Skip to main content
Log in

Agglomeration and regional growth policy: externalities versus comparative advantages

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
The Annals of Regional Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper explores the existence of different types of static and dynamic externalities and shows the relationship between externalities, interregional trade, and cluster policy. By guiding policy in choosing the most appropriate strategy for facing some frequent dilemmas, this paper has clear implications in regional development policy and adds to the existent literature in three ways. First, it contributes to a better characterization of dynamic externalities by extending the “advantages of backwardness” approach, formerly developed to explain the catching-up of national economies, to the regional context. Second, the paper presents a new model that relates static and dynamic externalities to the clustering mode of production in the regional context. Third, the paper contributes to give a more accurate theoretic basis to the regional cluster policy and to help policy-makers in choosing the right policy for increasing the well-being of depressed regions. The major conclusion is that policy must pursue a combination of the comparative advantage principle with one type of dynamic externalities uncovered in this paper: the “related variety benefits” of agglomeration.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Porter’s diamond model considers the following as the most important factors for explaining the competitive advantage of nations: (i) the context for firm strategy and rivalry; (ii) demand conditions; (iii) factor conditions; and (iv) related and supporting industries.

  2. Gordon and McCann (2000) suggest three basic models of cluster processes: agglomeration economies, industrial complex, and social networks. Each of these models produces cluster benefits in very different ways. But, as these authors have recognized (2000: 528), “actual clusters may contain elements of more than one type.”

  3. Of course, cluster development is not the only option for local and regional development (Karlsson 2008b). There are other alternatives to cluster policies for stimulating regional economic growth, and it has been alleged that many of them are also responsible by positive externalities: investments in machines and equipment (DeLong and Summers 1991), infrastructures (Barro 1990), human capital (Lucas 1988), and R&D (Romer 1990). The question of finding the most effective of these policies in pulling the economic growth is empirical in nature and is therefore beyond the scope of this paper.

  4. These prescriptions are synthesized in Woodward and Guimaraes (2009): (i) supporting the development of all clusters, not choosing among them; (ii) reinforcing established and promising clusters rather than attempting to create entirely new ones; (iii) cluster initiatives are advanced by the private sector, with government as facilitator; (iv) development should not be guided by top-down policy strategies.

  5. For a review of the theory of firm location decisions and the dynamic of industrial clusters, see Maggioni (2002, especially Chap. 3). Trying to give some order to the “conflicting conceptualizations” and “generated ambiguity,” Karlsson (2008a) reviews the models and origins of clusters.

  6. A convenient assumption used in monopolistic competition models consists of considering that firms prefer localizations near households and vice versa, as in Fujita (1988).

  7. For a deeper discussion of the character and role of pecuniary and technological externalities, see Johansson (2005). David and Rosenbloom (1990, p. 349) explore, in a stylized approach, agglomeration pecuniary externalities “that tend to reduce the prices at which primary inputs can be purchased as more and more of those inputs come to be assembled at the locale in question.”

  8. For a discussion of agglomeration economics, and specifically of the importance of clustering and agglomeration, see McCann (2008).

  9. While the expression “related industries’ is used by many authors (Scherer 1982; Morris 1990; Feldman and Audretsch 1999; Porter 2000) with different meanings, the “related variety benefits” is used in this paper as derived from “industry relatedness” with the meaning given by Neffke and Henning (2009): the extent to the knowledge and skill base of two industries overlap.

  10. This also explains why the relevant distinction, at the microlevel, between external economies of scale and scope (Goldstein and Gronberg 1984; Parr 2002) is not considered in Table 1.

  11. The term Marshall–Arrow–Romer (MAR) externalities, which relates to technological spillovers between the firms within an industry, was coined by Glaeser et al. (1992) when they added the Arrow’s (1962) formalization of learning and the Romer’s (1986) contributions regarding the impact of dynamic knowledge accumulation to the Marshall’s (1920) seminal idea of localization economies. Storper (2009) disputes the MAR concept, arguing that the true Romer’s sources of increasing returns are not in essence local.

  12. The reasons why some regions have more learning capability than others are varied: (a) some types of activities can be more prone to knowledge spillovers than others; (b) regional clusters with strong industry–institutional linkages can increase the region’s capacity to absorb knowledge spillovers; (c) the embodied capabilities of the labor force are not the same across regions, given not only different levels of formal education but also the industry-specific tacit knowledge; (d) different regional endowments of entrepreneurial talent.

  13. These are some reasons why one can consider the “death of geography” thesis as “exaggerated” (Morgan 2004), although proximity must not be considered only in terms of geographical distance (Boschma 2005).

  14. According to Porter (1990), it is local competition, as opposed to local monopoly, that promotes the pursuit and rapid adoption of innovation.

  15. The negative correlation between the initial productivity level and productivity growth rate is also stated in the neoclassical growth theory (see Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1992); however, the “advantages of backwardness” approach calls attention to other factors that are absent from the neoclassical theory.

  16. One of such adjustments is related to the mobility factor: labor mobility is higher across national regions than across countries.

  17. The concrete process of allocation is not important. Given the general assumptions formulated, the conclusions will be the same if there is a central planning authority or if allocation is done by market.

  18. Recall that we use labor in R as the numeraire.

  19. Of course, the amount of benefits depends also on the absorptive capacity of the \(P\) economy. However, for simplicity, we have opted for not introducing a new variable for controlling this effect. Besides, the inclusion of such variable would not change the main model conclusions.

  20. For a discussion about how cluster strategies work and the implications for theory and policy, see Karlsson (2008b).

References

  • Abramovitz M (1979) rapid growth potential and its realisation: the experience of capitalist economics in the post-war period. In: Malinvaud E (ed) Economic growth and resources: vol I: The major issues. Macmillan, London, pp 1–30

  • Abramovitz M (1986) Catching-up, forging ahead and falling behind. J Econ Hist 46(2):386–406

    Google Scholar 

  • Abramovitz M, David P (1995) Convergence and deferred catch-up productivity leadership and the waning of American exceptionalism. In: Landau R, Taylor T, Wright G (eds) Growth and development: the economics of the 21st century. Stanford CA, Stanford UP

  • Almeida P, Kogut B (1999) Localization of knowledge and the mobility of engineers in regional networks. Manag Sci 45:905–917

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow K (1962) The economic implications of learning by doing. Rev Econ Stud 29:155–173

    Google Scholar 

  • Asheim B, Gertler M (2005) The geography of innovation. In: Fagerberg J, Mowery DC, Nelson RR (eds) (2006) The Oxford handbook of innovation, Chap. 11, pp 291–317

  • Bailly A (1998) The region: a basic concept for understanding local areas and global systems, Cybergeo. Eur J Geogr. doi:10.4000/cybergeo.333

  • Baptista R, Swann P (1998) Do firms in clusters innovate more? Res Policy 27:525–540

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro R (1990) Government spending in a simple model of endogenous growth. J Polit Econ 98(5):S103–S125

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro R, Sala-i-Martin X (1992) Convergence. J Polit Econ 100:223–251

    Google Scholar 

  • Bathelt H, Schuldt N (2010) International trade fairs and global buzz, part I: ecology of global buzz. Eur Plan Stud 18:1957–1974

    Google Scholar 

  • Bathelt H, Malmberg A, Maskell P (2004) Clusters and knowledge: Local buzz, global pipelines and the process of knowledge creation. Prog Hum Geogr 28:31–56

    Google Scholar 

  • Beaudry C, Schiffauerova A (2009) Who’s right, Marshall or Jacobs? The localization versus urbanization debate. Res Policy 38:318–337

    Google Scholar 

  • Benneworth P, Danson M, Raines P, Whittam G (2003) Confusing clusters: making sense of the cluster approach in theory and practice. Eur Plan Stud 11(5):511–520

    Google Scholar 

  • Boschma R (2005) Proximity and innovation: a critical assessment. Reg Stud 39(1):61–74

    Google Scholar 

  • Boschma R (2009) Evolutionary economic geography and its implications for regional innovation policy. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Boschma R, Frenken K (2011) The emerging empirics of evolutionary economic geography. J Econ Geogr 11(2):295–307

    Google Scholar 

  • Boschma R, Wenting R (2007) The spatial evolution of the British automobile industry. Does location matter? Ind Corp Change 16(2):213–238

    Google Scholar 

  • Brachert M, Titze M, Kubis A (2011) Identifying industrial clusters from a multidimensional perspective: methodical aspects with an application to Germany. Pap Reg Sci 90(2):419–440

    Google Scholar 

  • Braun E, MacDonald S (1978) Revolution in miniature: the history and impact of semiconductor electronics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Brenner T, Mühlig A (2007) Factors and mechanisms causing the emergence of local industrial clusters—a meta-study of 159 cases. Papers on Economics & Evolution No 0723. Max Planck Institute of Economics, Jena

  • Camagni R (1991) Local ‘milieu’, uncertainty and innovation networks: towards a new dynamic theory of economic space. In: Camagni R (ed) Innovation networks: spatial perspectives. Belhaven Press, London, pp 121–144

    Google Scholar 

  • Ciccone A (2002) Agglomeration effects in Europe. Eur Econ Rev 46:213–227

    Google Scholar 

  • Ciccone A, Hall R (1996) Productivity and the density of economic activity. Am Econ Rev 86(1):54–70

    Google Scholar 

  • Corden M (1997) Trade policy and economic welfare, 2nd edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Coe D, Helpman E (1995) International R&D spillovers. Eur Econ Rev 39(5):859–887

    Google Scholar 

  • Coe D, Helpman E, Hoffmaister A (1997) North-South R&D spillovers. Econ J 107:134–149

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen MD, Levinthal DA (1990) Absorptive capacity. A new perspective on learning and innovation. Adm Sci Q 35:128–152

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooke P (2001) Clusters as key determinants of economic growth: the example of biotechnology. In: Mariussen A (ed) Cluster policies —cluster development? Nordregio Report 2001/2. Stockholm

  • Cooke P (2002) Knowledge economies: clusters, learning and cooperative advantage. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper D (2001) Innovation and reciprocal externalities: information transmission via job mobility. J Econ Behav Org 45(4):403–425

    Google Scholar 

  • David P, Rosenbloom J (1990) Marshallian factor market externalities and the dynamics of industrial location. J Urban Econ 28:349–370

    Google Scholar 

  • de Groot H, Poot J, Smit M (2008) Agglomeration externalities, innovation and regional growth: theoretical perspectives and meta-analysis. Department of Economics Working Paper Series, No 1/08. Hamilton, New Zealand: University of Waikato

  • DeLong B, Summers L (1991) Equipment investment and economic growth. Q J Econ 106(2):445–502

    Google Scholar 

  • Duranton G (2011) California Dreamin’: the feeble case for cluster policies. Rev Econ Anal 3(1):3–45

    Google Scholar 

  • Duranton G, Puga D (2001) Nursery cities: urban diversity, process innovation, and the life cycle of products. Am Econ Rev 91(5):1454–1477

    Google Scholar 

  • Enright M (1996) Regional clusters and economic development: A research agenda. In: Staber U, Schaefer NV, Sharma B (eds) Business networks: prospects for regional development. De Gruyter, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2008) The concept of clusters and cluster policies and their role for competitiveness and innovation: main statistical results and lessons learned, Commission Staff Working Document No. SEC 2637, Europe INNOVA/PRO INNO Europe Paper No. 9. European Communities, Luxembourg

  • Fagerberg J (1987) A technology gap approach to why growth rates differ. Res Policy 16:87–89

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagerberg J, Verspagen B (2002) Technology-gaps, innovation-diffusion and transformation: an evolutionary interpretation. Res Policy 31:1291–1304

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldman M (2000) Location and innovation: the new economic geography of innovation, spillovers, and agglomeration. In: Clark GL, Feldman M, Gertler M (eds) Oxford handbook of economic geography. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 373–394

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldman M, Audretsch D (1999) Innovation in cities: science-based diversity, specialization and localized competition. Eur Econ Rev 43(2):409–429

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman T (1961) A hundred years of geography. Gerald Duckworth, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Frenken K, Van Oort F, Verburg T (2007) Related variety, unrelated variety and regional economic growth. Reg Stud 41(5):685–697

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M (1988) A monopolistic competition model of spatial agglomeration: a differentiated product approach. Reg Sci Urban Econ 18:87–124

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M, Thisse J-F (2002) Economics of agglomeration: cities, industrial location, and regional growth. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Gertler M (2003) Tacit knowledge and the economic geography of context, or the undefinable tacitness of being (there). J Econ Geogr 3(1):75–99

    Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser E, Gottlieb J (2009) The wealth of cities: agglomeration economies and spatial equilibrium in the United States. J Econ Lit 47:983–1028

    Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser E, Maré D (2001) Cities and skills. J Lab Econ 19(2):316–342

    Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser E, Kallal H, Scheinkman J, Shleifer A (1992) Growth in cities. J Polit Econ 100(6):1126–1152

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein GS, Gronberg TJ (1984) Economies of scope and economies of agglomeration. J urban Econ 16:91–104

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon IR, McCann P (2000) Industrial clusters: complexes, agglomeration and/or social networks? Urban Stud 37(3):513–532

    Google Scholar 

  • Grabher G (1993) The weakness of strong ties: the ‘lock-in’ of regional development in the Ruhr area. In: Grabher G (ed) The embedded firm: on the socio-economics of industrial networks. Routledge, London, pp 255–277

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrison B, Kelley M, Gant J (1996) Specialization versus diversity in local economies: the implications for innovative private-sector behavior. Cityscape: J Policy Dev Res 2:61–93

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson V, Kuncoro A, Turner M (1995) Industrial development in cities. J Polit Econ 103:1067–1085

    Google Scholar 

  • Henning M, Moodysson J, Nilsson M (2010) Innovation and regional transformation: from clusters to new combinations. Region Skåne, Malmö

    Google Scholar 

  • Hospers G-J, Sautet F, Desrochers P (2008) Silicon somewhere: Is there a need for cluster policy? In: Karlsson C (ed) (2008b) Handbook of research on innovation and cluster: cases and policies, chap. 24, Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, Cheltenham

  • Isaksen A (1997) Regional clusters and competitiveness: the Norwegian case. Eur Plan Stud 5:65–76

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs J (1969) The economy of cities. Penguin, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs J (1984) Cities and the wealth of nations: principles of economic life. Vintage, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe A, Trajtenberg M, Henderson R (1993) Geographic localization of knowledge spillovers as evidenced by patent citations. Q J Econ 108(3):577–598

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansson B (2005) Parsing the menagerie of agglomeration and network externalities. In: Karlsson C, Johansson B, Stough R (eds) Industrial clusters and inter-firm networks, chapter 5. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansson B, Karlsson C, Stough R (eds) (2001) Theories of endogenous regional growth: lessons for regional policies. Advances in spatial science. Springer, Berlin

  • Karlsson C (ed) (2008a) Handbook of research on cluster theory (handbooks of research on clusters series, 1) Ed Elgar Publishing Limited, Cheltenham

  • Karlsson C (ed) (2008b) Handbook of research on innovation and cluster: cases and policies (Handbooks of research on clusters series, 2) Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, Cheltenham

  • Keeble D, Wilkinson F (eds) (2000) High-technology clusters. Networking and collective learning in Europe, Ashgate, Aldershot

  • Ketelhöhn N (2006) The role of clusters as sources of dynamic externalities in the US semiconductor industry. J Econ Geogr 6(5):679–699

    Google Scholar 

  • King C, Silk A, Ketelhöhn N (2003) Knowledge spillovers and the growth in the disagglomeration of the US advertising-agency industry. J Econ Manag Strateg 12:327–362

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1991a) Geography and trade. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman PR (1991b) Increasing returns and economic geography. J Polit Econ 99:483–499

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (2011) The new economic geography, now middle-aged. Reg Stud 45:1–7

    Google Scholar 

  • Leslie S (2000) The biggest “Angel” of them all: the military and the making of Silicon Valley. In: Kenney M (ed) Understanding Silicon Valley: the anatomy of an entrepreneurial region. Stanford University Press, Stanford, pp 48–67

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas RE Jr (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monetary Econ 22(1):3–42

    Google Scholar 

  • Macher J, Mowery D, Hodges D (1998) Reversal of fortune? The recovery of the US semiconductor industry. Calif Manag Rev 41:107–136

    Google Scholar 

  • Maggioni M (2002) Clustering dynamics and the location of high-tech-firms (contributions to economics). Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Malmberg A, Maskell P (2002) The elusive concept of localization economies: towards a knowledge-based theory of spatial clustering. Environ Plan A 34(3):429–449

    Google Scholar 

  • Malmberg A, Maskell P (2006) Localized learning revisited. Growth Change 37(1):1–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Malmberg A, Power D (2005) (How) do (Firms in) clusters create knowledge? Ind Innov 12:409–431

    Google Scholar 

  • Markusen A (1996) Sticky places in slippery space: a typology of industrial districts. Econ Geogr 72(3):293–313

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall A (1920) Principles of economics, 8th edn. Macmillan, London. Original work published 1890

  • Martin R, Sunley P (2003) Deconstructing Clusters: chaotic concept or policy Panacea? J Econ Geogr 3(1):5–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Maskell P, Kebir L (2006) What qualifies a cluster theory? In: Asheim B, Cooke P, Martin R (eds) Clusters and regional development. Critical reflections and explorations. Routledge, New York, pp 30–49

  • Maskell P, Malmberg A (1999) Localised learning and industrial competitiveness. Camb J Econ 23(2):167–185

    Google Scholar 

  • Maskell P, Eskelinen H, Hannibalsson I, Malmberg A, Vatne E (1998) Competitiveness, localised learning and regional development. Specialisation and prosperity in small open economies. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • McCann P (2008) Agglomeration economics. In: Karlsson C (ed) Handbook of research on cluster theory. Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, Cheltenham, pp 23–38

  • Morgan K (2004) The exaggerated death of geography: learning, proximity and territorial innovation systems. J Econ Geogr 4:3–21

    Google Scholar 

  • Morris P (1990) A history of the world’s semiconductor industry. Peter Peregrinus Ltd, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy KM, Shleifer A, Vishny RW (1989) Industrialization and the big push. J Polit Econ 97(5):1003–1026

    Google Scholar 

  • Neffke F, Henning M (2009) Skill-relatedness and firm diversification. Papers on Economics and Evolution 2009–06. Evolutionary Economics Group, revised, Max Planck Institute of Economics

  • Neffke F, Henning M, Boschma R (2008) Surviving in agglomerations: plant evolution and the changing benefits of the local environment. Papers in Evolutionary Economic Geography PEEG. 0820, Utrecht University, Section of Economic Geography

  • Neffke F, Henning M, Boschma R, Lundquist K-J, Olander L-O (2011) The dynamics of agglomeration externalities along the life cycle of industries. Reg Stud 45:49–65

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson R, Phelps E (1966) Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. Am Econ Revi 61:69–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Nooteboom B (2000) Learning and innovation in organizations and economies. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohlin BG (1933) Interregional and international trade. Harvard University Press, Cambridge. Revised edition published in 1967

  • Otter HS, van der Veen A, de Vriend HJ (2001) ABLOoM: Location behaviour, spatial patterns, and agent-based modelling. J Artif Soc Soc Simul 4(4). http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/4/4/2.html

  • Parr JB (2002) Agglomeration economies: ambiguities and confusions. Environ Plan A 34:717–731

    Google Scholar 

  • Perry M (2010a) Controversies in local economic development: stories, strategies, solutions. Routledge, Abingdon

    Google Scholar 

  • Perry M (2010b) Controversies in local economic development. Local Econ 25(7):527–534

    Google Scholar 

  • Polanyi M (1967) The tacit dimension. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter M (1990) The competitive advantage of nations. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter M (1998) Clusters versus industrial policy. In: Porter M (ed) On competition. Harvard Business School Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter M (2000) Location, competition and economic development: local clusters in the global economy. Econ Dev Q 14:15–31

    Google Scholar 

  • Potter A, Watts H (2011) Evolutionary agglomeration theory: increasing returns, diminishing returns, and the industry life cycle. J Econ Geogr 11(3):417–455

    Google Scholar 

  • Power D, Lundmark M (2004) Working through knowledge pools: labour market dynamics, the transference of knowledge and ideas, and industrial clusters. Urban Stud 41:1025–1044

    Google Scholar 

  • Richardson GB (1972) The organisation of industry. Econ J 82(327):883–896

  • Rodriguez-Clare A (2007) Clusters and comparative advantage: implications for industrial policy. J Dev Econ 82(1):43–57

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D (1996) Coordination failures and government policy: a model with applications to East Asia and Eastern Europe. J Int Econ 40(1–2):1–22

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer P (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Polit Econ 94:1002–1037

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer P (1990) Endogenous technological change. J Polit Econ 98(5):S71–S102

    Google Scholar 

  • Ros J (2000) Development theory and the economics of growth. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenfeld S (2005) Industry clusters: business choice, policy outcome, or branding strategy? J New Bus Ideas Trends 3(2):4–13

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal S, Strange W (2003) Geography, industrial organization, and agglomeration. Rev Econ Stat 85(2):377–393

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal S, Strange W (2004) Evidence on the nature and sources of agglomeration economies. In: Henderson JV, Thisse JF (eds) Handbook of urban and regional economics, vol 4. Elsevier Science Publishers, Amsterdam, pp 2119–2171

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruan J, Zhang X (2009) Finance and cluster-based industrial development in China. Econ Dev Cult Change 58:143–164

    Google Scholar 

  • Saxenian A (1994) Regional advantage: culture and competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Scherer F (1982) Demand-pull and technological innovation: schmookler revisited. J Ind Econ 30(3):225–238

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz H (1995) Collective efficiency: growth path for small-scale industry. J Dev Stud 31(4):529–566

    Google Scholar 

  • Scitovsky T (1954) Two concepts of external economies. J Polit Econ 62:70–82

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott AJ (2004) A perspective of economic geography. J Econ Geogr 4:479–499

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon HA (1997) An empirically based microeconomics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith T (2000) Semiconductors. Standard & Poor’s Industry Surveys, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Spencer G, Vinodrai T, Gertler M, Wolfe D (2009) Do clusters make a difference? Defining and assessing their economic performance. Reg Stud 34:1–19

    Google Scholar 

  • Stilwell F (1992) Understanding cities and regions: spatial political economy. Pluto Press, Leichardt

    Google Scholar 

  • Storper M (2009) The economics of context, location and trade: another great transformation? In: Becattini G, Bellandi M, De Propris L (eds) The handbook of industrial districts. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 141–157

  • Tödtling F, Lehner P, Kaufmann A (2009) Do different types of innovation rely on specific kinds of knowledge interactions? Technovation 29:59–71

    Google Scholar 

  • Van der Linde C (2003) The demography of clusters—findings from the cluster meta-study. In: Bröcker J, Dohse D, Soltwedel R (eds) Innovation clusters and interregional competition. Springer, Heidelberg, pp 130–149

    Google Scholar 

  • Van der Panne G (2004) Agglomeration externalities: Marshall versus Jacobs. J Evol Econ 14:593–604

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodward D, Guimaraes P (2009) Porter’s cluster strategy and industrial targeting. In: Goetz SJ, Deller S, Harris T (eds) Targeting regional economic development. Routledge, New York, pp 68–83

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

CEF.UP—Center for Economics and Finance at the University of Porto—is funded by the Fundação para a Ciência e Tecnologia (FCT), Portugal.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Argentino Pessoa.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Pessoa, A. Agglomeration and regional growth policy: externalities versus comparative advantages. Ann Reg Sci 53, 1–27 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-014-0625-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-014-0625-1

JEL Classification

Navigation