Skip to main content
Log in

Financial education as a complement to public pensions: the case of naive individuals

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies the optimal design of a pension system together with publicly provided individualized financial education. Agents can invest in both a risky and a non-risky asset and can either under- or over-estimate the expected return of the risky asset. We show that, under perfect information on the misperception biases, it is optimal for the government to impose a uniform level of pension contributions equal to the optimal level of investment in the riskless asset and a U-shaped level of mandatory education. Under asymmetric information, we show that the level of education is always distorted upward for agents with important misperception biases (who either under- or over-estimate financial returns), but can be distorted upward or downward for agents with mild misperception biases. Whether we end up in one or the other situation depends on the size of the public and private costs of education as well as on the shape of the distribution of the misperception biases in the economy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Data Availability

Data sharing is not applicable as no new data were created or analyzed in this study.

Notes

  1. Financial education is formally defined as “the process by which financial consumers/investors improve their understanding of financial products, concepts and risks and, through information, instruction and/or objective advice, develop the skills and confidence to become more aware of financial risks and opportunities, to make informed choices, to know where to go for help, and to take other effective actions to improve their financial well-being” (OECD 2005).

  2. Financial education can also be obtained through (voluntary) training on government platforms (see, for instance, in Canada, https://www.canada.ca/en/financial-consumer-agency/services/financial-literacy-programs.html).

  3. On this, see also Lusardi and Mitchell (2007); Lusardi et al. (2014) and Lusardi and Mitchell (2014).

  4. Kaiser and Menkhoff (2017) focus on different types of financial education while Kaiser and Menkhoff (2020) concentrate on financial education in schools.

  5. In this respect, our model is relevant for agents who are able to save. It does not apply to agents whose income is so low that they live hand-to-mouth.

  6. For a theory of paternalistic social welfare functions, see Bernheim and Rangel (2007, 2009).

  7. We come back on this point at the beginning of Section 4.2.

  8. This literature was initiated by Ramsey (1928); Fisher (1930); Friedman (1957) and Samuelson (1958). For a review of the literature, see Browning and Crossley (2001) and Attanasio and Weber (2010).

  9. See also Dutta et al. (2000).

  10. See also Spataro and Corsini (2017) who provide a unified framework for studying the impact of financial education on human capital acquisition and on capital market participation (i.e., through risky and riskless assets). In their case, the decision to acquire financial knowledge is a 0-1 decision and is only relevant for investing in the risky asset. Furthermore, in their paper, individuals are not myopic and the government does not intervene in the provision of financial education.

  11. We assume no income heterogeneity to concentrate on the effects of misperception biases on the agents’ investment choices and on how the government should intervene to correct for this inefficiency, putting aside any income redistribution concern.

  12. We could assume that the return of the risky asset in the bad state of nature is strictly positive. Relaxing this assumption would not qualitatively change our results.

  13. This assumption allows to rule out income effects and to obtain clear comparative statics (in particular regarding the impact of education on saving decisions derived in Section 4.2).

  14. An alternative way to model the misperception bias would be to assume that individuals have biased beliefs regarding investment returns, instead of misperceptions on the probability distribution of the returns. This approach would imply that the perceived marginal utilities of consumption in the good state of nature would be biased upwards or downwards, leading to an ambiguous overall impact of the misperception bias on investment levels in the risky asset.

  15. The misperception level \(\alpha \) could be related to the initial level of financial education of the agent.

  16. Throughout the paper, we assume that the second-order conditions of all maximization problems hold.

  17. This is equivalent to the first pillar of the pension system.

  18. At the end of this section, we discuss the case where pension contributions can be invested in the risky asset as well.

  19. For ease of notation, we drop the arguments of the functions whenever this does not lead to ambiguity.

  20. An alternative criterion would have consisted in assuming that the government is more risk averse than individuals themselves and would thus like to prevent ex post inequalities across states of nature and between individuals. We discuss in the Supplementary material how our results would change under this assumption.

  21. If public funds were costly, the optimal contribution would be equal to zero, as the same (laissez-faire) welfare level could be attained either through B or b but at a smaller cost for the society in the latter case.

  22. We have implicitly assumed here that individuals cannot borrow out of pension benefits. Assuming otherwise would only reinforce the case for mandatory financial education. Indeed, in our model, the only reason why people may borrow out of pension benefits would be to reallocate savings from the riskless to the risky asset. Hence, pessimistic agents would never borrow out of (riskless) pension benefits since they would prefer an even higher investment in the riskless asset. Only optimistic agents would borrow out of pension benefits to increase investments in the risky asset. This would undo the effect of the government’s intervention through the implementation of a pension system.

  23. To prove this, we have derived a model where the government also chooses a level \(S(\alpha )\) of mandatory contributions in the risky asset. Computations are available upon request.

  24. As Kezdi and Willis (2009) argue, it takes “effort, intelligence and motivation to acquire knowledge (..) and use it to make saving and portfolio decisions that will raise the individual’s or household’s level of expected utility.” As such, financial education is costly not only to governments but also to individuals, even in the absence of labour market opportunity costs (recall that, in our model, labor supply is fixed). Assuming \(p=0\) does not qualitatively change our conclusions both under symmetric and asymmetric information.

  25. As before, due to the quasi-linearity of preferences, individual decisions do not depend on the level of \(T(\alpha )\).

  26. It is straightforward to see that (16) evaluated at \(e=1\) is negative.

  27. The thresholds are obtained such that (16) evaluated in \(\{e=0,\alpha =\alpha _1\}\) or in \(\{e=0,\alpha =\alpha _2\}\) is equal to zero.

  28. When preferences are not CARA, we cannot obtain unambiguous results. Indeed, with CARA preferences, the bias \(\alpha \) affects investments in the risky and riskless assets only directly through \(\phi (\alpha ,e)\), but not indirectly through its impact on marginal utilities of consumption, \(u'(.)\).

  29. We show in the Supplementary material that the assumption that \(db/d\alpha \) and \(\partial b/\partial \alpha \) have the same sign is equivalent to assuming that even with education, \(\phi (\alpha ,e(\alpha ))\) increases in \(\alpha \). The same is true for the assumption that \(ds/d\alpha \) and \(\partial s/\partial \alpha \) have the same sign.

  30. Since the revelation principle applies in this context, we focus on a direct mechanism.

  31. The cumulative density function \(F_\rho (\hat{\rho })=P(\rho \le \hat{\rho })=P(\alpha \pi \le \hat{\rho })=F(\rho /\pi )\). Differentiating this expression, we obtain that the density function of \(\rho \) is equal to \(f(\rho /\pi )/\pi \).

  32. As we showed in the previous section, under full information, it is indeed optimal to set the same (first-best) level of mandatory contributions. To keep the model tractable and the results comparable with the ones from the previous sections, we limit the analysis to uniform benefits also in this section, even if they may be suboptimal under asymmetric information.

  33. Under Assumption 1, the solution to the individual’s problem in the absence of pension contributions is always interior.

  34. This is equivalent to a monotonicity constraint, which can replace second-order local incentive constraints. See the Supplementary material for further discussion.

  35. Note that \(b^{FB}=b^{LF}(1)<b(\phi (\rho /\pi ,e),0,e)\) since \(\phi (\rho /\pi ,e)<1\) for pessimistic agents.

  36. In Fig. 3, we implicitly assume that the distribution of \(e(\rho )\) is symmetric, which is not necessarily the case. A similar reasoning applies to the non-symmetric case.

References

  • Arrondel L, Debbich M, Savignac F (2015) Stockholding in France: the role of financial literacy and information. Appl Econ Lett 22(16):1315–1319

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attanasio OP, Weber G (2010) Consumption and saving: models of intertemporal allocation and their implications for public policy. J Econ Lit 48(3):693–751

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim BD, Rangel A (2007) Toward choice-theoretic foundations for behavioral welfare economics. Am Econ Rev 97:464–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim BD, Rangel A (2009) Beyond revealed preference: choice-theoretic foundations for behavioral welfare economics. Q J Econ 124:51–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Crossley TF (2001) The life-cycle model of consumption and saving. J Econ Perspect 15(3):3–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsini L, Spataro L (2014) Optimal decisions on pension plans in the presence of information costs and financial literacy. J Public Econ Theory 17(3):383–414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cremer H, De Donder P, Maldonado D, Pestieau P (2007) Voting over type and generosity of a pension system when some individuals are myopic. J Public Econ 91:2041–2061

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cremer H, De Donder P, Maldonado D, Pestieau P (2008) Designing an optimal linear pension scheme with forced savings and wage heterogeneity. Int Tax Public Finan 15:547–562

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cremer H, De Donder P, Maldonado D, Pestieau P (2009) Non linear pension schemes with myopia. South Econ J 76:86–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond P, Koszegi B (2003) Quasi-hyperbolic discounting and retirement. J Public Econ 87:1839–1872

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutta J, Kapur S, Orszag J (2000) A portfolio approach to the optimal funding of pensions. Econ Lett 69:201–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1930) The theory of interest. MacMillan, New York

  • Friedman M (1957) A theory of the consumption function. Princeton University Press for NBER, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hudomiet P, Kezdi G, Willis R (2011) Stock market crash and expectations of American households. J Appl Econom 26:393–415

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hurd MD, Rohwedder S (2011) Stock price expectations and stock trading, Rand W-P 938

  • Japelli T, Padula M (2013) Investment in financial literacy and saving decisions. J Bank Financ 37:2779–2792

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Japelli T, Padula M (2015) Investment in financial literacy, social security, and portfolio choice. J Pension Econ Finan 14(4):369–411

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaiser T, Menkhoff L (2017) Does financial education impact financial literacy and financial behavior, and if so, when? World Bank Econ Rev 31(3):611–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaiser T, Menkhoff L (2020) Financial education in schools: a meta-analysis of experimental studies. Econ Educ Rev 78:101930

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kezdi G, Willis R (2009) Stock market expectations and portfolio choice of American households. Working paper

  • Lalime T, Michaud P-C (2014) Litteratie financière et préparation à la retraite au Québec et dans le reste du Canada. L’Actualité économique 90(1):23–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusardi A, Mitchell O (2011) Financial literacy and retirement planning in the United States. J Pension Econ Financ 10(4):509–525

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusardi A, Mitchell O (2014) The economic importance of financial literacy: theory and evidence. J Econ Lit 52(1):5–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusardi A, Mitchell O, Curto V (2010) Financial literacy among the young. J Consum Aff 44(2):358–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusardi A, Mitchell O, Curto V (2014) Financial literacy and financial sophistication in the older population. J Pension Econ Financ 13(4):347–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusardi A, Michaud P-C, Mitchell O (2017) Optimal financial knowledge and wealth inequality. J Pol Econ 125(2):431–477

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusardi A, Mitchell O (2007) Financial literacy and retirement preparedness: evidence and implications for financial education. Business economics

  • Malmendier U, Nagel S (2011) Depression babies: do macroeconomic experiences affect risk taking? Q J Econ 126(1):373–416

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsen E, Thogersen O (2004) Designing social security - a portfolio choice approach. Eur Econ Rev 48:883–904

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2005) Improving financial literacy analysis of issues and policies. OECD Publishing

  • OECD (2019) Smarter financial education: key lessons from behavioural insights for financial literacy initiatives. OECD Publishing

  • Ramsey F (1928) A mathematical theory of saving. Econ J 38:543–559

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson PA (1958) An Exact Consumption-Loan Model of Interest with or without the Social Contrivance of Money. Journal of Political Economy, LXVI, 467–482

  • Schwartz S (2010) Can financial education improve financial literacy and retirement planning. IRPP Study, 12

  • Spataro L, Corsini L (2017) Endogenous financial literacy, saving and stock market participation. FinanzArchiv 73(2):135–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Rooij MC, Lusardi A, Alessie RJ (2011) Financial literacy and stock market participation. J Financ Econ 101:449–472

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Rooj M, Lusardi A, Alessie R (2012) Financial literacy, retirement planning and household wealth. Econ J 122:449–478

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank two anonymous referees and the Editor in charge, Grégory Ponthière, for their valuable comments. We further acknowledge valuable insights from participants at the L.-A. Gérard Varet Conference in Marseille (2022).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marie-Louise Leroux.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Gregory Ponthiere.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file 1 (pdf 234 KB)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Canta, C., Leroux, ML. Financial education as a complement to public pensions: the case of naive individuals. J Popul Econ 37, 69 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-024-01046-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-024-01046-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation