Abstract
An extensive literature documents the effects of birth order on various individual outcomes, with later-born children faring worse than their siblings. However, the potential mechanisms behind these effects remain poorly understood. This paper leverages US data on pregnancy intention to study the role of unwanted fertility in the observed birth order patterns. We document that children higher in the birth order are much more likely to be unwanted, in the sense that they were conceived at a time when the family was not planning to have additional children. Being an unwanted child is associated with negative life cycle outcomes as it implies a disruption in parental plans for optimal human capital investment. We show that the increasing prevalence of unwantedness across birth order explains a substantial part of the documented birth order effects in education and employment. Consistent with this mechanism, we document no birth order effects in families who have more control over their own fertility.
This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution.
Notes
- 1.
We follow the demographic definition of an unwanted birth as a birth in excess of total desired fertility. The broader notion of unintended birth includes both unwanted and mistimed births. Given our purposes, we do not consider mistimed births.
- 2.
- 3.
See Kessler (1991) for additional early references.
- 4.
- 5.
The indicator is not defined for those who reported being out of labor force for the entire year.
- 6.
Children who result from mistimed pregnancies, particularly when these occur before marriage, may also have negative effects on outcomes later in life. See, for example, (Nguyen 2018)
- 7.
Joyce et al. (2002) find that prospective and retrospective reports of pregnancy intention provide the same estimate of the effects of being an unintended child on various prenatal outcomes once they control for selective pregnancy recognition using an IV procedure. Further, they show that the extent of unwanted fertility was the same regardless of whether the assessment was during pregnancy or after birth. They show this for a subsample of women for whom pregnancy intention was assessed both prospectively (during pregnancy) and retrospectively (after birth).
- 8.
In principle, since we are looking at families with two and three children, the number of first-born and second-born children should be the same. In practice however, our number of second-born children is slightly smaller than the number of first-borns because they are more likely to have missing information on our outcome of interest, completed education.
- 9.
However, it is of interest to explore whether the pattern of increasing prevalence of unwanted children across birth order holds in 4-child families. Since we only know whether the first, last, or second to last child in a family was unwanted, we cannot tell whether a second-born child in a four-child family was unwanted. But we can still look at first-, third-, and fourth-born children in those families. Consistent with the patterns in Table 2, we find that in four-child families, the incidence of unwanted children grows from 16% among first-borns, to 27% among third-borns to a whopping 53% among fourth-borns.
- 10.
These are families for which we identify at least one unwanted child or families for which information for pregnancy status is missing for at least one child.
- 11.
We follow the religion taxonomy in Evans (2002) and classify the following religions as having a more strict attitude against abortion: Roman Catholic, Protestant, other Protestant, other Non-Christian, Latter Day Saints, Mormon, Jehovah’s Witnesses, Greek/Russian/Eastern Orthodox, Lutheran, Christian, Christian Science, Seventh Day Adventist, Pentecostal, Jewish, Amish, and Mennonite. Mothers reporting these religions are more likely to be pro-life and less likely to use abortion to terminate unwanted pregnancies. We then classify Baptists, Episcopalians, Methodists, Presbyterians, and Unitarians along with Agnostics and Atheists as having a less strict attitude towards abortion.
- 12.
In the pooled specification, the effects for the third child are statistically significantly different from each other across the two tables.
References
Ananat EO, Hungerman DM (2012) The power of the pill for the next generation: oral contraception’s effects on fertility, abortion, and maternal and child characteristics. Rev Econ Stat 94(1):37–51
Argys LM, Rees DI, Averett SL, Witoonchart BK (2006) Birth order and risky adolescent behavior. Econ Enquiry 44(2):215–233
Averett SL, Argys LM, Rees DI (2011) Older siblings and adolescent risky behavior: does parenting play a role? J Popul Econ 24(3):957–978
Bagger J, Birchenall JA, Mansour H, Urzua S (2013) Education, birth order, and family size. Working Paper 19111, National Bureau of Economic Research
Bailey MJ (2010) “Momma’s got the pill”: How Anthony Comstock and Griswold v. Connecticut shaped US childbearing. Amer Econ Rev 100(1):98–129
Barmby T, Cigno A (1990) A sequential probability model of fertility patterns. J Popul Econ 3(1):31–51
Baydar N (1995) Consequences for children of their birth planning status. Fam Plan Perspect 27(6):228–245
Becker GS, Lewis HG (1973) On the interaction between the quantity and quality of children. J Polit Econ 81(2, Part 2):S279–S288
Behrman JR, Pollak RA, Taubman P (1982) Parental preferences and provision for progeny. J Polit Econ 90(1):52–73
Behrman JR, Taubman P (1986) Birth order, schooling, and earnings. J Labor Econ 4(3, Part 2):S121–S145
Behrman JR (1988) Nutrition, health, birth order and seasonality: Intrahousehold allocation among children in rural india. J Dev Econ 28(1):43–62
Belmont L, Marolla FA (1973) Birth order, family size, and intelligence. Science 182(4117):1096–1101
Birdsall N (1979) Siblings and schooling in urban colombia. Ph.D. thesis, Yale University
Birdsall N (1990) Birth order effects and time allocation. Res Popul Econ 7:191–213
Björkegren E, Svaleryd H (2017) Birth order and child health. Working paper, Institute for Evaluation of Labour Market and Education Policy
Black SE, Devereux PJ, Salvanes KG (2005) The more the merrier? The effect of family size and birth order on children’s education. Q J Econ 120(2):669–700
Black SE, Devereux PJ, Salvanes KG (2011) Older and wiser? birth order and iq of young men. CESifo Econ Stud 57(1):103–120
Black SE, Devereux PJ, Salvanes KG (2016) Healthy (?), wealthy, and wise: Birth order and adult health. Econ Human Biol 23:27–45
Black SE, Grönqvist E, Öckert B (2017) Born to lead? the effect of birth order on non-cognitive abilities. Working Paper 23393, National Bureau of Economic Research
Booth AL, Kee HJ (2009) Birth order matters: the effect of family size and birth order on educational attainment. J Popul Econ 22(2):367–397
Breining S, Doyle J, Figlio D, Karbownik K, Roth J (2017) Birth order and delinquency: Evidence from Denmark and Florida. Working Paper 23394, National Bureau of Economic Research
Brenøe AA, Molitor R (2018) Birth order and health of newborns. J Popul Econ 31(2):397–395
Charles KK, Stephens Jr M (2006) Abortion legalization and adolescent substance use. J Law Econ 49(2):481–505
Child Trends (2013) Unintended births
Conley D, Glauber R (2006) Parental educational investment and children’s academic risk: Estimates of the impact of sibship size and birth order from exogenous variation in fertility. J Hum Resour 41(4):722–737
De Haan M (2010) Birth order, family size and educational attainment. Econ Educ Rev 29(4):576–588
De Haan M, Plug E, Rosero J (2014) Birth order and human capital development evidence from ecuador. J Hum Resour 49(2):359–392
Do Q-T, Phung TD (2010) The importance of being wanted. Amer Econ J: Appl Econ 2(4):236–253
Donohue JJ, Grogger J, Levitt SD (2009) The impact of legalized abortion on teen childbearing. Amer Law Econ Rev 11(1):24–46
Donohue JJ, Levitt SD (2001) The impact of legalized abortion on crime. Q J Econ 116(2):379–420
Eckstein D, Aycock KJ, Sperber MA, McDonald J, Van Wiesner V, Watts III RE, Ginsburg P (2010) A review of 200 birth-order studies: Lifestyle characteristics. J Individ Psychol 66(4):408–434
Edmonds EV (2006) Understanding sibling differences in child labor. J Popul Econ 19(4):795–821
Ejrnæs M, Pörtner CC (2004) Birth order and the intrahousehold allocation of time and education. Rev Econ Stat 86(4):1008–1019
Ermisch JF, Francesconi M (2001) Family structure and children’s achievements. J Popul Econ 14(2):249–270
Evans JH (2002) Polarization in abortion attitudes in u.s. religious traditions, 1972–1998. Sociol Forum 17(3):397–422
Galton F (1875) English men of science: Their nature and nurture. D. Appleton
Gruber J, Levine P, Staiger D (1999) Abortion legalization and child living circumstances: who is the ”marginal child”? Q J Econ 114(1):263–291
Hao L, Hotz VJ, Jin GZ (2008) Games parents and adolescents play: Risky behaviour, parental reputation and strategic transfers. Econ J 118(528):515–555
Horton S (1988) Birth order and child nutritional status: evidence from the philippines. Econ Dev Cult Chang 36(2):341–354
Hotz VJ, Pantano J (2015) Strategic parenting, birth order and school performance. J Popul Econ 28(4):911–936
Joyce TJ, Kaestner R, Korenman S (2000) The effect of pregnancy intention on child development. Demography 37(1):83–94
Joyce TJ, Kaestner R, Korenman S (2002) On the validity of retrospective assessments of pregnancy intention. Demography 39(1):199–213
Kantarevic J, Mechoulan S (2006) Birth order, educational attainment, and earnings an investigation using the PSID. J Hum Resour 41(4):755–777
Kessler D (1991) Birth order, family size, and achievement: Family structure and wage determination. J Labor Econ 9(4):413–426
Kubička L, Matějček Z, David H, Dytrych Z, Miller W, Roth Z (1995) Children from unwanted pregnancies in prague, Czech Republic revisited at age thirty. Acta Psychiatr Scand 91(6):361–369
Lehmann J-YK, Nuevo-Chiquero A, Vidal-Fernandez M (2013) Birth order and differences in early inputs and outcomes. Discussion Paper 6755, IZA Institute of Labor Economics
Lin W, Pantano J (2015) The unwanted: Negative outcomes over the life cycle. J Popul Econ 28(2):479–508
Lin W, Pantano J, Pinto R, Sun S (2017) Identification of quantity quality tradeoff with imperfect fertility control. Unpublished working paper
Lindert PH (1977) Sibling position and achievement. J Hum Resour 12 (2):198–219
Mechoulan S, Wolff F-C (2015) Intra-household allocation of family resources and birth order: evidence from France using siblings data. J Popul Econ 28(4):937–964
Michael RT, Willis RJ (1976) Contraception and fertility: Household production under uncertainty. In: Household Production and Consumption. NBER, pp 25–98
Miller AR (2009) Motherhood delay and the human capital of the next generation. Am Econ Rev 99(2):154–58
Myhrman A, Olsen P, Rantakallio P, Laara E (1995) Does the wantedness of a pregnancy predict a child’s educational attainment? Fam Plan Perspect 27 (3):116–119
Nguyen CV (2018) The long-term effects of mistimed pregnancy on children’s education and employment. J Popul Econ 31(3):937–968
Ozbeklik S (2014) The effect of abortion legalization on childbearing by unwed teenagers in future cohorts. Econ Inq 52(1):100–115
Pavan R (2016) On the production of skills and the birth order effect. J Hum Resour 51(3):699–726
Pop-Eleches C (2006) The impact of an abortion ban on socioeconomic outcomes of children: Evidence from romania. J Polit Econ 114(4):744–773
Price J (2008) Parent-child quality time: Does birth order matter? J Hum Resour 43(1):240–265
Rosenzweig MR, Wolpin KI (1993) Maternal expectations and ex post rationalizations: the usefulness of survey information on the wantedness of children. J Hum Resour 23(2):205–229
Schoen R, Astone NM, Kim YJ, Nathanson CA, Fields JM (1999) Do fertility intentions affect fertility behavior? J Marriage Fam 61(3):790–799
Sulloway FJ (2010) Why siblings are like darwin’s finches: Birth order, sibling competition, and adaptive divergence within the family. In: The Evolution of Personality and Individual Differences. Oxford University Press, New York
Westoff CF, Ryder NB (1977) The predictive validity of reproductive intentions. Demography 14(4):431–453
Willis RJ (1973) A new approach to the economic theory of fertility behavior. J Polit Econ 81(2, Part 2):S14–S64
Acknowledgments
We thank Janet Currie, Joe Doyle, Martha Bailey and seminar participants at the University of Michigan for helpful comments. Lin acknowledges research support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No.71573004) and the Key Laboratory of Mathematical Economics and Quantitative Finance (Peking University), Ministry of Education. During work on this project, Sun was supported in part by the George Katona Economic Behavior Research Award funded by the Institute for Social Research at the University of Michigan. All errors remain our own. The authors would like to thank the anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestions.
Funding
Wanchuan Lin acknowledges research support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No.71573004) and the Key Laboratory of Mathematical Economics and Quantitative Finance (Peking University), Ministry of Education. Shuqiao Sun was supported by the George Katona Economic Behavior Research Award, funded by the Institute for Social Research at the University of Michigan.
Author information
Affiliations
Corresponding author
Ethics declarations
Conflict of interest
The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.
Additional information
Publisher’s note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Responsible editor: Alessandro Cigno
Appendix
Appendix
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Lin, W., Pantano, J. & Sun, S. Birth order and unwanted fertility. J Popul Econ 33, 413–440 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-019-00747-4
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
Keywords
- Birth order
- Unwanted births
- Fertility intentions
JEL Classification
- J13
- J22
- J24