Skip to main content
Log in

Population age structure and consumption growth: evidence from National Transfer Accounts

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We assess the effects of the population age structure and the population dynamics on economic growth. Following recent research, we focus on the generational turnover effect to characterize the influence of birth and death rates, depending on the age profile of individual consumption, the extent of annuity market imperfections, and the willingness of households to shift consumption over time. Using data from the National Transfer Accounts on age profiles of consumption for a number of different countries, we assess—in a comparative way—the sign and the magnitude of the generational turnover effect and its impact on economic growth. We find considerable cross-country differences and trace them back to the underlying variation in demography and in the age structure of consumption.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In an early contribution on the role of population change for economic growth, Kuznets (1960) is observing this but not pursuing the point analytically.

  2. There is a slight tension between this finding and the overwhelming micro evidence of hump-shaped age profiles of consumption (as surveyed, e.g., in Fernandez-Villaverde and Krueger 2007; Attanasio and Weber 2010). Middle-aged individuals typically experience peak earnings over their life cycle. Thus, they can afford higher consumption levels, while they are, at the same time, saving to an extent that their propensity to save is highest over the life cycle.

  3. Annuities guarantee individuals a fixed income stream over their remaining life cycle and, thereby, insure the individual against longevity risks. If priced in an actuarially fair way, the return to annuities adjusts to the remaining life expectancy. Private annuity markets are typically rather thin, but public pension entitlements constitute an important form of mandatory annuitization (Hosseini 2015).

  4. To the best of our knowledge, Heijdra and Ligthart (2000) were the first to employ the term “generational turnover effect,” which has been adopted as a convenient terminology in many subsequent works involving continuous-time OLG models. Recently, Mierau and Turnovsky (2014a, 2014b) have provided a detailed analysis of the generational turnover effect and its role for balanced growth economies.

  5. A similar mechanism is at work within R&D-based endogenous growth models with an overlapping generations structure such as Prettner (2013), Banz et al. (2014), Kuhn and Prettner (2016), and Prettner and Trimborn (2016). In a related contribution, Schneider and Winkler (2016) endogenize the rate of mortality in an overlapping generations AK type of growth model and analyze the growth and welfare implications of individual health investments in the presence of moral hazard when annuities condition on average mortality.

  6. Contributions by d’Albis (2007), d’Albis and Augeraud-Véron (2009), Lau (2009), Sánchez-Romero (2013), and Sánchez-Romero et al. (2013) focus on the impact of a realistic demographic structure on capital accumulation.

  7. Recently, data from the National Transfer Accounts have also been used for the calibration of overlapping generations models in Sánchez-Romero et al. (2013), Mason et al. (2016), and Sánchez-Romero et al. (2016).

  8. While per se our analysis does not rely on general equilibrium relationships, the underlying life-cycle problem assumes the absence of liquidity constraints and income shocks.

  9. It can be shown analytically that in a model in which individuals are not credit constrained, the life-cycle distribution of accidental bequests is unrelated to the life-cycle pattern of consumption. The present value of accidental bequests only determines the level of consumption of the newborn cohort.

  10. Note that for \(c^{\dag }\left (t\right )/c(t,t) \geq \beta /\bar {\mu }\) the impact is always negative, regardless of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution and the (im-)perfection of the annuity market.

  11. Inspection of the individual Euler equation (5) in Appendix A shows that the term \(-\left (\overline {\mu }/\sigma \right ) (1-\theta )\left [ c^{\dag }\left (t\right ) /c\left (t\right ) \right ] \) is not part of the generational turnover effect in a strict sense. We nevertheless include it in Ω(t) as a growth drag that is structured in analogy to—and in fact magnifying—the loss of aggregate consumption through the death of a part of the population. The magnitude of this particular channel is identified in Table 2 further on below, where the last column reports the proportion of the growth drag that is explained by incomplete annuitization at 𝜃 = 0.5.

  12. This is most clearly seen for the case where \(\beta =\overline {\mu }\) and, therefore, π = 0. We then have \(\dot {c}\left (t\right ) /c\left (t\right ) =\sigma ^{-1}\left [ r(t)-\rho \right ] -\left [ \overline {\mu }c\left (t,t\right ) /c\left (t\right ) \right ] \left \{ \left [ 1+\sigma ^{-1}\left (1-\theta \right ) \right ] c^{\dag }\left (t\right ) /c\left (t,t\right ) -1\right \}\) , which is unambiguously falling in the rate of demographic turnover, \(\overline {\mu }.\)

  13. For the sake of the argument, we may assume here that altruistic parents are allocating consumption to their children in a way that is reflecting the optimal life-cycle allocation. To mitigate possible errors in the estimation of the consumption level of children, we consider the weighted average over the age groups 0–20.

  14. Broadly, one could say that the growth drag and the share of the growth drag explained by annuities increases with the elasticity of intertemporal substitution.

References

  • Ashraf Q H, Weil D N, Wilde J (2013) The effect of fertility reduction on economic growth. Popul Dev Rev 39:97–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attanasio O P, Weber G (2010) Consumption and saving: models of intertemporal allocation and their implications for public policies. J Econ Lit 48:693–751

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banz L, Prettner K, Werner K (2014) Endogenous growth and realistic demography. Mimeo

  • Blanchard O (1985) Debt, deficits and finite horizons. J Polit Econ 93(2):223–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom D E, Canning D (2008) Global demographic change: dimensions and economic significance. Popul Dev Rev 34:17–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloom D E, Canning D, Graham B (2003) Longevity and life-cycle savings. Scand J Econ 105:319–338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom D E, Canning D, Mansfield R K, Moore M (2007) Demographic change, social security systems, and savings. J Monetary Econ 54:92–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom D E, Canning D, Fink G (2010) Implications of population ageing for economic growth. Oxford Rev Econ Pol 26(4):583–612

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chetty R (2006) A new method of estimating risk aversion. Am Econ Rev 96 (5):1821–1834

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crespo Cuaresma J, Lutz W, Sanderson W (2014) Is the demographic dividend an education dividend? Demography 51:299–315

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Albis H (2007) Demographic structure and capital accumulation. J Econ Theory 132:411–434

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Albis H, Augeraud-Véron E (2009) Competitive growth in a life-cycle model: existence and dynamics. Int Econ Rev 50:459–484

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Albis H, Moosa D (2015) Generational economics and the national transfer accounts. J Demographic Econ 81(4):409–441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erlandsen S, Nymoen R (2008) Consumption and population structure. J Popul Econ 21:505–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fair R C, Dominguez K M (1991) Effects of the changing U.S. age distribution on macroeconomic equations. Am Econ Rev 81:1276–1294

    Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez-Villaverde J, Krueger D (2007) Consumption over the life cycle: facts from consumer expenditure survey data. Rev Econ Stat 89:552–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guvenen F (2006) Reconciling conflicting evidence on the elasticity of intertemporal substitution: a macroeconomic perspective. J of Monetary Econ 53:1451–1472

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen G D, Imrohoroglu S (2008) Consumption over the life cycle: the role of annuities. Rev Econ Dyn 11:566–583

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heijdra B J, Ligthart J E (2000) The dynamic macroeconomic effects of tax policy in an overlapping generations model. Oxford Econ Pap 52:677–701

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heijdra B J, Mierau J O (2012) The individual life-cycle, annuity market imperfections and economic growth. J Econ Dyn Control 36:876–890

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heijdra B J, Mierau J O, Reijnders L S M (2013) A tragedy of annuitization? Longevity insurance in general equilibrium. Macroecon Dyn 18(7):1607–1634

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hosseini R (2015) Adverse selection in the annuity market and the role for social security. J Polit Econ 123:941–984

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Human Mortality Database (2014) Human mortality database. University of California, Berkeley (USA), and Max Planck Institute for Demographic Research (Germany). Available at www.mortality.org

  • Kuhn M, Prettner K (2016) Growth and welfare effects of health care in knowledge based economies. J Health Econ 46:100–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets S (1960) Population change and aggregate output. In: National bureau of economic research demographic and economic change in developed countries. Columbia University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Lau S -H P (2009) Demographic structure and capital accumulation: a quantitative assessment. J Econ Dyn Control 33:554–567

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee R, Mason A (2010a) Some macroeconomic aspects of global population aging. Demography 47:S151–S172

  • Lee R, Mason A (2010b) Fertility, human capital, and economic growth over the demographic transitions. Eur J Popul 26:159–182

  • Lee R, Mason A (2011) Population aging and the generational economy. a global perspective. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham UK and Northampton, MA, USA

  • Lee R., Mason A. (2014) National Transfer Accounts. Website: www.ntaccounts.org

  • Lee R, Mason A, Members of the NTA Network (2014) Is low fertility really a problem? Population aging, dependency, and consumption. Science 346:229–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mason A, Lee R, Jiang J X (2016) Demographic dividends, human capital, and saving. J Econ Ageing 7:106–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mierau J O, Turnovsky S J (2014a) Demography, growth, and inequality. Econ Theor 55:29–68

  • Mierau J O, Turnovsky S J (2014b) Capital accumulation and the sources of demographic change. J Popul Econ 27:857–894

  • Prettner K (2013) Population aging and endogenous economic growth. J Popul Econ 26(2):811–834

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prettner K, Trimborn T (2016) Demographic change and R&D-based economic growth: reconciling theory and evidence. Economica, in press

  • Prettner K, Bloom D E, Strulik H (2013) Declining fertility and economic well-being: do health and education ride to the rescue. Labour Econ 22:70–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prettner K, Canning D (2014) Increasing life expectancy and optimal retirement in general equilibrium. Econ Theor 56:191–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sánchez-Romero M (2013) The role of demography on per capita output growth and saving rates. J Popul Econ 26:1347–1377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sánchez-Romero M, Patxot C, Rentería E, Souto G (2013) On the effects of public and private transfers on capital accumulation: some lessons from the NTA aggregates. J Popul Econ 26:1409–1430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sánchez-Romero M, Abio G, Patxot C, Souto G (2016) Contribution of demography to the Spanish economic growth from 1850 to 2000. Mimeo

  • Schneider M T, Winkler R (2016) Growth and welfare under endogenous lifetime. Bath Economics Research Papers No. 47/16

  • Tung A -C (2011) Population aging and the generational economy. A global perspective. In: Lee R, Mason A (eds). Edward Elgar, Cheltenham UK and Northampton, MA, USA

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank two anonymous referees, Alessandro Cigno, Bernhard Hammer, Dirk Krueger, Alexia Prskawetz, and Miguel Sánchez-Romero for valuable comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Klaus Prettner.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Alessandro Cigno

Appendices

Appendix A: Derivations

1.1 A.1 The aggregate Euler equation

Maximizing Eq. 1 subject to Eq. 2 implies that the optimal consumption path of an individual is characterized by

$$ \frac{\dot{c}(t_{0},t)}{c(t_{0},t)}=\frac{r(t)-\rho -\left( 1-\theta \right) \mu \left( t-t_{0}\right) }{\sigma }, $$
(5)

which corresponds to the standard Euler equation in case of complete annuity markets (𝜃 = 1). By contrast, uninsured mortality within an incomplete annuity market (𝜃 < 1) implies a downward drag on consumption growth. This is the more realistic case on which we focus our attention: as μ(tt 0) becomes large for age a = tt 0 approaching D, it follows that consumption declines toward the end of life. Given that the interest rate exceeds the rate of time preference, this will generate the hump-shaped age profiles of consumption that are typically observed in the data (see Hansen and Imrohoroglu 2008; Heijdra and Mierau 2012).

We can write aggregate consumption as

$$C\left( t\right) =N\left( t\right) {\int}_{t-D}^{t}n\left( t_{0},t\right) c\left( t_{0},t\right) dt_{0}, $$

where \(n\left (t_{0},t\right ) =\beta e^{-\pi \left (t-t_{0}\right ) -M\left (t-t_{0}\right ) }\) is the population share at time t of the cohort born at time t 0, given the survival function \(e^{-M\left (t-t_{0}\right ) }\). Differentiating with respect to time, we obtain

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \overset{\cdot }{C}\left( t\right) & \,=\,&\pi C\left( t\right) \,+\,N\left( t\right) \left\{ \beta c\left( t,t\right) \,+\,{\int}_{t-D}^{t}\left[ \,-\,\left( \pi \,+\,\mu \left( t\!-t_{0}\right) \right) \,+\,\frac{\overset{\cdot }{c}(t_{0},t)}{c(t_{0},t) }\right] n\left( t_{0},t\right) c(t_{0},t)dt_{0}\right\} \\ & =&\frac{r-\rho }{\sigma}C(t)+N(t)\left\{ \beta c(t,t)-\left[ 1+\frac {1-\theta }{\sigma}\right] {\int}_{t-D}^{t}\mu (t-t_{0})n(t_{0},t)c(t_{0},t)dt_{0}\right\} , \end{array} $$

where we use \(\dot {N}\left (t\right ) =\pi N\left (t\right ) \). Defining average consumption across the deceased by

$$c^{\dag }\left( t\right) :=\frac{1}{\overline{\mu }}{\int}_{t-D}^{t}\mu \left( t-t_{0}\right) c(t_{0},t)n\left( t_{0},t\right) dt_{0} $$

allows us to write the aggregate Euler equation as

$$\frac{\dot{C}(t)}{C(t)}=\frac{r-\rho }{\sigma}+{\Omega} \left( t\right) , $$

where

$$ {\Omega} \left( t\right) :=-\overline{\mu }\left\{ \left[ 1+\frac{1-\theta}{\sigma } \right] \frac{c^{\dag }\left( t\right) }{c\left( t\right) }-\frac{ \beta }{\overline{\mu }}\frac{c\left( t,t\right) }{c\left( t\right) }\right \} $$
(6)

with c(t) = C(t)/N(t) being per capita consumption.

1.2 A.2 The balanced growth path for an AK production structure

Following Mierau and Turnovsky (2014a), we assume a production function

$$Y_{i}(t)=A(t)K_{i}(t)^{\alpha }L_{i}(t)^{1-\alpha }, $$

where Y i is output of firm i, K i (t) is its capital stock, L i (t) is its employment level, α ∈ [0, 1] denotes the elasticity of output with respect to capital, and A(t) = A k(t)1−α refers to the productivity index as a function of learning-by-doing spillovers. In this case, the aggregate production function is of the AK type. Denoting the rate of depreciation by δ ∈ [0, 1] , we obtain r(t) = α Aδ and, thus, a balanced growth path of

$$g=\frac{\dot{k}\left( t\right) }{k\left( t\right) }=A-\delta -\pi -\frac{ c\left( t\right) }{k\left( t\right) }=\frac{1}{\sigma }\left[ \alpha A-\delta -\rho \right] +{\Omega} \left( t\right) -\pi =\frac{\dot{c}\left( t\right) }{c\left( t\right) }. $$

In this case, an increase in the generational turnover effect, Ω(t), would also predict an increase in the growth rate of capital accumulation and, thus, an increase in the gross savings rate and in the per capita growth rate of the economy. Solving the interior equation yields

$$\frac{c\left( t\right) }{k\left( t\right) }=\left( 1-\frac{\alpha }{\sigma } \right) A-\left( 1-\frac{1}{\sigma }\right) \delta +\frac{\rho }{\sigma } -{\Omega} \left( t\right)\!, $$

implying a negative relationship between the consumption/capital ratio and the generational turnover effect, Ω(t).

Appendix B: Data

The National Transfer Accounts (NTA) project consists of research teams in more than 40 countries. The teams are measuring how people at each age consume and save. The particular advantage of NTA data over other data is that they include the evolution of intergenerational transfers. Hence, the data allow to keep track of the true underlying consumption-savings profiles over the life cycle. For a detailed description of the NTA project and the data, see: http://www.ntaccounts.org/web/nta/show/.

Figure 1 contains the private consumption level of each age group (from birth to 89 years in 1-year steps and for the group 90 + ) divided by average labor income at ages 30 to 49 for the following countries for which the necessary data of both sources (the National Transfer Accounts and the Human Mortality Database) were available: Austria, Chile, Finland, Germany, Japan, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Taiwan, and the USA. We clearly observe a steep consumption-age profile for the USA, while the profile is rather flat for Taiwan.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Age-specific consumption profiles of the countries included in our analysis

Appendix C: Robustness

To assess the sensitivity of the results with respect to the elasticity of intertemporal substitution, we present the results regarding the generational turnover effect and the growth drag for the cases of σ = 1, σ = 2, and σ = 4 in Tables 34, and 5. The cases σ = 1 and σ = 4 can be considered as the lower and upper bounds of reasonable estimates of σ (cf. Chetty 2006; Guvenen 2006). We see that neither the generational turnover effect nor the growth drag change their signs. However, we see that the larger is σ (which implies a lower elasticity of intertemporal substitution), the smaller is the negative effect of incomplete annuitization on economic growth. Note that this is intuitively clear because, ceteris paribus, a higher elasticity of intertemporal substitution implies a stronger drag of mortality on individual consumption change.

Table 3 Generational turnover and growth drag for \(\protect \sigma =1\)
Table 4 Generational turnover and growth drag for \(\protect \sigma =2\)
Table 5 Generational turnover and growth drag for \(\protect \sigma =4\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kuhn, M., Prettner, K. Population age structure and consumption growth: evidence from National Transfer Accounts. J Popul Econ 31, 135–153 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-017-0654-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-017-0654-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation