Journal of Population Economics

, Volume 30, Issue 3, pp 771–804 | Cite as

Knot yet: minimum marriage age law, marriage delay, and earnings

Original Paper

Abstract

Despite the historical highs for age at first marriage, little is known about the causal relationship between marriage delay and wages, and more importantly, the mechanisms driving such relationship. We attempt to fill the void. Building on an identification strategy proposed in Dahl (Demography 47:689–718, 2010), we first establish the causal wage effects of marriage delay. We then propose ways to distinguish among competing theories and hypotheses, as well as the channels through which marriage delay affects wages. Specifically, we take advantage of their different implications for causal relationship, across gender and sub-populations. We reach two conclusions. First, we find a positive causal impact of marriage delay on wages, with a larger effect for women. Comparison of IV and OLS estimates suggests that the observed relationship between marriage delay and wages is attributed to both selection in late marriages and true causal effects. Second, we find strong evidence that the positive, causal effects are almost exclusively through increased education for both men and women.

Keywords

Timing of first marriage Wages Human capital Selection 

JEL Classification

J12 J16 J31 

References

  1. Angrist JD, Imbens GW (1995) Two-stage least square estimation of average causal effects in models with variable treatment intensity. J Am Stat Assoc 90:431–442CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Angrist J, Krueger AB (1991) Do compulsory school attendance affect schooling and earnings. Q J Econ 106:979–1014CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Angrist JD, Pischke JS (2009) Mostly harmless econometrics: an empiricist’s companion princeton. Princeton University Press, NJGoogle Scholar
  4. Bailey MJ (2006) More power to the pill: the impact of contraceptive freedom on women’s life cycle labor supply. Q J Econ 121:289–320Google Scholar
  5. Balbo N, Barban N, MIlls M (2013) Friend and peer effects on entry into marriage and parenthood. A multiprocess approach. Dondena Working PapersGoogle Scholar
  6. Becker GS (1973) A theory of marriage: part I. J Polit Econ 81:813–846CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Bergstrom T, Bagnoli M (1993) Courtship as a waiting game. J Polit Econ 101:185–202CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Bergstrom T, Schoeni RF (1996) Income prospects and age-at-marriage. J Popul Econ 9:115–130CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Bertrand M, Duflo E, Mullainathan S (2004) How much should we trust differences-in-differences estimates? Q J Econ 119:249–275CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Blank RM, Charles KK, Sallee JM (2009) A cautionary tale about the use of administrative data: evidence from age of marriage laws. American Econ J: Appl Econ 1:128–149Google Scholar
  11. Bound J, Jaeger DA, Baker RM (1995) Problems with instrumental variables estimation when the correlation between the instruments and the endogenous explanatory variable is weak. J Am Stat Assoc 90:443–450Google Scholar
  12. Buchinsky M (2001) Quantile regression with sample selection: estimating women’s return to education in the U.S. Empir Econ 26:87–113CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Cadena BC (2013) Recent immigrants as labor market arbitrageurs. Evidence from the minimum wage. Unpublished ManuscriptGoogle Scholar
  14. Chang SK (2011) Simulation estimation of two-tiered dynamic panel Tobit models with an application to the labor supply of married women. J Appl Econom 26:854–871CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Charles KK, Luoh MC (2007), Male incarceration, the marriage market and female outcomes. Unpublished ManuscriptGoogle Scholar
  16. Dahl GB (2010) Early teen marriage and future poverty. Demography 47:689–718CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Dougherty C (2005) Why are the returns to schooling higher for women than for men? J Hum Resour 40:969–988CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Ellwood DT, Jencks C (2002) The growing difference in family structure. What do we know? Where do we look for answers? Unpublished manuscriptGoogle Scholar
  19. Field E, Ambrus A (2008) Early marriage, age of menarche, and female schooling attainment in Bangladesh. J Polit Econ 116:881–930CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Gladden T (1999) Labor market effects of family ties and migration. Unpublished ManuscriptGoogle Scholar
  21. Goldin C, Katz LF (2002) The power of the pill: oral contraceptives and women’s career and marriage decisions. J Polit Econ 110:730–770CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Goldin C, Katz LF, Kuziemko I (2006) The homecoming of american college women: the reversal of the college gender gap. J Econ Perspect 20:133–156CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Henderson DJ, Polachek SW, Wang L (2011) Heterogeneity in schooling rates of return. Econ Educ Rev 30:1202–1214CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Hersch J, Stratton LS (1997) Housework, fixed effects, and wages of married workers. J Hum Resour:32Google Scholar
  25. Hersch J, Stratton LS (2000) Household specialization and the male marriage wage premium. Ind Labor Relat Rev 54:78–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Huber M, Mellace G (2014) Testing exclusion restrictions and additive separability in sample selection models. Empir Econ 2011–45Google Scholar
  27. Imbens G, Angrist J (1994) Identification and estimation of local average treatment effects. Econometrica 62:467–475CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Keeley M (1974) A model of marital formation: the determinants of the optimal age at first marriage. Ph.D. thesis, University of ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  29. Kelejian HH (1971) Two-stage least squares and econometric systems linear in parameters but nonlinear in the endogeneous variables. J Am Stat Assoc 66:373–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Kerckhoff AC, Parrow AA (1979) The effect of early marriage on the educational attainment of young men. J Marriage Fam 41:97–107CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Koenker R, Hallock KF (2001) Quantile regression. J Econ Perspect 15:143–156CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Korenman S, Neumark D (1992) Marriage, motherhood, and wages. J Hum Resour 27:233–55CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Lam D (1988) Marriage markets and assortative mating with household public goods: theoretical results and empirical implications. J Hum Resour 23:462–487CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Loughran D (2002) The effect of male wage inequality on female age at first marriage. Rev Econ Stat 84:237–250CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Loughran DS, Zissimpoulos J (2004) Are there gains to delaying marriage? The effect of age at first marriage on career development and wages. Unpublished ManuscriptGoogle Scholar
  36. Loughran DS, Zissimpoulos J (2009) Why wait? The effect of marriage and childbearing on the wage growth of men and women. J Hum Resour 44:326–349Google Scholar
  37. Low H, Meghir C, Pistaferri L (2010) Wage risk and employment risk over the life cycle. Am Econ Rev 100:1432–67CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Lundberg S, Pollak RA (1995) Bargaining and distribution in marriage. J Econ Perspect 10:139–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Lundberg SJ, Rose E (2000) Parenthood and the earnings of married men and women. Labour Econ 7:689–710CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Lundberg SJ, Rose E (2002) The effects of sons and daughters on men’s labor supply and wages. Rev Econ Stat 84:251–268CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Martins M (2001) Parametric and semiparametric estimation of sample selection models: an empirical application to the female labour force in Portugal. J Appl Econom 16:23–39CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Miller AR (2011) The effects of motherhood timing on career path. J Popul Econ 24:1071–1100CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Miller AR (2013) Lifecycle events and their consequences: job loss, family change, and declines in health, chapter marriage timing, motherhood timing, and women’s wellbeing in retirement. Stanford University Press, Stanford, pp 109–132CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Mroz T (1987) The sensitivity of an empirical model of married women’s hours of work to economic and statistical assumptions. Econometrica 55:765–799CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Polachek SW, Siebert WS (1993) The economics of earnings. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Rose E (2001) Marriage and assortative mating: how have the patterns changed? University of Washington. Working Paper pp. 0–25Google Scholar
  47. Ruggles S, Alexander JT, Genadek K, Goeken R, Schroeder MB, Sobek M (2010) Integrated public use microdata series: version 5.0 [machine-readable database]. Technical report, University of MinnesotaGoogle Scholar
  48. Shemyakina O (2007) The effect of armed conflict in Tajikistan on the marriage market and female reproductive behavior. Unpublished ManuscriptGoogle Scholar
  49. Staiger D, Stock JH (1997) Instrumental variables regression with weak instruments. Econometrica 65:557–586CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Wooldridge JM (2002) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. MIT PressGoogle Scholar
  51. Wooldridge JM (2010) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. MIT PressGoogle Scholar
  52. Zabel JE (1993) The relationship between hours of work and labor force participation in four models of labor supply behavior. J Labor Econ 11:387–416CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Zhang J (1995) Do men with higher wages marry earlier and later? Econ Lett 49:193–196CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2017

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsThe University of OklahomaNormanUSA

Personalised recommendations