Skip to main content
Log in

Same-occupation spouses: preferences or search costs?

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Married individuals match with spouses who share their occupation more frequently than should happen by chance if marriage markets are large frictionless search markets covering a particular geographic area. This suggests that either there is a preference for same-occupation matches or that search costs are lower within occupation. This paper uses 2008–2015 data from the American Community Survey to analyze same-occupation matching among a sample of recently married couples. Our empirical strategy compares the difference in wages between same-occupation husbands and different-occupation husbands across occupations with different percent male workers. Under a preference explanation, this difference should become less negative as the share of males in the occupation increases. Under a search cost explanation, this difference should become more negative as the share of males increases. Our results are consistent with the search cost explanation. Furthermore, using an occupation-specific index of workplace communication, we demonstrate that the results are most consistent with the search cost mechanism for occupations with a greater degree of workplace communication. Finally, we show that matching on field of degree for couples in which both spouses have a college degree is also consistent with the search cost explanation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Bruze (2011) shows that movie actors, whose job does not require a specific level of education, are more likely to marry spouses with their same level of education. He concludes that preferences play a significant role in explaining educational assortative matching.

  2. Details on the procedure of calculating random matching by occupation, following the procedure from Fryer (2007), are in the Appendix.

  3. An additional explanation for within-occupation matching is that married individuals might recruit their partners into their own occupations after matching. For example, in Table 1, it might be that the very few women who report being fishers, hunters, or trappers are in that category because their husbands brought them into the occupation, generating a very large within-occupation matched rate for women in that occupation (0.60). This explanation is less likely to be relevant for married individuals with college degrees, because entrance into an occupation often requires investment in specialized education and training.

  4. This raises the question of how, in this two-sided matching model, the non-smoking women are able to attract higher-quality smoking husbands. It is not because the smoking men value non-smoking wives (Chiappori et al. assume that smokers, unlike non-smokers, are indifferent to smoking status). Rather, the smoking men face a shortage of smoking wives, and it is this gender imbalance that drives some smoking men to match with non-smoking wives.

  5. Banerjee et al. (2013) analyze an Indian marriage market in which individuals care about caste and other attributes. While matching by caste may seem very applicable to matching by occupation, there is a crucial difference; there is sex balance across castes, but sex imbalance across occupations. A key finding of Banerjee et al. (2013) is that, under the assumption of sex balance, sorting on other attributes does not change much in the presence of preferences for same-caste matching. Chiappori et al. (forthcoming) have a similar prediction for the case in which men and women smoke at the same rate. The prediction we are using from Chiappori et al. is driven by the sex imbalance across groups.

  6. There is a substantial literature on models of marriage markets with search costs. Unlike the perfect assortative matching predicted in frictionless markets, in the presence of search costs, markets will develop a class structure in which individuals match with one of a range of acceptable partners rather than their ideal partner (Burdett and Coles 1997; Bloch and Ryder 2000; Smith 2006; Jacquet and Tan 2007). These models, however, do not allow search costs to vary across different types of potential partners or across different marriage markets.

  7. It may seem more realistic to have a model in which individuals allocate some effort to within-occupation search and some effort to outside-occupation search. But in this simple search framework, one search pool will always dominate the other in the marginal return to additional search, so it would never be optimal for an individual to allocate effort to both pools. A potential model extension would be to allow search costs to increase as an individual searches in a given pool, perhaps if the search pool has a limited number of options, so that at some point it becomes optimal for an individual to switch to the other search pool.

  8. A similar empirical prediction is generated by the two-sided search market with frictions in Moen (1997). In his model, submarkets vary by wage and search costs (workers per vacancy). Submarkets with higher wages attract more workers per vacancy and therefore have greater search costs. A comparison of identical workers who matched in different submarkets will find that the worker who matched in the market with greater search costs is receiving a higher wage.

  9. This may at first seem counter-intuitive because we expect lower search costs to generate matches with higher-quality husbands. But in the analysis, we are not comparing women across occupations facing different search costs. If we were, then we would predict that women in occupations with lower search costs should on average match with higher-quality husbands. Instead, we are comparing women in the same occupation, facing the same within-occupation search costs, who match either with same-occupation husbands or with different-occupation husbands.

  10. Our results are very similar if we instead just use the midpoint of the reported hour interval when calculating the hourly wage, specifically, if we use hour values of 7, 20, 33, 43.5, 48.5, and 51, respectively, for the reported intervals 1–13, 14–26, 27–39, 40–47, 48–49, and 50–52.

  11. Stevenson and Wolfers (2011), in calculations with SIPP data, find that 91% of women married in the late 1990s were married at their 5th anniversary and 77% were married at their 10th anniversary. Kreider and Ellis (2011) report similar marriage survival statistics. Our findings are similar if we restrict the sample to couples who have been married for 2 years or less. Van Kammen and Adams (2014) show that spouses with similar occupational characteristics are more likely to divorce.

  12. Because the eliminated occupations are small, results using the full sample in which the small occupations are retained are quite similar to those in which they are eliminated. Because there may be a concern that the military operates as a somewhat distinct marriage market, we also confirmed that results are robust to excluding couples in which either or both of the husband and wife work in the military.

  13. Other papers have used both husband’s education and wife’s education as measures of quality. We do not use this approach here, because it is important to control for education on the right-hand side of the equation in order to avoid bias due to unobserved heterogeneity in wife’s quality.

  14. The results for husband’s wage are robust to including non-working wives in the sample. We cannot estimate results for the wage ratio if the sample includes non-working wives.

  15. It is likely that, even in the absence of preferences for same-occupation spouses, individuals prefer spouses from high-wage occupations. A certain amount of same-occupation matching will occur just from individuals in high-wage occupations assortatively matching with spouses in high-wage occupations. But this form of sorting will be picked up by the occupation fixed effects. If both female doctors and female lawyers agree that male doctors are the most desirable spouses, there is no reason for female doctors to disproportionately sacrifice to marry a male doctor. The focus of our analysis is whether the male doctor is disproportionately attractive to female doctors compared to women from other occupations.

  16. Because the interaction term is zero unless husband and wife share the same occupation, it is equivalent to the interaction of Same_Occ with the percent male in husband’s occupation.

  17. It could be the case the individuals who select into low-communication workplaces are particularly adverse to social interaction and therefore consider search outside the workplace disproportionately difficult. If that were so, then individuals in low-communication workplaces should be even more willing to accept a low-quality match within occupation rather than engage in wider search. This would work against our finding a negative estimate for the coefficient on Same_Occ*%Male*Comm.

  18. As was the case with the occupation-level characteristics in Eqs. (1)–(3), field of degree characteristics are calculated on the larger sample of men and women ages 25–45 who report a field of degree in the 2008–2015 ACS, unconditional on marital status.

  19. We do not report the coefficient estimate for the main effect of the same-occupation variable, because this coefficient is only interpretable in combination with the coefficients on the interaction of the same-occupation variable with the four occupation-level wage characteristics.

  20. Specifically, the coefficient (standard error) on Same_Occ*%Male is 0.185 (1.50) using wife’s wage and 0.038 (0.043) using logged wife’s wage.

  21. Percent male in wife’s occupations included in the sample ranges from a maximum of 93.5% to a minimum of 2.0%.

References

  • Abramitzky R, Delavande A, Vasconcelos L (2011) Marrying up: the role of sex ratio in assortative matching. Am Econ J: Appl Econ 3(3):124–156

    Google Scholar 

  • Angrist J (2002) How do sex ratios affect marriage and labor markets? Evidence from America’s second generation. Q J Econ 117(3):997–1038

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee A, Duflo E, Ghatak M, Lafortune J (2013) Marry for what? Caste and mate selection in modern India. Am Econ J: Microecon 5(2):33–72

    Google Scholar 

  • Belot M, Francesconi M (2013) Dating preferences and meeting opportunities in mate choice decisions. J Hum Resour 48(2):474–508

    Google Scholar 

  • Blau F, Brummund P, Liu AY-H (2013) Trends in occupational segregation by gender 1970-2009: adjusting for the impact of changes in the occupational coding system. Demography 50(2):471–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloch F, Ryder H (2000) Two-sided search, marriage and matchmakers. Int Econ Rev 41(1):93–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blossfeld H-P (2009) Educational assortative marriage in comparative perspective. Annu Rev Sociol 35:513–530

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blossfeld H-P, Timm A (eds) (2003) Who marries whom? Educational systems as marriage markets in modern societies. Kluwer Acad, Dordrecht

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruze G (2011) Marriage choices of movie stars: does spouse’s education matter? J Hum Cap 5(1):1–28

  • Burdett K, Coles M (1997) Marriage and class. Q J Econ 112(1):141–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charles K, Luoh M (2010) Male incarceration, the marriage market, and female outcomes. Rev Econ Stat 92(3):614–627

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori P-A, Fortin B, Lacroix G (2002) Marriage markets, divorce, legislation and household labor supply. J Polit Econ 110(1):37–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori P-A, Oreffice S, Quintana-Domeque C (2012) Fatter attraction: anthropometric and socioeconomic characteristics in the marriage market. J Polit Econ 120(4):659–695

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori P-A, Oreffice S, Quintana-Domeque C Forthcoming. Bidimensional matching with heterogenous preferences: education and smoking in the marriage market. J Eur Econ Assoc

  • Choo E, Siow A (2006) Who marries whom and why. J Polit Econ 114(1):175–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • England P, Allison P, Yuxiao W (2007) Does bad pay cause occupations to feminize, does feminization reduce pay, and how can we tell from longitudinal data? Soc Sci Res 36(3):1237–1256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisman R, Iyengar S, Kamenica E, Simonson I (2006) Gender differences in mate selection: evidence from a speed dating experiment. Q J Econ 121(2):673–697

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fryer RG Jr (2007) Guess who’s been coming to dinner? Trends in interracial marriage over the 20th century. J Econ Perspect 21(2):71–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furtado D, Theodoropolous N (2011) Interethnic marriage: a choice between ethnic and educational similarities. J Popul Econ 24:1257–1279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hitsch G, Hortascsu A, Ariely D (2010) Matching and sorting in online dating. Am Econ Rev 100(1):130–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hout M (1982) The association between husbands’ and wives’ occupations in two-earner families. Am J Sociol 87:397–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacquet N, Tan S (2007) On the segmentation of markets. J Polit Econ 115(4):639–664

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalmijn M (1994) Assortative mating by cultural and economic occupational status. Am J Sociol 100:422–452

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalmijn M (1998) Intermarriage and homogamy: causes, patterns, trends. Am Rev Sociol 24:395–421

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufman K, Messner M, Solis A (2013) Returns to elite higher education in the marriage market: evidence from Chile. Working Paper. Available at: http://kaufmann.vwl.uni-mannheim.de/fileadmin/user_upload/kaufmann/Paper_Chile_MarriageMarket-SSRN.pdf

  • Kreider RM, Ellis R (2011) Number, timing, and duration of marriages and divorces: 2009. Current Population Reports, P70–125, U.S. Census Bureau, Washington, DC

  • Lafortune J (2013) Making yourself attractive: pre-marital investments and returns to education in the marriage market. Am Econ J: Appl Econ 5(2):151–178

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee S Forthcoming. Effect of online dating on marital sorting. J Appl Econ

  • Levanon A, England P, Allison P (2009) Occupational feminization and pay: assessing causal dynamics using 1950-2000 census data. Soc Forces 88(2):865–981

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansour H, McKinnish T (2014) Who marries differently-aged spouses? Ability, education, occupation, earnings and appearance. Rev Econ Stat 96(3):577–580

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKinnish T (2007) Sexually-integrated workplaces and divorce: another form of on- the-job search. J Hum Resour 42(2):331–352

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moen E (1997) Competitive search equilibrium. J Polit Econ 105(2):385–411

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nielsen H, Svarer M (2009) Educational homogamy: how much is opportunity? J Hum Resour 44(4):1066–1086

    Google Scholar 

  • Oreffice S, Quintana-Domeque C (2010) Anthropometry and socioeconomics in ‘ the couple: evidence in the United States. Econ Hum Biol 8(3):373–384

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pestel N (2016) Searching on the campus? Marriage market effects of the student gender composition by field of study. Working Paper. Available at: https://ideas.repec.org/p/zbw/vfsc16/145510.html

  • Smith L (2006) The marriage model with search frictions. J Polit Econ 114(6):1124–1144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smits J, Ultee W, Lammers J (1999) Occupational homogamy in eight countries of the European Union. Acta Sociol 42(1):55–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson B, Wolfers J (2011) Trends in marital stability. Research Handbook in the Law and Economics of the Family, Edward Elgar Press

  • Svarer M (2007) Working late: do workplace sex ratios affect partnership formation and dissolution? J Hum Resour 42(3):583–595

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Kammen B, Adams SJ (2014) Dissimilar occupations and marital stability. IZA J Labor Econ 3(9)

  • Weitzman M (1979) Optimal search for the best alternative. Econometrica 47(3):641–654

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wong L (2003) Why do only 5.5% of black men marry white women? Int Econ Rev 44(3):803–826

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We gratefully acknowledge helpful comments from Chris Bollinger, Murat Iyigun, and Rick Mansfield and two anonymous referees as well as seminar participants at the University of Kentucky, Osaka University, University of Melbourne, University of Sydney, University of New South Wales, UC-Santa Barbara, Deakin University, SEA annual meetings, SOLE/EALE World Congress, and the IZA/SOLE transatlantic meetings.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Terra McKinnish.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Alessandro Cigno

Appendix: Random matching

Appendix: Random matching

In Table 2, we report the probability a married man (woman) in occupation k is married to a woman (man) who also works in occupation k under random matching by occupation (conditional on non-random matching by education).

We calculate these random matching probabilities adapting Fryer (2007)’s approach for random matching by race.

There are seven steps to the calculation:

  1. Step 1:

    Restrict the sample to married mixed-sex couples. Divide married men and women into two education categories based on college degree completion. Calculate for men (women) in each education category the proportion whose spouse is in each education category (e.g., the proportion of male college graduates married to female college graduates)

  2. Step 2:

    For men (women) in each education category, calculate the number in each occupation category.

  3. Step 3:

    Multiply the numbers from step 2 (e.g., the number of male college graduates in occupation 1) by the proportions from step 1 (e.g. ,the proportion of male college graduates married to female college graduates) to calculate the expected number of pairings between men (women) in each education/occupation group and women (men) in each education group (e.g., the expected number of pairings between male college graduates in occupation 1 and female college graduates).

  4. Step 4:

    Using the numbers from step 2, calculate for men (women) in each education category the share in each occupation category.

  5. Step 5:

    Multiply the expected number of pairings from step 3 by the shares from step 4 to calculate expected pairings by education/occupation group (e.g., multiply the expected number of pairings between male college graduates in occupation 1 and female college graduates times the share of female college graduates in occupation 1. This produces the expected number of pairings between male college graduates in occupation 1 and female college graduates in occupation 1).

  6. Step 6:

    Find the total expected number of same-occupation pairings in each occupation group by summing over the relevant pairings in step 5 (e.g., for men in occupation 1, calculate the total number of expected pairings with women in occupation 1).

  7. Step 7:

    Convert the expected number of same-occupation pairings to probabilities by dividing by the number of men (women) in the occupation from step 2.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mansour, H., McKinnish, T. Same-occupation spouses: preferences or search costs?. J Popul Econ 31, 1005–1033 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-017-0670-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-017-0670-z

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation