Advertisement

Empirical Economics

, Volume 45, Issue 1, pp 305–321 | Cite as

Housing prices and crime perception

  • Paolo Buonanno
  • Daniel MontolioEmail author
  • Josep Maria Raya-Vílchez
Article

Abstract

In this article, we combine data from the housing market with data from a victimization survey to estimate the effect of crime perception on housing prices in the City of Barcelona from 2004 to 2006. Using dwelling data and a hedonic price model (using both OLS and quantile regressions), in the first stage, we estimate the shadow price of the location of dwellings. In the second stage, we analyse the impact of crime perception, after controlling for other district characteristics such as local public spending and immigration, on this locational valuation. After accounting for the possible endogeneity of crime and housing prices, our findings suggest that crime exerts relevant costs beyond its direct costs. Indeed, a one standard deviation increase in perceived security is associated with a 0.57 % increase in the valuation of districts. Moreover, in districts perceived as being less safe than the average for the City of Barcelona, houses are highly discounted. Less safe districts have on average a valuation that is 1.27 % lower.

Keywords

Housing prices Crime perception Security perception Hedonic prices 

JEL Classification

K42 R21 R31 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Anderson DA (1999) The aggregate burden of crime. J Law Econ 42: 611–642CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Bartik TJ (1987) The estimation of demand parameters in hedonic price models. J Polit Econ 95: 81–88CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Becker SO, Bentolila S, Fernandes A, Ichino A (2010) Youth emancipation and perceived job insecurity of parents and children. J Popul Econ 23: 1175–1199CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Bell B, Fasani F, Machin S (2010) Crime and immigration: evidence from large immigrant waves. CEP Discussion Papers dp0984, Centre for Economic Performance, LSEGoogle Scholar
  5. Bianchi M, Buonanno P, Pinotti P (2012) Do immigrants cause crime?. J Eur Econ Assoc (forthcoming)Google Scholar
  6. Black SE (1999) Do better schools matter? Parental valuation of elementary education. Q J Econ 114: 577–599CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Bound J, Holzer H (2000) Demand shifts, population adjustment, and labour market outcomes. J Lab Econ 1: 20–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Bowes DR, Ihlanfeldt KR (2001) Identifying the impacts of rail transit stations on residential property values. J Urban Econ 50: 1–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Brand S, Price N (2000) The economic and social costs of crime. Home Office Research Study n°. 217Google Scholar
  10. Buchinsky M (1995) Estimating the asymptotic covariance matrix for quantile regression models a Monte Carlo study. J Econ 68: 303–338Google Scholar
  11. Buchinsky M (1997) Recent advances in quantile regression models: a practical guideline for empirical research. J Hum Resour 33: 88–126CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Buonanno P, Montolio D (2009) Juvenile crime in Spain. Appl Econ Lett 16: 495–500CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Buonanno P, Montolio D, Vanin P (2009) Does social capital reduce crime?. J Law Econ 52: 145–170CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Chay KY, Greenstone M (2005) Does air quality matter? Evidence from the housing market. J Polit Econ 113: 376–424CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Colwell F, Dilmore G (1999) Who was first?. An examination of an early hedonic study. Land Econ 75: 620–626CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Cook PJ, MacDonald J (2011) Public safety through private action: an economic assessment of BIDS. Econ J 121: 445–462CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Court AT (1939) Hedonic price indexes with automotive examples in “the dynamics of automobile demand”. General Motors, New York, pp 98–119Google Scholar
  18. Detotto C, Vannini M (2010) Counting the cost of crime in Italy. Working Paper CRENoS, No. 2010-13Google Scholar
  19. Essex S, Chalkley B (1998) Olympic games: catalyst of urban change. Leis Study 17: 187–206CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Garcia J, Montolio D, Raya JM (2010) Local public expenditures and housing prices. Urban Study 47: 1501–1510CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Gibbons S (2004) The costs of urban property crime. Econ J 114: F441–F463CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. González L, Ortega F (2009) Immigration and housing booms: evidence from Spain. IZA Discuss Paper 4333Google Scholar
  23. Goodman CA (1998) Andrew court and the invention of hedonic price analysis. J Urban Econ 44: 291–298CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Griliches Z (1971) Hedonic price indexes for automobiles: an econometric analysis of quality change. NBER 73: 173–196Google Scholar
  25. Hellman DA, Naroff JL (1979) The impact of crime on urban residential property values. Urban Study 16: 105–112Google Scholar
  26. Ihlanfeldt KR, Martínez-Vázquez J (1986) Alternative value estimates of owner-occupied housing: evidence on sample selection bias and systematic errors. J Urban Econ 20: 356–369CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Lancaster KJ (1966) A new approach to consumer theory. J Polit Econ 74: 132–157CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Levitt SD, Lochner L (2001) The determinants of juvenile crime. NBER Chapters in: Risky behavior among youths: an economic analysis, pp 327–374Google Scholar
  29. Lynch AK, Rasmussen DW (2001) Measuring the impact of crime on house prices. Appl Econ 33: 1981–1989CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. MacDonald Z (2002) Official crime statistics: their use and interpretation. Econ J 112: F85–F106CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Mendelsohn R (1984) Estimating the structural equations of implicit markets and household production functions. Rev Econ Stat 66: 673–677CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Mills ES, Simenauer R (1996) New hedonic estimates of regional constant quality house prices. J Urban Econ 39: 209–215CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Nunziata L (2011) Crime perception and victimization in Europe: does immigration matter? CSEA Working Paper 04/2011Google Scholar
  34. Oates WE (1969) The effects of property taxes and local public spending on property vales: an empirical study of tax capitalization and the tiebout hypothesis. J Polit Econ 77: 957–971CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Palmquist RB (1984) Estimating the demand for the characteristics of housing. Rev Econ Stat 66: 394–404CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Peña D, Ruiz-Castillo J (1984) Distributional aspects of public rental housing and rent control policies in Spain. J Urban Econ 15: 350–370CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Rizzo MJ (1979) The effect of crime on residential rents and property values. Am Econ 23: 16–21Google Scholar
  38. Rosen S (1974) Hedonic prices and implicit markets: product differentiation in pure competition. J Polit Econ 82: 34–55CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Soares R (2010) Welfare costs of crime and common violence: a critical review. PUC Working Paper Series no. 581Google Scholar
  40. Stock JH, Yogo M (2002) Testing for weak instruments in linear IV regression. NBER: 284Google Scholar
  41. Tabellini G (2008) Presidential address institutions and culture. J Eur Econ Assoc 6: 255–294CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Thaler R (1978) A note on the value of crime control: evidence from the property market. J Urban Econ 5: 137–145CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Tinbergen J (1951) Some remarks on the distribution of labour incomes. Int Econ Pap 1: 195–207Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag 2012

Authors and Affiliations

  • Paolo Buonanno
    • 1
  • Daniel Montolio
    • 2
    Email author
  • Josep Maria Raya-Vílchez
    • 3
  1. 1.Dipartimento di Scienze EconomicheUniversity of BergamoBergamoItaly
  2. 2.Facultat d’Economia i EmpresaUniversity of Barcelona and Barcelona Institute of EconomicsBarcelonaSpain
  3. 3.Departament d’Economia i EmpresaEscola Universitària del Maresme, University Pompeu FabraBarcelonaSpain

Personalised recommendations