Abstract
Two concerns central to the debate over skilled guest worker programs in the USA are that (1) guest workers are restricted from inter-firm mobility and are “effectively tied” to their firms, and (2) guest workers provide cheap and immobile labor that crowds out natives, especially during times of heightened unemployment. We address these concerns by using a unique dataset of employee records from six large Indian IT firms operating in the USA. We find that the guest workers in our sample exhibit a significant amount of inter-firm mobility that varies over both the earnings distribution and the business cycle. We also find that these workers exit the USA during periods of heightened unemployment. These findings provide new evidence on the implications of the institutional features and debate surrounding guest worker programs.
This is a preview of subscription content,
to check access.




Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
This action does not extend the 6-year length of the visa. Unfortunately, our data does not span the necessary years to examine the impact of this policy change. Naidu et al. (Forthcoming) estimates the impact of decreased mobility costs for low skilled guest workers in the United Arab Emirates, finding significant increases in both earnings and mobility rates.
This information was obtained from a series of press releases on the USCIS website: http://www.uscis.gov/news-releases
See the USCIS website for more details, specifically Table 31: http://www.dhs.gov/yearbook-immigration-statistics-2012-nonimmigrant-admissions.
Available at http://www.flcdatacenter.com/caseh1b.aspx.
We focus on all certified applications filed between 2003 and 2011, and display the distribution of the midpoint of the stated salary, weighting by the number of workers given in each LCA record.
In our data cleaning process, the trim above the $135,233 threshold cuts seven observations for each observation below the $36,566 threshold. Overall, this trim results in the loss of 3.6 % of our data. We also report results on our untrimmed data in the robustness check section.
Our full data include a large number of workers who are right-censored (still employed at the end of the period of study). Figure 6 in the Appendix repeats this analysis on our full sample.
USCIS data is culled from reports publicly available at http://www.uscis.gov/tools/reports-studies/reports-and-studies.
More limited data on Indian born H-1B workers that include initial petitions granted for the years 2003–2009 and continuation petitions approved (includes both extensions as well as inter-firm transfers) for the years 2006–2012 suggest that there were 144 continuing petitions approved for every 100 initial visas granted. The 3-year lag between the two counts is imposed to account for renewals happening after 3 years.
We later relax the assumption of independence of outcomes through use of a bivariate probit model. Results, reported in the robustness check section, find no evidence of correlation in unobservables for the two outcomes.
We use the monthly state-level population unemployment rates as reported by the St. Louis Federal Reserve. We later run robustness checks using industry and occupation specific measures of the unemployment rate.
We later simulate time-varying wages. Results are reported in the robustness check section.
The elasticities are calculated using the estimated coefficients on log earnings and the interactions between log earnings and unemployment at the appropriate level of unemployment.
Recall that all observations will be at risk of a quit to another firm in the USA, as H-1B workers may obtain another sponsor, and L-1 workers may find a firm that is willing to sponsor them on an H-1B visa.
The inelastic estimate for single workers does not appear to have been driven by an over-representation of L-1 visa holders among this group. Statistics from government reports, available at https://web.archive.org/web/20130215115750/http://www.travel.state.gov/visa/statistics/nivstats/nivstats_4582.htmlas FY1997-2012 NIV Detail Table (Excel spreadsheet), show that for Indian nationals, there are proportionately more dependent visas (spouses and children) associated with L-1 visas than H-1B visas. This suggests that H-1B visa holders from India are more likely to have a spouse or child in the USA on a dependent visa than are L-1 visa holders.
Table 13 in the Appendix reports summary statistics on these alternative measures of unemployment, the official rate reported by the Fed, and our own measure of unemployment using the same data (CPS) as the alternative measures. The correlations between the Federal Reserve Economic Data unemployment rate (used in the main analysis) and the CPS industry (Professional and Technical Services) and occupation (Computer and Mathematical Science Occupations) specific unemployment rates are 0.567 and 0.338, respectively. Table 14 in the Appendix reports these correlations.
We further repeat this exercise two more times, replacing the 90 % proportion with 80 and 70 %. Results from the full set of simulations are presented in the Appendix in Table 15.
See Appendix Table 13 for details.
These results become more similar to our main results when we alternatively assume that H-1B workers are drawn at a rate of 80 and 70 % from the top two-thirds of the wage distribution. These results are reported in Appendix Table 15. We also note that in each of these scenarios the quit rate is relatively stable, varying between 33 and 36 %.
References
Abramitzky R, Boustan LP, Eriksson K (2014) A nation of immigrants: assimilation and economic outcomes in the age of mass migration. J Polit Econ 122(3):467–506. doi:10.1086/675805
Banerjee P (2006) Indian information technology workers in the United States: the H-1B visa, flexible production, and the racialization of labor. Crit Sociol 32(2–3):425–445. doi:10.1163/156916306777835295
Banerjee P (2009) Indian IT workers in the U.S.: race, gender, and state in the making of immigrant labor. Dissertation, Syracuse University
Borjas GJ (2001) Does immigration grease the wheels of the labor market? Brook Pap Eco Ac 2001(1):69–133
Borjas GJ (2009) Immigration in high-skill labor markets: the impact of foreign students on the earnings of doctorates. In: Freeman RB, Goroff D (eds) Science and engineering careers in the United States: an analysis of markets and employment. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 131–161
Borjas GJ, Doran KB (2012) The collapse of the Soviet Union and the productivity of American mathematicians. Q J Econ 127(3):1143–1203. doi:10.1093/qje/qjs015
Bound J, Braga B, Golden JM, Khanna G (2015) Recruitment of foreigners in the market for computer scientists in the US. J Labor Econ 33(S1):S187–S223. doi:10.1086/679020
Burdett K, Mortensen DT (1998) Wage differentials, employer size, and unemployment. Int Econ Rev 39(2):257–273. doi:10.2307/2527292
Cadena BC, Kovak BK (2016) Immigrants equilibrate local labor markets: evidence from the Great Recession. Am Econ J: Appl Econ 8(1):257–290. doi:10.1257/app.20140095
Chakravartty P (2006) Symbolic analysts or indentured servants? Indian high-tech migrants in America’s information economy. Knowl, Technol Policy 19(3):27–43. doi:10.1007/s12130-006-1028-0
Depew B, Sorensen TA (2013) The elasticity of labor supply to the firm over the business cycle. Labour Econ 24:196–204. doi:10.1016/j.labeco.2013.08.005
Devereux PJ, Hart RA (2006) Real wage cyclicality of job stayers, within-company job movers, and between-company job movers. Ind Labor Relat Rev 60(1):105–119. doi:10.1177/001979390606000106
Dorning J, Fanning C (2012) Gaming the system: guest worker visa programs and professional and technical workers in the U.S. Department for Professional Employees, AFL-CIO, Washington, DC. http://dpeaflcio.org/wp-content/uploads/Gaming-the-System-2012-Revised.pdf
Dube A, Freeman E, Reich M (2010) Employee replacement costs. IRLE Working Paper 201-10, http://escholarship.org/uc/item/7kc29981
Dustmann C (2003) Return migration, wage differentials, and the optimal migration duration. Eur Econ Rev 47(2):353–369. doi:10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00184-2
Farber HS (1994) The analysis of inter-firm worker mobility. J Labor Econ 12 (4):554–593
Flood S, King M, Ruggles S, Warren JR (2015) Integrated public use microdata series, current population survey: version 4.0. [machine-readable database]
Friedman TL (2007) The world is at: a brief history of the twenty-first century. Farrar, Straus and Giroux, New York
Harris JR, Todaro MP (1970) Migration, unemployment and development: a two-sector analysis. Am Econ Rev 60(1):126–142
Hatch O (2000) American competitiveness in the 21st century. Senate Committee on the Judiciary Report 106-260. U.S Senate, Washington, DC
Hira R (2010a) Bridge to immigration or cheap temporary labor? The H-1B & L-1 visa programs are a source of both. Briefing Paper 257. Economic Policy Institute, Washington, DC. http://www.epi.org/publication/bp257/
Hira R (2010b) The H-1B and L-1 visa programs: out of control. Briefing Paper 280. Economic Policy Institute, Washington, DC. http://www.epi.org/publication/bp280/
Hirsch B, Jahn EJ (2015) Is there monopsonistic discrimination against immigrants? Ind Labor Relat Rev 68(3):501–528. doi:10.1177/0019793915572124
Hirsch B, Schank T, Schnabel C (2010) Differences in labor supply to monopsonistic firms and the gender pay gap: an empirical analysis using linked employer-employee data from Germany. J Labor Econ 28(2):291–330. doi:10.1086/651208
Hirsch B, Jahn EJ, Schnabel C (2013) The cyclical behaviour of employers’ monopsony power and workers. IZA Discussion Paper 7776
Hotchkiss JL, Quispe-Agnoli M (2013) The expected impact of state immigration legislation on labor market outcomes. J Policy Anal Manag 32(1):34–59. doi:10.1002/pam.21664
Hunt J (2010) Skilled immigrants’ contribution to innovation and entrepreneurship in the United States. In: Open for business: migrant entrepreneurship in OECD countries. OECD Publishing, Paris
Hunt J, Gauthier-Loiselle M (2010) How much does immigration boost innovation? Am Econ J: Macroecon 2(2):31–56. doi:10.1257/mac.2.2.31
Hyde A (1998) Silicon valley’s high-velocity labor market. J Appl Corp Financ 11(2):28–37
Kandilov AMG (2008) Labor market outcomes of immigrants in the United States. Dissertation, University of Michigan
Kerr SP, Kerr WR, Lincoln WF (2015) Skilled immigration and the employment structures of US firms. J Labor Econ 33(S1):S147–S186. doi:10.1086/678986
Kerr W, Lincoln W (2010) The supply side of innovation: H-1B visa reforms and US ethnic invention. J Labor Econ 28(3):473–508
Lofstrom M, Hayes JJ (2011) H-1Bs: How do they stack up to US born workers? IZA Discussion Paper 6259
Loury LD (2006) Some contacts are more equal than others: Informal networks, job tenure, and wages. J Labor Econ 24(2):299–318. doi:10.1086/499974
Manning A (2011) Chapter 11 - imperfect competition in the labor market. In: Card D, Ashenfelter O (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 4. Part B, Elsevier, pp 973–1041. doi:10.1016/S0169-7218(11)02409-9
Matloff N (2003) On the need for reform of the H-1B non-immigrant work visa in computer-related occupations. Univ Mich J Law Reform 36(4):815–914
Matloff N (2013) Immigration and the tech industry: as a labour shortage remedy, for innovation, or for cost savings? Migr Lett 10(2):210–227
Mithas S, Lucas HC (2010) Are foreign IT workers cheaper? U.S. visa policies and compensation of information technology professionals. Manage Sci 56(5):745–765. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1100.1149
Mukhopadhyay S, Oxborrow D (2012) The value of an employment-based green card. Demography 49(1):219–237. doi:10.1007/s13524-011-0079-3
Naidu S, Nyarko Y, Wang SY (Forthcoming) Monopsony power in migrant labor markets: evidence from the United Arab Emirates. J Pol Econ
Norlander P (2014) Organizing migrations: people and knowledge flows in the global economy. Dissertation, University of California Los Angeles
Ransom MR, Sims DP (2010) Estimating the firm’s labor supply curve in a “new monopsony” framework: school teachers in Missouri. J Labor Econ 28(2):331–356. doi:10.1086/649904
Ruggles S, Alexander JT, Genadek K, Goeken R, Schroeder MB, Sobek M (2010) Integrated public use microdata series: Version 5.0 [machine-readable database]
Sjaastad LA (1962) The costs and returns of human migration. J Polit Econ 70(5):80–93
Solon G, Whately W, Stevens AH (1997) Wage changes and intrafirm job mobility over the business cycle: two case studies. Ind Labor Relat Rev 50(3):402–415. doi:10.1177/001979399705000302
Webber DA (2015) Firm market power and the earnings distribution. Labour Econ 35:123–134. doi:10.1016/j.labeco.2015.05.003
Yueh LY (2008) Do social networks increase labour supply elasticity? Appl Econ Lett 15(1):5–10. doi:10.1080/13504850600690020
Acknowledgments
We would like to thank the anonymous referees, Randy Akee, Louis Beland, Leah Boustan, Danny Brent, Peter Brummund, Christopher Ericksson, Gordon Dahl, David Fairris, Boris Hirsch, Elke Jahn, Taylor Jaworski, William Lincoln, Norman Matloff, Sankar Mukhopadhyay, Mindy Marks, Naci Mocan, Patrick O’Rourke, Ben Rissing, Chad Sparber, Doug Webber, Tiemen Woutersen and Klaus Zimmermann for their helpful comments. In addition, we appreciate the feedback received at University of Nevada Reno, UCLA, UT-Dallas, UT-Austin, IAB Nuremberg, Whittier College, the 2013 meetings of the Southern Economics Association, the 2014 meetings of the American Economics Association, the 2014 meetings of the Society of Labor Economists, and the 2014 IZA Annual Migration Meetings. We are grateful to the providers of the confidential payroll data analyzed in this paper; the data is confidential to protect the identities of individuals and firms.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Responsible editor: Klaus F. Zimmermann
Appendices
Appendix A: Institutional details and data construction
The H-1B and L-1 visa programs are intended for highly-skilled guest workers. Individuals who receive H-1B visas are required to possess skills in a “specialty occupation” while holders of L-1 visas are expected to possess “specialized knowledge.” An annual cap of 65,000 was initially placed on the number of H-1B visas available. The American Competitiveness and Workforce Improvement Act of 1998 increased the H-1B visa cap to 115,000 for 1999 and 107,500 for 2000. The American Competitiveness and Worker Investment Act for the 21st Century of 2000 increased the cap to 195,000 through 2003, after which the number of visas reverted to 65,000. Additional changes allowed another 20,000 recipients of post graduate degrees obtained in the USA to receive this visa. Employers of H-1B workers must pay the annual prevailing wage which can be prorated into monthly or more frequent regular salary payments. Hourly workers must meet the prorated annual minimum each pay period (they have to be paid for non-productive time), as described in paragraph (c)(7)(i) of of 20 CFR Section 655.731, which is why firms in this industry typically pay a prorated annual salary. See http://www.law.cornell.edu/cfr/text/20/655.731#c_2. While regulations prohibit workers on an L-1 visa from switching jobs in the same manner as workers on an H-1B, L-1 workers are able to switch jobs if they find a new employer who will sponsor them for an H-1B visa, or if they are able to obtain permanent residency. Legislation enacted in 2004 restricted the use of L-1 visas by “job-shops” that contract L-1 workers out to other firms, and starting in 2009, the Obama administration began a crackdown on L-1 usage, especially with regard to applications from India (National Foundation for American Policy, 2012). While we do not know whether the guest workers in our data are on an L-1 or an H-1B visa, we believe most are on the H-1B and consult several sources to confirm. USCIS provided information on large H-1B and L-1 visa sponsoring firms to U.S. Senator Charles Grassley. A link to this data is available here: https://web.archive.org/web/20070627215621/http://grassley.senate.gov/releases/2007/062620072.pdf. This document gives the number of H-1B visas issued to the top 20 users of H-1B visas in fiscal year 2006, which falls during the middle of our period of study. It also reports the number of L-1 visas issued to these firms. From this list, we exclude seven domestic corporations: Microsoft, Deloitte and Touche, IBM, Oracle, Cisco, Intel, Ernst and Young, and Motorola. The remaining firms are Indian IT firms, and accounted for 23,293 H-1B visas and 11,712 L-1 visas. Thus, this information suggests that there is nearly a 67 to 33 % split between H-1B and L-1 visas in large firms in this industry in fiscal year 2006. As we do not know the identity of the six firms in our data, we must rely upon this industry level measure. One potential concern with this approach is that by focusing on the largest users of H-1B visas, we may be overestimating the importance of the H-1B visa in this industry. To examine this issue, we turn to a separate report which gives the number of L-1 visas issued to the Top 20 L visa-using firms. See https://web.archive.org/web/20070627215549/ http://grassley.senate.gov/releases/2007/06262007.pdf. In this report, we note that 12 firms from the previous document also appear. Of these, non-domestic firms account for a total of only 945 visas. Even if these firms sponsored no H-1B visas, this would lower our estimate of H-1B workers in this industry by only two percentage points. Finally, using data from government reports (available at https://web.archive.org/web/20130215115750/http://www.travel.state.gov/visa/statistics/nivstats/nivstats_4582.htmlas FY1997-2012 NIV Detail Table (Excel spreadsheet)), we see that H-1B visas account for 67.8 % of combined H-1B and L-1 visas issued to Indian nationals between fiscal years 2003 and 2011. We believe that guest workers who quit in the USA separate to other employment, and that other separations are returns, for the following reasons. Firms are required to repatriate workers according to Section 8 C.F.R. 214.2(h)(4)(iii)(E). We note that guest workers who quit without an approved change of employer are heavily penalized if they move to informal employment; the law requires an employee who quits or is dismissed to find a new job. Failing this, they will immediately become “out of status,” and thus become an “illegal alien.” If a worker left their job but did not obtain new employment, the worker would be “out of status” and in violation of immigration law. Furthermore, time limits for workers are not reset when a H-1B or L-1 worker switches employment. A summary is available at http://www.klaskolaw.com/articles.php?action=view&id=50 See 8 C.F.R. 214.2(h)(13)(iii) as well as http://www.uscis.gov/USCIS/Resources/C2en.pdf for further details. We acknowledge that there is an Indian born population of undocumented and unauthorized workers in the USA, and that H-1B workers moving between jobs without proper authorization may be among these workers. Estimates from the Pew Hispanic Center (http://www.pewhispanic.org/2014/12/11/unauthorized-trends/) suggest that, from 2005 through 2011, there were an average of 360,000 unauthorized Indian Born individuals in the USA, compared to a average total unauthorized population of around 11.5 million. Combined with population counts from the 2005–2011 American Community Survey, this suggests that around 17.5 % of Indian migrants and 28.5 % of all migrants were unauthorized. ACS and Pew data (http://www.pewhispanic.org/2009/04/14/iv-social-and-economic-characteristics/) reveal that only 15 % of unauthorized immigrants have a Bachelor’s degree, compared to 30 % of all immigrants. Assuming that, among Indian Immigrants, the unauthorized are also half as likely to have a Bachelor’s degree, we can apply Bayes’ law to find that the probability that a college educated Indian born worker is undocumented. This calculation suggests the rate is a relatively low 8.75 %. It is unlikely that the workers in our dataset face mobility frictions due to a pending application for permanent residence. Hira (2010a, b) constructs an immigrant yield measure that compares the number of immigrants sponsored by firms for temporary worker visas to the number that the same firms sponsor for permanent residence. The largest ten offshore outsourcing firms, including the Indian IT firms, sponsored only 6 % as many workers for permanent residence as for H-1B visas in 2008, compared to 64 % yields for traditional technology firms such as Microsoft, Cisco, Oracle, Qualcomm, Google, and Intel. Hira discusses three reasons why Indian IT firms do not hire US workers: to facilitate knowledge transfer to India, to have an inexpensive labor source in the USA, and to train workers who will return to India and continue to support operations remotely. When studying mobility between firms using CPS data, we employ the CPS-March Supplement variable “numemps,” which reports the number of employers that a survey respondent had in the previous year. Using data from 2003 to 2011, we compute the percentage of IT workers who had more than one employer in a given year. We limit our sample to IT workers who are currently employed and working at least 40 h per week on the main job in order to avoid counting workers who are working more than one job at a time, rather than switching jobs. Our sample is of two occupations: CPS “occ1990” codes 229 and 64, which represent “Computer Programmers” and “Computer Systems Analysts and Scientists,” respectively. Likely, Indian guest workers are, as previously defined, non-citizens born in India who have been in the USA for less than 8 years. We would expect guest workers to have a Bachelor’s degree as is required by the H-1B and L-1 programs. In fact, 99.7 % of the likely guest workers in the CPS data do. Since no such degree requirement exists for native born workers in this industry, only 60.9 % of workers have a degree. To make the samples more comparable, we drop workers without a Bachelors in the analysis. All calculations are done using survey weights, a mobility gap of less than 1 % exists when not using survey weights, and in both cases, a Chi-square test of significance fails to reject the null hypothesis of equivalent quit rates. When studying previous quit elasticity estimates, we use 25 estimated quit elasticities reported by Manning (2011) in Tables 6 and 7 of his book chapter. When estimates for multiple groups were reported, we took the raw average of the reported estimates. When ranges were given, we took the midpoint. For a paper reporting one-sided bounds, we used the bound itself as the estimate. All reported elasticities in these tables were obtained by estimating the relationship between earnings and separations. Rather than report the implied supply elasticities, as Manning and the original authors did, we instead report minus one half of his numbers, i.e., the raw separation elasticity results that were used to generate the implied supply elasticity numbers, and are thus most comparable to the numbers presented in our study.
Appendix B: Tables and figures
Appendix: References
Ron Hira. Bridge to immigration or cheap temporary labor? The H-1B & L-1 visa programs are a source of both. Briefing Paper 257, Economic Policy Institute, Washington, DC., 2010. http://www.epi.org/publication/bp257/.
National Foundation for American Policy. Analysis: Data reveal high denial rates for L-1 and H-1B petitions at U.S. citizenship and immigration services. NFAP Policy Brief, February 2012.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Depew, B., Norlander, P. & Sørensen, T.A. Inter-firm mobility and return migration patterns of skilled guest workers. J Popul Econ 30, 681–721 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-016-0607-y
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-016-0607-y