., Lyk-Jensen, S.V. & Weatherall, C.D. Accelerating the transition to employment at benefit exhaustion: still possible after four years of unemployment?. Empir Econ 54, 1107–1135 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1236-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1236-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation